Download PDF
ads:
Russia
Donald Mackenzie Wallace
The Project Gutenberg Etext of Russia by Donald Mackenzie Wallace
Copyright laws are changing all over the world, be sure to check
the copyright laws for your country before posting these files!!
Please take a look at the important information in this header.
We encourage you to keep this file on your own disk, keeping an
electronic path open for the next readers. Do not remove this.
**Welcome To The World of Free Plain Vanilla Electronic Texts**
**Etexts Readable By Both Humans and By Computers, Since 1971**
*These Etexts Prepared By Hundreds of Volunteers and Donations*
Information on contacting Project Gutenberg to get Etexts, and
further information is included below. We need your donations.
Russia
by Donald Mackenzie Wallace
June, 1998 [Etext #1349]
The Project Gutenberg Etext of Russia by Donald Mackenzie Wallace
******This file should be named rsdmw10.txt or rsdmw10.zip******
Corrected EDITIONS of our etexts get a new NUMBER, rsdmw11.txt.
VERSIONS based on separate sources get new LETTER, rsdmw10a.txt.
This etext was prepared by Donald Lainson, charlie@idirect.com.
We are now trying to release all our books one month in advance
of the official release dates, for time for better editing.
Please note: neither this list nor its contents are final till
midnight of the last day of the month of any such announcement.
The official release date of all Project Gutenberg Etexts is at
Midnight, Central Time, of the last day of the stated month. A
preliminary version may often be posted for suggestion, comment
and editing by those who wish to do so. To be sure you have an
up to date first edition [xxxxx10x.xxx] please check file sizes
ads:
Livros Grátis
http://www.livrosgratis.com.br
Milhares de livros grátis para download.
in the first week of the next month. Since our ftp program has
a bug in it that scrambles the date [tried to fix and failed] a
look at the file size will have to do, but we will try to see a
new copy has at least one byte more or less.
Information about Project Gutenberg (one page)
We produce about two million dollars for each hour we work. The
fifty hours is one conservative estimate for how long it we take
to get any etext selected, entered, proofread, edited, copyright
searched and analyzed, the copyright letters written, etc. This
projected audience is one hundred million readers. If our value
per text is nominally estimated at one dollar then we produce $2
million dollars per hour this year as we release thirty-two text
files per month, or 384 more Etexts in 1997 for a total of 1000+
If these reach just 10% of the computerized population, then the
total should reach over 100 billion Etexts given away.
The Goal of Project Gutenberg is to Give Away One Trillion Etext
Files by the December 31, 2001. [10,000 x 100,000,000=Trillion]
This is ten thousand titles each to one hundred million readers,
which is only 10% of the present number of computer users. 2001
should have at least twice as many computer users as that, so it
will require us reaching less than 5% of the users in 2001.
We need your donations more than ever!
All donations should be made to "Project Gutenberg/CMU": and are
tax deductible to the extent allowable by law. (CMU = Carnegie-
Mellon University).
For these and other matters, please mail to:
Project Gutenberg
P. O. Box 2782
Champaign, IL 61825
When all other email fails try our Executive Director:
Michael S. Hart <[email protected]m>
We would prefer to send you this information by email
(Internet, Bitnet, Compuserve, ATTMAIL or MCImail).
******
If you have an FTP program (or emulator), please
FTP directly to the Project Gutenberg archives:
[Mac users, do NOT point and click. . .type]
ftp uiarchive.cso.uiuc.edu
login: anonymous
password: your@login
cd etext/etext90 through /etext96
or cd etext/articles [get suggest gut for more information]
dir [to see files]
ads:
get or mget [to get files. . .set bin for zip files]
GET INDEX?00.GUT
for a list of books
and
GET NEW GUT for general information
and
MGET GUT* for newsletters.
**Information prepared by the Project Gutenberg legal advisor**
(Three Pages)
***START**THE SMALL PRINT!**FOR PUBLIC DOMAIN ETEXTS**START***
Why is this "Small Print!" statement here? You know: lawyers.
They tell us you might sue us if there is something wrong with
your copy of this etext, even if you got it for free from
someone other than us, and even if what's wrong is not our
fault. So, among other things, this "Small Print!" statement
disclaims most of our liability to you. It also tells you how
you can distribute copies of this etext if you want to.
*BEFORE!* YOU USE OR READ THIS ETEXT
By using or reading any part of this PROJECT GUTENBERG-tm
etext, you indicate that you understand, agree to and accept
this "Small Print!" statement. If you do not, you can receive
a refund of the money (if any) you paid for this etext by
sending a request within 30 days of receiving it to the person
you got it from. If you received this etext on a physical
medium (such as a disk), you must return it with your request.
ABOUT PROJECT GUTENBERG-TM ETEXTS
This PROJECT GUTENBERG-tm etext, like most PROJECT GUTENBERG-
tm etexts, is a "public domain" work distributed by Professor
Michael S. Hart through the Project Gutenberg Association at
Carnegie-Mellon University (the "Project"). Among other
things, this means that no one owns a United States copyright
on or for this work, so the Project (and you!) can copy and
distribute it in the United States without permission and
without paying copyright royalties. Special rules, set forth
below, apply if you wish to copy and distribute this etext
under the Project's "PROJECT GUTENBERG" trademark.
To create these etexts, the Project expends considerable
efforts to identify, transcribe and proofread public domain
works. Despite these efforts, the Project's etexts and any
medium they may be on may contain "Defects". Among other
things, Defects may take the form of incomplete, inaccurate or
corrupt data, transcription errors, a copyright or other
intellectual property infringement, a defective or damaged
disk or other etext medium, a computer virus, or computer
codes that damage or cannot be read by your equipment.
LIMITED WARRANTY; DISCLAIMER OF DAMAGES
But for the "Right of Replacement or Refund" described below,
[1] the Project (and any other party you may receive this
etext from as a PROJECT GUTENBERG-tm etext) disclaims all
liability to you for damages, costs and expenses, including
legal fees, and [2] YOU HAVE NO REMEDIES FOR NEGLIGENCE OR
UNDER STRICT LIABILITY, OR FOR BREACH OF WARRANTY OR CONTRACT,
INCLUDING BUT NOT LIMITED TO INDIRECT, CONSEQUENTIAL, PUNITIVE
OR INCIDENTAL DAMAGES, EVEN IF YOU GIVE NOTICE OF THE
POSSIBILITY OF SUCH DAMAGES.
If you discover a Defect in this etext within 90 days of
receiving it, you can receive a refund of the money (if any)
you paid for it by sending an explanatory note within that
time to the person you received it from. If you received it
on a physical medium, you must return it with your note, and
such person may choose to alternatively give you a replacement
copy. If you received it electronically, such person may
choose to alternatively give you a second opportunity to
receive it electronically.
THIS ETEXT IS OTHERWISE PROVIDED TO YOU "AS-IS". NO OTHER
WARRANTIES OF ANY KIND, EXPRESS OR IMPLIED, ARE MADE TO YOU AS
TO THE ETEXT OR ANY MEDIUM IT MAY BE ON, INCLUDING BUT NOT
LIMITED TO WARRANTIES OF MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR A
PARTICULAR PURPOSE.
Some states do not allow disclaimers of implied warranties or
the exclusion or limitation of consequential damages, so the
above disclaimers and exclusions may not apply to you, and you
may have other legal rights.
INDEMNITY
You will indemnify and hold the Project, its directors,
officers, members and agents harmless from all liability, cost
and expense, including legal fees, that arise directly or
indirectly from any of the following that you do or cause:
[1] distribution of this etext, [2] alteration, modification,
or addition to the etext, or [3] any Defect.
DISTRIBUTION UNDER "PROJECT GUTENBERG-tm"
You may distribute copies of this etext electronically, or by
disk, book or any other medium if you either delete this
"Small Print!" and all other references to Project Gutenberg,
or:
[1] Only give exact copies of it. Among other things, this
requires that you do not remove, alter or modify the
etext or this "small print!" statement. You may however,
if you wish, distribute this etext in machine readable
binary, compressed, mark-up, or proprietary form,
including any form resulting from conversion by word pro-
cessing or hypertext software, but only so long as
*EITHER*:
[*] The etext, when displayed, is clearly readable, and
does *not* contain characters other than those
intended by the author of the work, although tilde
(~), asterisk (*) and underline (_) characters may
be used to convey punctuation intended by the
author, and additional characters may be used to
indicate hypertext links; OR
[*] The etext may be readily converted by the reader at
no expense into plain ASCII, EBCDIC or equivalent
form by the program that displays the etext (as is
the case, for instance, with most word processors);
OR
[*] You provide, or agree to also provide on request at
no additional cost, fee or expense, a copy of the
etext in its original plain ASCII form (or in EBCDIC
or other equivalent proprietary form).
[2] Honor the etext refund and replacement provisions of this
"Small Print!" statement.
[3] Pay a trademark license fee to the Project of 20% of the
net profits you derive calculated using the method you
already use to calculate your applicable taxes. If you
don't derive profits, no royalty is due. Royalties are
payable to "Project Gutenberg Association/Carnegie-Mellon
University" within the 60 days following each
date you prepare (or were legally required to prepare)
your annual (or equivalent periodic) tax return.
WHAT IF YOU *WANT* TO SEND MONEY EVEN IF YOU DON'T HAVE TO?
The Project gratefully accepts contributions in money, time,
scanning machines, OCR software, public domain etexts, royalty
free copyright licenses, and every other sort of contribution
you can think of. Money should be paid to "Project Gutenberg
Association / Carnegie-Mellon University".
*END*THE SMALL PRINT! FOR PUBLIC DOMAIN ETEXTS*Ver.04.29.93*END*
RUSSIA
by
Donald Mackenzie Wallace
Copyright 1905
Contents
Preface
CHAPTER I
TRAVELLING IN RUSSIA
Railways--State Interference--River Communications--Russian "Grand
Tour"--The Volga--Kazan--Zhigulinskiya Gori--Finns and Tartars--The
Don--Difficulties of Navigation--Discomforts--Rats--Hotels and
Their Peculiar Customs--Roads--Hibernian Phraseology Explained--
Bridges--Posting--A Tarantass--Requisites for Travelling--
Travelling in Winter--Frostbitten--Disagreeable Episodes--Scene at
a Post-Station.
CHAPTER II
IN THE NORTHERN FORESTS
Bird's-eye View of Russia--The Northern Forests--Purpose of my
Journey--Negotiations--The Road--A Village--A Peasant's House--
Vapour-Baths--Curious Custom--Arrival.
CHAPTER III
VOLUNTARY EXILE
Ivanofka--History of the Place--The Steward of the Estate--Slav and
Teutonic Natures--A German's View of the Emancipation--Justices of
the Peace--New School of Morals--The Russian Language--Linguistic
Talent of the Russians--My Teacher--A Big Dose of Current History.
CHAPTER IV
THE VILLAGE PRIEST
Priests' Names--Clerical Marriages--The White and the Black Clergy--
Why the People do not Respect the Parish Priests--History of the
White Clergy--The Parish Priest and the Protestant Pastor--In What
Sense the Russian People are Religious--Icons--The Clergy and
Popular Education--Ecclesiastical Reform--Premonitory Symptoms of
Change--Two Typical Specimens of the Parochial Clergy of the
Present Day.
CHAPTER V
A MEDICAL CONSULTATION
Unexpected Illness--A Village Doctor--Siberian Plague--My Studies--
Russian Historians--A Russian Imitator of Dickens--A ci-devant
Domestic Serf--Medicine and Witchcraft--A Remnant of Paganism--
Credulity of the Peasantry--Absurd Rumours--A Mysterious Visit from
St. Barbara--Cholera on Board a Steamer--Hospitals--Lunatic
Asylums--Amongst Maniacs.
CHAPTER VI
A PEASANT FAMILY OF THE OLD TYPE
Ivan Petroff--His Past Life--Co-operative Associations--
Constitution of a Peasant's Household--Predominance of Economic
Conceptions over those of Blood-relationship--Peasant Marriages--
Advantages of Living in Large Families--Its Defects--Family
Disruptions and their Consequences.
CHAPTER VII
THE PEASANTRY OF THE NORTH
Communal Land--System of Agriculture--Parish Fetes--Fasting--
Winter Occupations--Yearly Migrations--Domestic Industries--
Influence of Capital and Wholesale Enterprise--The State Peasants--
Serf-dues--Buckle's "History of Civilisation"--A precocious
Yamstchik--"People Who Play Pranks"--A Midnight Alarm--The Far
North.
CHAPTER VIII
THE MIR, OR VILLAGE COMMUNITY
Social and Political Importance of the Mir--The Mir and the Family
Compared--Theory of the Communal System--Practical Deviations from
the Theory--The Mir a Good Specimen of Constitutional Government of
the Extreme Democratic Type--The Village Assembly--Female Members--
The Elections--Distribution of the Communal Land.
CHAPTER IX
HOW THE COMMUNE HAS BEEN PRESERVED, AND WHAT IT IS TO EFFECT IN THE
FUTURE
Sweeping Reforms after the Crimean War--Protest Against the Laissez
Faire Principle--Fear of the Proletariat--English and Russian
Methods of Legislation Contrasted--Sanguine Expectations--Evil
Consequences of the Communal System--The Commune of the Future--
Proletariat of the Towns--The Present State of Things Merely
Temporary.
CHAPTER X
FINNISH AND TARTAR VILLAGES
A Finnish Tribe--Finnish Villages--Various Stages of Russification--
Finnish Women--Finnish Religions--Method of "Laying" Ghosts--
Curious Mixture of Christianity and Paganism--Conversion of the
Finns--A Tartar Village--A Russian Peasant's Conception of
Mahometanism--A Mahometan's View of Christianity--Propaganda--The
Russian Colonist--Migrations of Peoples During the Dark Ages.
CHAPTER XI
LORD NOVGOROD THE GREAT
Departure from Ivanofka and Arrival at Novgorod--The Eastern Half
of the Town--The Kremlin--An Old Legend--The Armed Men of Rus--The
Northmen--Popular Liberty in Novgorod--The Prince and the Popular
Assembly--Civil Dissensions and Faction-fights-- The Commercial
Republic Conquered by the Muscovite Tsars--Ivan the Terrible--
Present Condition of the Town--Provincial Society--Card-playing--
Periodicals--"Eternal Stillness."
CHAPTER XII
THE TOWNS AND THE MERCANTILE CLASSES
General Character of Russian Towns--Scarcity of Towns in Russia--
Why the Urban Element in the Population is so Small--History of
Russian Municipal Institutions--Unsuccessful Efforts to Create a
Tiers-etat--Merchants, Burghers, and Artisans--Town Council--A Rich
Merchant--His House--His Love of Ostentation--His Conception of
Aristocracy--Official Decorations--Ignorance and Dishonesty of the
Commercial Classes--Symptoms of Change.
CHAPTER XIII
THE PASTORAL TRIBES OF THE STEPPE
A Journey to the Steppe Region of the Southeast--The Volga--Town
and Province of Samara--Farther Eastward--Appearance of the
Villages--Characteristic Incident--Peasant Mendacity--Explanation
of the Phenomenon--I Awake in Asia--A Bashkir Aoul--Diner la
Tartare--Kumyss--A Bashkir Troubadour--Honest Mehemet Zian--Actual
Economic Condition of the Bashkirs Throws Light on a Well-known
Philosophical Theory--Why a Pastoral Race Adopts Agriculture--The
Genuine Steppe--The Kirghiz--Letter from Genghis Khan--The Kalmyks--
Nogai Tartars--Struggle between Nomadic Hordes and Agricultural
Colonists.
CHAPTER XIV
THE MONGOL DOMINATION
The Conquest--Genghis Khan and his People--Creation and Rapid
Disintegration of the Mongol Empire--The Golden Horde--The Real
Character of the Mongol Domination--Religious Toleration--Mongol
System of Government--Grand Princes--The Princes of Moscow--
Influence of the Mongol Domination--Practical Importance of the
Subject.
CHAPTER XV
THE COSSACKS
Lawlessness on the Steppe--Slave-markets of the Crimea--The
Military Cordon and the Free Cossacks--The Zaporovian Commonwealth
Compared with Sparta and with the Mediaeval Military Orders--The
Cossacks of the Don, of the Volga, and of the Ural--Border Warfare--
The Modern Cossacks--Land Tenure among the Cossacks of the Don--
The Transition from Pastoral to Agriculture Life--"Universal Law"
of Social Development--Communal versus Private Property--Flogging
as a Means of Land-registration.
CHAPTER XVI
FOREIGN COLONISTS ON THE STEPPE
The Steppe--Variety of Races, Languages, and Religions--The German
Colonists--In What Sense the Russians are an Imitative People--The
Mennonites--Climate and Arboriculture--Bulgarian Colonists--Tartar-
Speaking Greeks--Jewish Agriculturists--Russification--A Circassian
Scotchman--Numerical Strength of the Foreign Element.
CHAPTER XVII
AMONG THE HERETICS
The Molokanye--My Method of Investigation--Alexandrof-Hai--An
Unexpected Theological Discussion--Doctrines and Ecclesiastical
Organisation of the Molokanye--Moral Supervision and Mutual
Assistance--History of the Sect--A False Prophet--Utilitarian
Christianity--Classification of the Fantastic Sects--The "Khlysti"--
Policy of the Government towards Sectarianism--Two Kinds of
Heresy--Probable Future of the Heretical Sects--Political
Disaffection.
CHAPTER XVIII
THE DISSENTERS
Dissenters not to be Confounded with Heretics--Extreme Importance
Attached to Ritual Observances--The Raskol, or Great Schism in the
Seventeenth Century--Antichrist Appears!--Policy of Peter the Great
and Catherine II.--Present Ingenious Method of Securing Religious
Toleration--Internal Development of the Raskol--Schism among the
Schismatics--The Old Ritualists--The Priestless People--Cooling of
the Fanatical Enthusiasm and Formation of New Sects--Recent Policy
of the Government towards the Sectarians--Numerical Force and
Political Significance of Sectarianism.
CHAPTER XIX
CHURCH AND STATE
The Russian Orthodox Church--Russia Outside of the Mediaeval Papal
Commonwealth--Influence of the Greek Church--Ecclesiastical History
of Russia--Relations between Church and State--Eastern Orthodoxy
and the Russian National Church--The Synod--Ecclesiastical
Grumbling--Local Ecclesiastical Administration--The Black Clergy
and the Monasteries--The Character of the Eastern Church Reflected
in the History of Religious Art--Practical Consequences--The Union
Scheme.
CHAPTER XX
THE NOBLESSE
The Nobles In Early Times--The Mongol Domination--The Tsardom of
Muscovy--Family Dignity--Reforms of Peter the Great--The Nobles
Adopt West-European Conceptions--Abolition of Obligatory Service--
Influence of Catherine II.--The Russian Dvoryanstvo Compared with
the French Noblesse and the English Aristocracy--Russian Titles--
Probable Future of the Russian Noblesse.
CHAPTER XXI
LANDED PROPRIETORS OF THE OLD SCHOOL
Russian Hospitality--A Country-House--Its Owner Described--His
Life, Past and Present--Winter Evenings--Books---Connection with
the Outer World--The Crimean War and the Emancipation--A Drunken,
Dissolute Proprietor--An Old General and his Wife--"Name Days"--A
Legendary Monster--A Retired Judge--A Clever Scribe--Social
Leniency--Cause of Demoralisation.
CHAPTER XXII
PROPRIETORS OF THE MODERN SCHOOL
A Russian Petit Maitre--His House and Surroundings--Abortive
Attempts to Improve Agriculture and the Condition of the Serfs--A
Comparison--A 'Liberal" Tchinovnik--His Idea of Progress--A Justice
of the Peace--His Opinion of Russian Literature, Tchinovniks, and
Petits Maitres--His Supposed and Real Character--An Extreme
Radical--Disorders in the Universities--Administrative Procedure--
Russia's Capacity for Accomplishing Political and Social
Evolutions--A Court Dignitary in his Country House.
CHAPTER XXIII
SOCIAL CLASSES
Do Social Classes or Castes Exist in Russia?--Well-marked Social
Types--Classes Recognised by the Legislation and the Official
Statistics--Origin and Gradual Formation of these Classes--
Peculiarity in the Historical Development of Russia--Political Life
and Political Parties.
CHAPTER XXIV
THE IMPERIAL ADMINISTRATION AND THE OFFICIALS
The Officials in Norgorod Assist Me in My Studies--The Modern
Imperial Administration Created by Peter the Great, and Developed
by his Successors--A Slavophil's View of the Administration--The
Administration Briefly Described--The Tchinovniks, or Officials--
Official Titles, and Their Real Significance--What the
Administration Has Done for Russia in the Past--Its Character
Determined by the Peculiar Relation between the Government and the
People--Its Radical Vices--Bureaucratic Remedies--Complicated
Formal Procedure--The Gendarmerie: My Personal Relations with this
Branch of the Administration; Arrest and Release--A Strong, Healthy
Public Opinion the Only Effectual Remedy for Bad Administration.
CHAPTER XXV
MOSCOW AND THE SLAVOPHILS
Two Ancient Cities--Kief Not a Good Point for Studying Old Russian
National Life--Great Russians and Little Russians--Moscow--Easter
Eve in the Kremlin--Curious Custom--Anecdote of the Emperor
Nicholas--Domiciliary Visits of the Iberian Madonna--The Streets of
Moscow--Recent Changes in the Character of the City--Vulgar
Conception of the Slavophils--Opinion Founded on Personal
Acquaintance--Slavophil Sentiment a Century Ago--Origin and
Development of the Slavophil Doctrine--Slavophilism Essentially
Muscovite--The Panslavist Element--The Slavophils and the
Emancipation.
CHAPTER XXVI
ST. PETERSBURG AND EUROPEAN INFLUENCE
St. Petersburg and Berlin--Big Houses--The "Lions"--Peter the
Great--His Aims and Policy--The German Regime--Nationalist
Reaction--French Influence--Consequent Intellectual Sterility--
Influence of the Sentimental School--Hostility to Foreign
Influences--A New Period of Literary Importation--Secret Societies--
The Catastrophe--The Age of Nicholas--A Terrible War on Parnassus--
Decline of Romanticism and Transcendentalism--Gogol--The
Revolutionary Agitation of 1848--New Reaction--Conclusion.
CHAPTER XXVII
THE CRIMEAN WAR AND ITS CONSEQUENCES
The Emperor Nicholas and his System--The Men with Aspirations and
the Apathetically Contented--National Humiliation--Popular
Discontent and the Manuscript Literature--Death of Nicholas--
Alexander II.--New Spirit--Reform Enthusiasm--Change in the
Periodical Literature--The Kolokol--The Conservatives--The
Tchinovniks--First Specific Proposals--Joint-Stock Companies--The
Serf Question Comes to the Front.
CHAPTER XXVIII
THE SERFS
The Rural Population in Ancient Times--The Peasantry in the
Eighteenth Century--How Was This Change Effected?--The Common
Explanation Inaccurate--Serfage the Result of Permanent Economic
and Political Causes--Origin of the Adscriptio Glebae--Its
Consequences--Serf Insurrection--Turning-point in the History of
Serfage--Serfage in Russia and in Western Europe--State Peasants--
Numbers and Geographical Distribution of the Serf Population--Serf
Dues--Legal and Actual Power of the Proprietors--The Serfs' Means
of Defence--Fugitives--Domestic Serfs--Strange Advertisements in
the Moscow Gazette--Moral Influence of Serfage.
CHAPTER XXIX
THE EMANCIPATION OF THE SERFS
The Question Raised--Chief Committee--The Nobles of the Lithuanian
Provinces--The Tsar's Broad Hint to the Noblesse--Enthusiasm in the
Press--The Proprietors--Political Aspirations--No Opposition--The
Government--Public Opinion--Fear of the Proletariat--The Provincial
Committees--The Elaboration Commission--The Question Ripens--
Provincial Deputies--Discontent and Demonstrations--The Manifesto--
Fundamental Principles of the Law--Illusions and Disappointment of
the Serfs--Arbiters of the Peace--A Characteristic Incident--
Redemption--Who Effected the Emancipation?
CHAPTER XXX
THE LANDED PROPRIETORS SINCE THE EMANCIPATION
Two Opposite Opinions--Difficulties of Investigation--The Problem
Simplified--Direct and Indirect Compensation--The Direct
Compensation Inadequate--What the Proprietors Have Done with the
Remainder of Their Estates--Immediate Moral Effect of the Abolition
of Serfage--The Economic Problem--The Ideal Solution and the
Difficulty of Realising It--More Primitive Arrangements--The
Northern Agricultural Zone--The Black-earth Zone--The Labour
Difficulty--The Impoverishment of the Noblesse Not a New
Phenomenon--Mortgaging of Estates--Gradual Expropriation of the
Noblesse-Rapid Increase in the Production and Export of Grain--How
Far this Has Benefited the Landed Proprietors.
CHAPTER XXXI
THE EMANCIPATED PEASANTRY
The Effects of Liberty--Difficulty of Obtaining Accurate
Information--Pessimist Testimony of the Proprietors--Vague Replies
of the Peasants--My Conclusions in 1877--Necessity of Revising
Them--My Investigations Renewed in 1903--Recent Researches by
Native Political Economists--Peasant Impoverishment Universally
Recognised--Various Explanations Suggested--Demoralisation of the
Common People--Peasant Self-government--Communal System of Land
Tenure--Heavy Taxation--Disruption of Peasant Families--Natural
Increase of Population--Remedies Proposed--Migration--Reclamation
of Waste Land--Land-purchase by Peasantry--Manufacturing Industry--
Improvement of Agricultural Methods--Indications of Progress.
CHAPTER XXXII
THE ZEMSTVO AND THE LOCAL SELF-GOVERNMENT
Necessity of Reorganising the Provincial Administration--Zemstvo
Created in 1864--My First Acquaintance with the Institution--
District and Provincial Assemblies--The Leading Members--Great
Expectations Created by the Institution--These Expectations Not
Realised--Suspicions and Hostility of the Bureaucracy--Zemstvo
Brought More Under Control of the Centralised Administration--What
It Has Really Done--Why It Has Not Done More---Rapid Increase of
the Rates--How Far the Expenditure Is Judicious--Why the
Impoverishment of the Peasantry Was Neglected--Unpractical,
Pedantic Spirit--Evil Consequences--Chinese and Russian Formalism--
Local Self-Government of Russia Contrasted with That of England--
Zemstvo Better than Its Predecessors--Its Future.
CHAPTER XXXIII
THE NEW LAW COURTS
Judicial Procedure in the Olden Times--Defects and Abuses--Radical
Reform--The New System--Justices of the Peace and Monthly Sessions--
The Regular Tribunals--Court of Revision--Modification of the
Original Plan--How Does the System Work?--Rapid Acclimatisation--
The Bench--The Jury--Acquittal of Criminals Who Confess Their
Crimes--Peasants, Merchants, and Nobles as Jurymen--Independence
and Political Significance of the New Courts.
CHAPTER XXXIV
REVOLUTIONARY NIHILISM AND THE REACTION
The Reform-enthusiasm Becomes Unpractical and Culminates in
Nihilism--Nihilism, the Distorted Reflection of Academic Western
Socialism--Russia Well Prepared for Reception of Ultra-Socialist
Virus--Social Reorganisation According to Latest Results of
Science--Positivist Theory--Leniency of Press-censure--Chief
Representatives of New Movement--Government Becomes Alarmed--
Repressive Measures--Reaction in the Public--The Term Nihilist
Invented--The Nihilist and His Theory--Further Repressive Measures--
Attitude of Landed Proprietors--Foundation of a Liberal Party--
Liberalism Checked by Polish Insurrection--Practical Reform
Continued--An Attempt at Regicide Forms a Turning-point of
Government's Policy--Change in Educational System--Decline of
Nihilism.
CHAPTER XXXV
SOCIALIST PROPAGANDA, REVOLUTIONARY AGITATION, AND TERRORISM
Closer Relations with Western Socialism--Attempts to Influence the
Masses--Bakunin and Lavroff--"Going in among the People"--The
Missionaries of Revolutionary Socialism--Distinction between
Propaganda and Agitation--Revolutionary Pamphlets for the Common
People--Aims and Motives of the Propagandists--Failure of
Propaganda--Energetic Repression--Fruitless Attempts at Agitation--
Proposal to Combine with Liberals--Genesis of Terrorism--My
Personal Relations with the Revolutionists--Shadowers and Shadowed--
A Series of Terrorist Crimes--A Revolutionist Congress--
Unsuccessful Attempts to Assassinate the Tsar--Ineffectual Attempt
at Conciliation by Loris Melikof--Assassination of Alexander II.--
The Executive Committee Shows Itself Unpractical--Widespread
Indignation and Severe Repression--Temporary Collapse of the
Revolutionary Movement--A New Revolutionary Movement in Sight.
CHAPTER XXXVI
INDUSTRIAL PROGRESS AND THE PROLETARIAT
Russia till Lately a Peasant Empire--Early Efforts to Introduce
Arts and Crafts--Peter the Great and His Successors--Manufacturing
Industry Long Remains an Exotic--The Cotton Industry--The Reforms
of Alexander II.--Protectionists and Free Trade--Progress under
High Tariffs--M. Witte's Policy--How Capital Was Obtained--Increase
of Exports--Foreign Firms Cross the Customs Frontier--Rapid
Development of Iron Industry--A Commercial Crisis--M. Witte's
Position Undermined by Agrarians and Doctrinaires--M. Plehve a
Formidable Opponent--His Apprehensions of Revolution--Fall of M.
Witte--The Industrial Proletariat
CHAPTER XXXVII
THE REVOLUTIONARY MOVEMENT IN ITS LATEST PHASE
Influence of Capitalism and Proletariat on the Revolutionary
Movement--What is to be Done?--Reply of Plekhanof--A New Departure--
Karl Marx's Theories Applied to Russia--Beginnings of a Social
Democratic Movement--The Labour Troubles of 1894-96 in St.
Petersburg--The Social Democrats' Plan of Campaign--Schism in the
Party--Trade-unionism and Political Agitation--The Labour Troubles
of 1902--How the Revolutionary Groups are Differentiated from Each
Other--Social Democracy and Constitutionalism--Terrorism--The
Socialist Revolutionaries--The Militant Organisation--Attitude of
the Government--Factory Legislation--Government's Scheme for
Undermining Social Democracy--Father Gapon and His Labour
Association--The Great Strike in St. Petersburg--Father Gapon goes
over to the Revolutionaries.
CHAPTER XXXVIII
TERRITORIAL EXPANSION AND FOREIGN POLICY
Rapid Growth of Russia--Expansive Tendency of Agricultural Peoples--
The Russo-Slavonians--The Northern Forest and the Steppe--
Colonisation--The Part of the Government in the Process of
Expansion--Expansion towards the West--Growth of the Empire
Represented in a Tabular Form--Commercial Motive for Expansion--The
Expansive Force in the Future--Possibilities of Expansion in
Europe--Persia, Afghanistan, and India--Trans-Siberian Railway and
Weltpolitik--A Grandiose Scheme--Determined Opposition of Japan--
Negotiations and War--Russia's Imprudence Explained--Conclusion.
CHAPTER XXXIX
THE PRESENT SITUATION
Reform or Revolution?--Reigns of Alexander II. and Nicholas II.
Compared and Contrasted--The Present Opposition--Various Groups--
The Constitutionalists--Zemski Sobors--The Young Tsar Dispels
Illusions--Liberal Frondeurs--Plehve's Repressive Policy--
Discontent Increased by the War--Relaxation and Wavering under
Prince Mirski--Reform Enthusiasm--The Constitutionalists Formulate
their Demands--The Social Democrats--Father Gapon's Demonstration--
The Socialist-Revolutionaries--The Agrarian Agitators--The Subject-
Nationalities--Numerical Strength of the Various Groups--All United
on One Point--Their Different Aims--Possible Solutions of the
Crisis--Difficulties of Introducing Constitutional Regime--A Strong
Man Wanted--Uncertainty of the Future.
PREFACE
The first edition of this work, published early in January, 1877,
contained the concentrated results of my studies during an
uninterrupted residence of six years in Russia--from the beginning
of 1870 to the end of 1875. Since that time I have spent in the
European and Central Asian provinces, at different periods, nearly
two years more; and in the intervals I have endeavoured to keep in
touch with the progress of events. My observations thus extend
over a period of thirty-five years.
When I began, a few months ago, to prepare for publication the
results of my more recent observations and researches, my intention
was to write an entirely new work under the title of "Russia in the
Twentieth Century," but I soon perceived that it would be
impossible to explain clearly the present state of things without
referring constantly to events of the past, and that I should be
obliged to embody in the new work a large portion of the old one.
The portion to be embodied grew rapidly to such proportions that,
in the course of a few weeks, I began to ask myself whether it
would not be better simply to recast and complete my old material.
With a view to deciding the question I prepared a list of the
principal changes which had taken place during the last quarter of
a century, and when I had marshalled them in logical order, I
recognised that they were neither so numerous nor so important as I
had supposed. Certainly there had been much progress, but it had
been nearly all on the old lines. Everywhere I perceived
continuity and evolution; nowhere could I discover radical changes
and new departures. In the central and local administration the
reactionary policy of the latter half of Alexander II.'s reign had
been steadily maintained; the revolutionary movement had waxed and
waned, but its aims were essentially the same as of old; the Church
had remained in its usual somnolent condition; a grave agricultural
crisis affecting landed proprietors and peasants had begun, but it
was merely a development of a state of things which I had
previously described; the manufacturing industry had made gigantic
strides, but they were all in the direction which the most
competent observers had predicted; in foreign policy the old
principles of guiding the natural expansive forces along the lines
of least resistance, seeking to reach warm-water ports, and pegging
out territorial claims for the future were persistently followed.
No doubt there were pretty clear indications of more radical
changes to come, but these changes must belong to the future, and
it is merely with the past and the present that a writer who has no
pretensions to being a prophet has to deal.
Under these circumstances it seemed to me advisable to adopt a
middle course. Instead of writing an entirely new work I
determined to prepare a much extended and amplified edition of the
old one, retaining such information about the past as seemed to me
of permanent value, and at the same time meeting as far as possible
the requirements of those who wish to know the present condition of
the country.
In accordance with this view I have revised, rearranged, and
supplemented the old material in the light of subsequent events,
and I have added five entirely new chapters--three on the
revolutionary movement, which has come into prominence since 1877;
one on the industrial progress, with which the latest phase of the
movement is closely connected; and one on the main lines of the
present situation as it appears to me at the moment of going to
press.
During the many years which I have devoted to the study of Russia,
I have received unstinted assistance from many different quarters.
Of the friends who originally facilitated my task, and to whom I
expressed my gratitude in the preface and notes of the early
editions, only three survive--Mme. de Novikoff, M. E. I. Yakushkin,
and Dr. Asher. To the numerous friends who have kindly assisted me
in the present edition I must express my thanks collectively, but
there are two who stand out from the group so prominently that I
may be allowed to mention them personally: these are Prince
Alexander Grigorievitch Stcherbatof, who supplied me with
voluminous materials regarding the agrarian question generally and
the present condition of the peasantry in particular, and M. Albert
Brockhaus, who placed at my disposal the gigantic Russian
Encyclopaedia recently published by his firm (Entsiklopeditcheski
Slovar, Leipzig and St. Petersburg, 1890-1904). This monumental
work, in forty-one volumes, is an inexhaustible storehouse of
accurate and well-digested information on all subjects connected
with the Russian Empire, and it has often been of great use to me
in matters of detail.
With regard to the last chapter of this edition I must claim the
reader's indulgence, because the meaning of the title, "the present
situation," changes from day to day, and I cannot foresee what
further changes may occur before the work reaches the hands of the
public.
LONDON, 22nd May, 1905.
RUSSIA
CHAPTER I
TRAVELLING IN RUSSIA
Railways--State Interference--River Communications--Russian "Grand
Tour"--The Volga--Kazan--Zhigulinskiya Gori--Finns and Tartars--The
Don--Difficulties of Navigation--Discomforts--Rats--Hotels and
Their Peculiar Customs--Roads--Hibernian Phraseology Explained--
Bridges--Posting--A Tarantass--Requisites for Travelling--
Travelling in Winter--Frostbitten--Disagreeable Episodes--Scene at
a Post-Station.
Of course travelling in Russia is no longer what it was. During
the last half century a vast network of railways has been
constructed, and one can now travel in a comfortable first-class
carriage from Berlin to St. Petersburg or Moscow, and thence to
Odessa, Sebastopol, the Lower Volga, the Caucasus, Central Asia, or
Eastern Siberia. Until the outbreak of the war there was a train
twice a week, with through carriages, from Moscow to Port Arthur.
And it must be admitted that on the main lines the passengers have
not much to complain of. The carriages are decidedly better than
in England, and in winter they are kept warm by small iron stoves,
assisted by double windows and double doors--a very necessary
precaution in a land where the thermometer often descends to 30
degrees below zero. The train never attains, it is true, a high
rate of speed--so at least English and Americans think--but then we
must remember that Russians are rarely in a hurry, and like to have
frequent opportunities of eating and drinking. In Russia time is
not money; if it were, nearly all the subjects of the Tsar would
always have a large stock of ready money on hand, and would often
have great difficulty in spending it. In reality, be it
parenthetically remarked, a Russian with a superabundance of ready
money is a phenomenon rarely met with in real life.
In conveying passengers at the rate of from fifteen to thirty miles
an hour, the railway companies do at least all that they promise;
but in one very important respect they do not always strictly
fulfil their engagements. The traveller takes a ticket for a
certain town, and on arriving at what he imagines to be his
destination, he may find merely a railway-station surrounded by
fields. On making inquiries, he discovers, to his disappointment,
that the station is by no means identical with the town bearing the
same name, and that the railway has fallen several miles short of
fulfilling the bargain, as he understood the terms of the contract.
Indeed, it might almost be said that as a general rule railways in
Russia, like camel-drivers in certain Eastern countries, studiously
avoid the towns. This seems at first a strange fact. It is
possible to conceive that the Bedouin is so enamoured of tent life
and nomadic habits that he shuns a town as he would a man-trap; but
surely civil engineers and railway contractors have no such dread
of brick and mortar. The true reason, I suspect, is that land
within or immediately beyond the municipal barrier is relatively
dear, and that the railways, being completely beyond the
invigorating influence of healthy competition, can afford to look
upon the comfort and convenience of passengers as a secondary
consideration. Gradually, it is true, this state of things is
being improved by private initiative. As the railways refuse to
come to the towns, the towns are extending towards the railways,
and already some prophets are found bold enough to predict that in
the course of time those long, new, straggling streets, without an
inhabited hinterland, which at present try so severely the springs
of the ricketty droshkis, will be properly paved and kept in decent
repair. For my own part, I confess I am a little sceptical with
regard to this prediction, and I can only use a favourite
expression of the Russian peasants--dai Bog! God grant it may be
so!
It is but fair to state that in one celebrated instance neither
engineers nor railway contractors were directly to blame. From St.
Petersburg to Moscow the locomotive runs for a distance of 400
miles almost as "the crow" is supposed to fly, turning neither to
the right hand nor to the left. For twelve weary hours the
passenger in the express train looks out on forest and morass, and
rarely catches sight of human habitation. Only once he perceives
in the distance what may be called a town; it is Tver which has
been thus favoured, not because it is a place of importance, but
simply because it happened to be near the bee-line. And why was
the railway constructed in this extraordinary fashion? For the
best of all reasons--because the Tsar so ordered it. When the
preliminary survey was being made, Nicholas I. learned that the
officers entrusted with the task--and the Minister of Ways and
Roads in the number--were being influenced more by personal than
technical considerations, and he determined to cut the Gordian knot
in true Imperial style. When the Minister laid before him the map
with the intention of explaining the proposed route, he took a
ruler, drew a straight line from the one terminus to the other, and
remarked in a tone that precluded all discussion, "You will
construct the line so!" And the line was so constructed--remaining
to all future ages, like St. Petersburg and the Pyramids, a
magnificent monument of autocratic power.
Formerly this well-known incident was often cited in whispered
philippics to illustrate the evils of the autocratic form of
government. Imperial whims, it was said, over-ride grave economic
considerations. In recent years, however, a change seems to have
taken place in public opinion, and some people now assert that this
so-called Imperial whim was an act of far-seeing policy. As by far
the greater part of the goods and passengers are carried the whole
length of the line, it is well that the line should be as short as
possible, and that branch lines should be constructed to the towns
lying to the right and left. Evidently there is a good deal to be
said in favour of this view.
In the development of the railway system there has been another
disturbing cause, which is not likely to occur to the English mind.
In England, individuals and companies habitually act according to
their private interests, and the State interferes as little as
possible; private initiative does as it pleases, unless the
authorities can prove that important bad consequences will
necessarily result. In Russia, the onus probandi lies on the other
side; private initiative is allowed to do nothing until it gives
guarantees against all possible bad consequences. When any great
enterprise is projected, the first question is--"How will this new
scheme affect the interests of the State?" Thus, when the course
of a new railway has to be determined, the military authorities are
among the first to be consulted, and their opinion has a great
influence on the ultimate decision. The natural consequence is
that the railway-map of Russia presents to the eye of the
strategist much that is quite unintelligible to the ordinary
observer--a fact that will become apparent even to the uninitiated
as soon as a war breaks out in Eastern Europe. Russia is no longer
what she was in the days of the Crimean War, when troops and stores
had to be conveyed hundreds of miles by the most primitive means of
transport. At that time she had only 750 miles of railway; now she
has over 36,000 miles, and every year new lines are constructed.
The water-communication has likewise in recent years been greatly
improved. On the principal rivers there are now good steamers.
Unfortunately, the climate puts serious obstructions in the way of
navigation. For nearly half of the year the rivers are covered
with ice, and during a great part of the open season navigation is
difficult. When the ice and snow melt the rivers overflow their
banks and lay a great part of the low-lying country under water, so
that many villages can only be approached in boats; but very soon
the flood subsides, and the water falls so rapidly that by
midsummer the larger steamers have great difficulty in picking
their way among the sandbanks. The Neva alone--that queen of
northern rivers--has at all times a plentiful supply of water.
Besides the Neva, the rivers commonly visited by the tourist are
the Volga and the Don, which form part of what may be called the
Russian grand tour. Englishmen who wish to see something more than
St. Petersburg and Moscow generally go by rail to Nizhni-Novgorod,
where they visit the great fair, and then get on board one of the
Volga steamers. For those who have mastered the important fact
that Russia is not a country of fine scenery, the voyage down the
river is pleasant enough. The left bank is as flat as the banks of
the Rhine below Cologne, but the right bank is high, occasionally
well wooded, and not devoid of a certain tame picturesqueness.
Early on the second day the steamer reaches Kazan, once the capital
of an independent Tartar khanate, and still containing a
considerable Tartar population. Several metchets (as the Mahometan
houses of prayer are here termed), with their diminutive minarets
in the lower part of the town, show that Islamism still survives,
though the khanate was annexed to Muscovy more than three centuries
ago; but the town, as a whole, has a European rather than an
Asiatic character. If any one visits it in the hope of getting "a
glimpse of the East," he will be grievously disappointed, unless,
indeed, he happens to be one of those imaginative tourists who
always discover what they wish to see. And yet it must be admitted
that, of all the towns on the route, Kazan is the most interesting.
Though not Oriental, it has a peculiar character of its own, whilst
all the others--Simbirsk, Samara, Saratof--are as uninteresting as
Russian provincial towns commonly are. The full force and
solemnity of that expression will be explained in the sequel.
Probably about sunrise on the third day something like a range of
mountains will appear on the horizon. It may be well to say at
once, to prevent disappointment, that in reality nothing worthy of
the name of mountain is to be found in that part of the country.
The nearest mountain-range in that direction is the Caucasus, which
is hundreds of miles distant, and consequently cannot by any
possibility be seen from the deck of a steamer. The elevations in
question are simply a low range of hills, called the Zhigulinskiya
Gori. In Western Europe they would not attract much attention, but
"in the kingdom of the blind," as the French proverb has it, "the
one-eyed man is king"; and in a flat region like Eastern Russia
these hills form a prominent feature. Though they have nothing of
Alpine grandeur, yet their well-wooded slopes, coming down to the
water's edge--especially when covered with the delicate tints of
early spring, or the rich yellow and red of autumnal foliage--leave
an impression on the memory not easily effaced.
On the whole--with all due deference to the opinions of my
patriotic Russian friends--I must say that Volga scenery hardly
repays the time, trouble and expense which a voyage from Nizhni to
Tsaritsin demands. There are some pretty bits here and there, but
they are "few and far between." A glass of the most exquisite wine
diluted with a gallon of water makes a very insipid beverage. The
deck of the steamer is generally much more interesting than the
banks of the river. There one meets with curious travelling
companions. The majority of the passengers are probably Russian
peasants, who are always ready to chat freely without demanding a
formal introduction, and to relate--with certain restrictions--to a
new acquaintance the simple story of their lives. Often I have
thus whiled away the weary hours both pleasantly and profitably,
and have always been impressed with the peasant's homely common
sense, good-natured kindliness, half-fatalistic resignation, and
strong desire to learn something about foreign countries. This
last peculiarity makes him question as well as communicate, and his
questions, though sometimes apparently childish, are generally to
the point.
Among the passengers are probably also some representatives of the
various Finnish tribes inhabiting this part of the country; they
may be interesting to the ethnologist who loves to study
physiognomy, but they are far less sociable than the Russians.
Nature seems to have made them silent and morose, whilst their
conditions of life have made them shy and distrustful. The Tartar,
on the other hand, is almost sure to be a lively and amusing
companion. Most probably he is a peddler or small trader of some
kind. The bundle on which he reclines contains his stock-in-trade,
composed, perhaps, of cotton printed goods and especially bright-
coloured cotton handkerchiefs. He himself is enveloped in a
capacious greasy khalat, or dressing-gown, and wears a fur cap,
though the thermometer may be at 90 degrees in the shade. The
roguish twinkle in his small piercing eyes contrasts strongly with
the sombre, stolid expression of the Finnish peasants sitting near
him. He has much to relate about St. Petersburg, Moscow, and
perhaps Astrakhan; but, like a genuine trader, he is very reticent
regarding the mysteries of his own craft. Towards sunset he
retires with his companions to some quiet spot on the deck to
recite evening prayers. Here all the good Mahometans on board
assemble and stroke their beards, kneel on their little strips of
carpet and prostrate themselves, all keeping time as if they were
performing some new kind of drill under the eve of a severe drill-
sergeant.
If the voyage is made about the end of September, when the traders
are returning home from the fair at Nizhni-Novgorod, the
ethnologist will have a still better opportunity of study. He will
then find not only representatives of the Finnish and Tartar races,
but also Armenians, Circassians, Persians, Bokhariots, and other
Orientals--a motley and picturesque but decidedly unsavoury cargo.
However great the ethnographical variety on board may be, the
traveller will probably find that four days on the Volga are quite
enough for all practical and aesthetic purposes, and instead of
going on to Astrakhan he will quit the steamer at Tsaritsin. Here
he will find a railway of about fifty miles in length, connecting
the Volga and the Don. I say advisedly a railway, and not a train,
because trains on this line are not very frequent. When I first
visited the locality, thirty years ago, there were only two a week,
so that if you inadvertently missed one train you had to wait about
three days for the next. Prudent, nervous people preferred
travelling by the road, for on the railway the strange jolts and
mysterious creakings were very alarming. On the other hand the
pace was so slow that running off the rails would have been merely
an amusing episode, and even a collision could scarcely have been
attended with serious consequences. Happily things are improving,
even in this outlying part of the country. Now there is one train
daily, and it goes at a less funereal pace.
From Kalatch, at the Don end of the line, a steamer starts for
Rostoff, which is situated near the mouth of the river. The
navigation of the Don is much more difficult than that of the
Volga. The river is extremely shallow, and the sand-banks are
continually shifting, so that many times in the course of the day
the steamer runs aground. Sometimes she is got off by simply
reversing the engines, but not unfrequently she sticks so fast that
the engines have to be assisted. This is effected in a curious
way. The captain always gives a number of stalwart Cossacks a free
passage on condition that they will give him the assistance he
requires; and as soon as the ship sticks fast he orders them to
jump overboard with a stout hawser and haul her off! The task is
not a pleasant one, especially as the poor fellows cannot
afterwards change their clothes; but the order is always obeyed
with alacrity and without grumbling. Cossacks, it would seem, have
no personal acquaintance with colds and rheumatism.
In the most approved manuals of geography the Don figures as one of
the principal European rivers, and its length and breadth give it a
right to be considered as such; but its depth in many parts is
ludicrously out of proportion to its length and breadth. I
remember one day seeing the captain of a large, flat-bottomed
steamer slacken speed, to avoid running down a man on horseback who
was attempting to cross his bows in the middle of the stream.
Another day a not less characteristic incident happened. A Cossack
passenger wished to be set down at a place where there was no pier,
and on being informed that there was no means of landing him,
coolly jumped overboard and walked ashore. This simple method of
disembarking cannot, of course, be recommended to those who have no
local knowledge regarding the exact position of sand-banks and deep
pools.
Good serviceable fellows are those Cossacks who drag the steamer
off the sand-banks, and are often entertaining companions. Many of
them can relate from their own experience, in plain, unvarnished
style, stirring episodes of irregular warfare, and if they happen
to be in a communicative mood they may divulge a few secrets
regarding their simple, primitive commissariat system. Whether
they are confidential or not, the traveller who knows the language
will spend his time more profitably and pleasantly in chatting with
them than in gazing listlessly at the uninteresting country through
which he is passing.
Unfortunately, these Don steamers carry a large number of free
passengers of another and more objectionable kind, who do not
confine themselves to the deck, but unceremoniously find their way
into the cabin, and prevent thin-skinned travellers from sleeping.
I know too little of natural history to decide whether these agile,
bloodthirsty parasites are of the same species as those which in
England assist unofficially the Sanitary Commissioners by punishing
uncleanliness; but I may say that their function in the system of
created things is essentially the same, and they fulfil it with a
zeal and energy beyond all praise. Possessing for my own part a
happy immunity from their indelicate attentions, and being
perfectly innocent of entomological curiosity, I might, had I been
alone, have overlooked their existence, but I was constantly
reminded of their presence by less happily constituted mortals, and
the complaints of the sufferers received a curious official
confirmation. On arriving at the end of the journey I asked
permission to spend the night on board, and I noticed that the
captain acceded to my request with more readiness and warmth than I
expected. Next morning the fact was fully explained. When I began
to express my thanks for having been allowed to pass the night in a
comfortable cabin, my host interrupted me with a good-natured
laugh, and assured me that, on the contrary, he was under
obligations to me. "You see," he said, assuming an air of mock
gravity, "I have always on board a large body of light cavalry, and
when I have all this part of the ship to myself they make a
combined attack on me; whereas, when some one is sleeping close by,
they divide their forces!
On certain steamers on the Sea of Azof the privacy of the sleeping-
cabin is disturbed by still more objectionable intruders; I mean
rats. During one short voyage which I made on board the Kertch,
these disagreeable visitors became so importunate in the lower
regions of the vessel that the ladies obtained permission to sleep
in the deck-saloon. After this arrangement had been made, we
unfortunate male passengers received redoubled attention from our
tormentors. Awakened early one morning by the sensation of
something running over me as I lay in my berth, I conceived a
method of retaliation. It seemed to me possible that, in the event
of another visit, I might, by seizing the proper moment, kick the
rat up to the ceiling with such force as to produce concussion of
the brain and instant death. Very soon I had an opportunity of
putting my plan into execution. A significant shaking of the
little curtain at the foot of the berth showed that it was being
used as a scaling-ladder. I lay perfectly still, quite as much
interested in the sport as if I had been waiting, rifle in hand,
for big game. Soon the intruder peeped into my berth, looked
cautiously around him, and then proceeded to walk stealthily across
my feet. In an instant he was shot upwards. First was heard a
sharp knock on the ceiling, and then a dull "thud" on the floor.
The precise extent of the injuries inflicted I never discovered,
for the victim had sufficient strength and presence of mind to
effect his escape; and the gentleman at the other side of the
cabin, who had been roused by the noise, protested against my
repeating the experiment, on the ground that, though he was willing
to take his own share of the intruders, he strongly objected to
having other people's rats kicked into his berth.
On such occasions it is of no use to complain to the authorities.
When I met the captain on deck I related to him what had happened,
and protested vigorously against passengers being exposed to such
annoyances. After listening to me patiently, he coolly replied,
entirely overlooking my protestations, "Ah! I did better than that
this morning; I allowed my rat to get under the blanket, and then
smothered him!"
Railways and steamboats, even when their arrangements leave much to
be desired, invariably effect a salutary revolution in hotel
accommodation; but this revolution is of necessity gradual.
Foreign hotelkeepers must immigrate and give the example; suitable
houses must be built; servants must be properly trained; and, above
all, the native travellers must learn the usages of civilised
society. In Russia this revolution is in progress, but still far
from being complete. The cities where foreigners most do
congregate--St. Petersburg, Moscow, Odessa--already possess hotels
that will bear comparison with those of Western Europe, and some of
the more important provincial towns can offer very respectable
accommodation; but there is still much to be done before the West-
European can travel with comfort even on the principal routes.
Cleanliness, the first and most essential element of comfort, as we
understand the term, is still a rare commodity, and often cannot be
procured at any price.
Even in good hotels, when they are of the genuine Russian type,
there are certain peculiarities which, though not in themselves
objectionable, strike a foreigner as peculiar. Thus, when you
alight at such an hotel, you are expected to examine a considerable
number of rooms, and to inquire about the respective prices. When
you have fixed upon a suitable apartment, you will do well, if you
wish to practise economy, to propose to the landlord considerably
less than he demands; and you will generally find, if you have a
talent for bargaining, that the rooms may be hired for somewhat
less than the sum first stated. You must be careful, however, to
leave no possibility of doubt as to the terms of the contract.
Perhaps you assume that, as in taking a cab, a horse is always
supplied without special stipulation, so in hiring a bedroom the
bargain includes a bed and the necessary appurtenances. Such an
assumption will not always be justified. The landlord may perhaps
give you a bedstead without extra charge, but if he be uncorrupted
by foreign notions, he will certainly not spontaneously supply you
with bed-linen, pillows, blankets, and towels. On the contrary, he
will assume that you carry all these articles with you, and if you
do not, you must pay for them.
This ancient custom has produced among Russians of the old school a
kind of fastidiousness to which we are strangers. They strongly
dislike using sheets, blankets, and towels which are in a certain
sense public property, just as we should strongly object to putting
on clothes which had been already worn by other people. And the
feeling may be developed in people not Russian by birth. For my
own part, I confess to having been conscious of a certain
disagreeable feeling on returning in this respect to the usages of
so-called civilised Europe.
The inconvenience of carrying about the essential articles of
bedroom furniture is by no means so great as might he supposed.
Bedrooms in Russia are always heated during cold weather, so that
one light blanket, which may be also used as a railway rug, is
quite sufficient, whilst sheets, pillow-cases, and towels take up
little space in a portmanteau. The most cumbrous object is the
pillow, for air-cushions, having a disagreeable odour, are not well
suited for the purpose. But Russians are accustomed to this
encumbrance. In former days--as at the present time in those parts
of the country where there are neither railways nor macadamised
roads--people travelled in carts or carriages without springs and
in these instruments of torture a huge pile of cushions or pillows
is necessary to avoid contusions and dislocations. On the railways
the jolts and shaking are not deadly enough to require such an
antidote; but, even in unconservative Russia, customs outlive the
conditions that created them; and at every railway-station you may
see men and women carrying about their pillows with them as we
carry wraps. A genuine Russian merchant who loves comfort and
respects tradition may travel without a portmanteau, but he
considers his pillow as an indispensable article de voyage.
To return to the old-fashioned hotel. When you have completed the
negotiations with the landlord, you will notice that, unless you
have a servant with you, the waiter prepares to perform the duties
of valet de chambre. Do not be surprised at his officiousness,
which seems founded on the assumption that you are three-fourths
paralysed. Formerly, every well-born Russian had a valet always in
attendance, and never dreamed of doing for himself anything which
could by any possibility be done for him. You notice that there is
no bell in the room, and no mechanical means of communicating with
the world below stairs. That is because the attendant is supposed
to he always within call, and it is so much easier to shout than to
get up and ring the bell.
In the good old times all this was quite natural. The well-born
Russian had commonly a superabundance of domestic serfs, and there
was no reason why one or two of them should not accompany their
master when his Honour undertook a journey. An additional person
in the tarantass did not increase the expense, and considerably
diminished the little unavoidable inconveniences of travel. But
times have changed. In 1861 the domestic serfs were emancipated by
Imperial ukaz. Free servants demand wages; and on railways or
steamers a single ticket does not include an attendant. The
present generation must therefore get through life with a more
modest supply of valets, and must learn to do with its own hands
much that was formerly performed by serf labour. Still, a
gentleman brought up in the old conditions cannot be expected to
dress himself without assistance, and accordingly the waiter
remains in your room to act as valet. Perhaps, too, in the early
morning you may learn in an unpleasant way that other parts of the
old system are not yet extinct. You may hear, for instance,
resounding along the corridors such an order as--"Petrusha!
Petrusha! Stakan vody! ("Little Peter, little Peter, a glass of
water!") shouted in a stentorian voice that would startle the Seven
Sleepers.
When the toilet operations are completed, and you order tea--one
always orders tea in Russia--you will be asked whether you have
your own tea and sugar with you. If you are an experienced
traveller you will be able to reply in the affirmative, for good
tea can be bought only in certain well-known shops, and can rarely
be found in hotels. A huge, steaming tea-urn, called a samovar--
etymologically, a "self-boiler"--will be brought in, and you will
make your tea according to your taste. The tumbler, you know of
course, is to be used as a cup, and when using it you must be
careful not to cauterise the points of your fingers. If you should
happen to have anything eatable or drinkable in your travelling
basket, you need not hesitate to take it out at once, for the
waiter will not feel at all aggrieved or astonished at your doing
nothing "for the good of the house." The twenty or twenty-five
kopeks that you pay for the samovar--teapot, tumbler, saucer,
spoon, and slop-basin being included under the generic term pribor--
frees you from all corkage and similar dues.
These and other remnants of old customs are now rapidly
disappearing, and will, doubtless, in a very few years be things of
the past--things to be picked up in out-of-the-way corners, and
chronicled by social archaeology; but they are still to be found in
towns not unknown to Western Europe.
Many of these old customs, and especially the old method of
travelling, may be studied in their pristine purity throughout a
great part of the country. Though railway construction has been
pushed forward with great energy during the last forty years, there
are still vast regions where the ancient solitudes have never been
disturbed by the shrill whistle of the locomotive, and roads have
remained in their primitive condition. Even in the central
provinces one may still travel hundreds of miles without ever
encountering anything that recalls the name of Macadam.
If popular rumour is to be trusted, there is somewhere in the
Highlands of Scotland, by the side of a turnpike, a large stone
bearing the following doggerel inscription:
"If you had seen this road before it was made,
You'd lift up your hands and bless General Wade."
Any educated Englishman reading this strange announcement would
naturally remark that the first line of the couplet contains a
logical contradiction, probably of Hibernian origin; but I have
often thought, during my wanderings in Russia, that the expression,
if not logically justifiable, might for the sake of vulgar
convenience be legalised by a Permissive Bill. The truth is that,
as a Frenchman might say, "there are roads and roads"--roads made
and roads unmade, roads artificial and roads natural. Now, in
Russia, roads are nearly all of the unmade, natural kind, and are
so conservative in their nature that they have at the present day
precisely the same appearance as they had many centuries ago. They
have thus for imaginative minds something of what is called "the
charm of historical association." The only perceptible change that
takes place in them during a series of generations is that the ruts
shift their position. When these become so deep that fore-wheels
can no longer fathom them, it becomes necessary to begin making a
new pair of ruts to the right or left of the old ones; and as the
roads are commonly of gigantic breadth, there is no difficulty in
finding a place for the operation. How the old ones get filled up
I cannot explain; but as I have rarely seen in any part of the
country, except perhaps in the immediate vicinity of towns, a human
being engaged in road repairing, I assume that beneficent Nature
somehow accomplishes the task without human assistance, either by
means of alluvial deposits, or by some other cosmical action only
known to physical geographers.
On the roads one occasionally encounters bridges; and here, again,
I have discovered in Russia a key to the mysteries of Hibernian
phraseology. An Irish member once declared to the House of Commons
that the Church was "the bridge that separated the two great
sections of the Irish people." As bridges commonly connect rather
than separate, the metaphor was received with roars of laughter.
If the honourable members who joined in the hilarious applause had
travelled much in Russia, they would have been more moderate in
their merriment; for in that country, despite the laudable activity
of the modern system of local administration created in the
sixties, bridges often act still as a barrier rather than a
connecting link, and to cross a river by a bridge may still be what
is termed in popular phrase "a tempting of Providence." The
cautious driver will generally prefer to take to the water, if
there is a ford within a reasonable distance, though both he and
his human load may be obliged, in order to avoid getting wet feet,
to assume undignified postures that would afford admirable material
for the caricaturist. But this little bit of discomfort, even
though the luggage should be soaked in the process of fording, is
as nothing compared to the danger of crossing by the bridge. As I
have no desire to harrow unnecessarily the feelings of the reader,
I refrain from all description of ugly accidents, ending in bruises
and fractures, and shall simply explain in a few words how a
successful passage is effected.
When it is possible to approach the bridge without sinking up to
the knees in mud, it is better to avoid all risks by walking over
and waiting for the vehicle on the other side; and when this is
impossible, a preliminary survey is advisable. To your inquiries
whether it is safe, your yamstchik (post-boy) is sure to reply,
"Nitchevo!"--a word which, according to the dictionaries, means
"nothing" but which has, in the mouths of the peasantry, a great
variety of meanings, as I may explain at some future time. In the
present case it may be roughly translated. "There is no danger."
"Nitchevo, Barin, proyedem" ("There is no danger, sir; we shall get
over"), he repeats. You may refer to the generally rotten
appearance of the structure, and point in particular to the great
holes sufficient to engulf half a post-horse. "Ne bos', Bog
pomozhet" ("Do not fear. God will help"), replies coolly your
phlegmatic Jehu. You may have your doubts as to whether in this
irreligious age Providence will intervene specially for your
benefit; but your yamstchik, who has more faith or fatalism, leaves
you little time to solve the problem. Making hurriedly the sign of
the cross, he gathers up his reins, waves his little whip in the
air, and, shouting lustily, urges on his team. The operation is
not wanting in excitement. First there is a short descent; then
the horses plunge wildly through a zone of deep mud; next comes a
fearful jolt, as the vehicle is jerked up on to the first planks;
then the transverse planks, which are but loosely held in their
places, rattle and rumble ominously, as the experienced, sagacious
animals pick their way cautiously and gingerly among the dangerous
holes and crevices; lastly, you plunge with a horrible jolt into a
second mud zone, and finally regain terra firma, conscious of that
pleasant sensation which a young officer may be supposed to feel
after his first cavalry charge in real warfare.
Of course here, as elsewhere, familiarity breeds indifference.
When you have successfully crossed without serious accident a few
hundred bridges of this kind you learn to be as cool and fatalistic
as your yamstchik.
The reader who has heard of the gigantic reforms that have been
repeatedly imposed on Russia by a paternal Government may naturally
be astonished to learn that the roads are still in such a
disgraceful condition. But for this, as for everything else in the
world, there is a good and sufficient reason. The country is
still, comparatively speaking, thinly populated, and in many
regions it is difficult, or practically impossible, to procure in
sufficient quantity stone of any kind, and especially hard stone
fit for road-making. Besides this, when roads are made, the
severity of the climate renders it difficult to keep them in good
repair.
When a long journey has to be undertaken through a region in which
there are no railways, there are several ways in which it may be
effected. In former days, when time was of still less value than
at present, many landed proprietors travelled with their own
horses, and carried with them, in one or more capacious, lumbering
vehicles, all that was required for the degree of civilisation
which they had attained; and their requirements were often
considerable. The grand seigneur, for instance, who spent the
greater part of his life amidst the luxury of the court society,
naturally took with him all the portable elements of civilisation.
His baggage included, therefore, camp-beds, table-linen, silver
plate, a batterie de cuisine, and a French cook. The pioneers and
part of the commissariat force were sent on in advance, so that his
Excellency found at each halting-place everything prepared for his
arrival. The poor owner of a few dozen serfs dispensed, of course,
with the elaborate commissariat department, and contented himself
with such modest fare as could be packed in the holes and corners
of a single tarantass.
It will be well to explain here, parenthetically, what a tarantass
is, for I shall often have occasion to use the word. It may be
briefly defined as a phaeton without springs. The function of
springs is imperfectly fulfilled by two parallel wooden bars,
placed longitudinally, on which is fixed the body of the vehicle.
It is commonly drawn by three horses--a strong, fast trotter in the
shafts, flanked on each side by a light, loosely-attached horse
that goes along at a gallop. The points of the shafts are
connected by the duga, which looks like a gigantic, badly formed
horseshoe rising high above the collar of the trotter. To the top
of the duga is attached the bearing-rein, and underneath the
highest part of it is fastened a big bell--in the southern
provinces I found two, and sometimes even three bells--which, when
the country is open and the atmosphere still, may be heard a mile
off. The use of the bell is variously explained. Some say it is
in order to frighten the wolves, and others that it is to avoid
collisions on the narrow forest-paths. But neither of these
explanations is entirely satisfactory. It is used chiefly in
summer, when there is no danger of an attack from wolves; and the
number of bells is greater in the south, where there are no
forests. Perhaps the original intention was--I throw out the hint
for the benefit of a certain school of archaeologists--to frighten
away evil spirits; and the practice has been retained partly from
unreasoning conservatism, and partly with a view to lessen the
chances of collisions. As the roads are noiselessly soft, and the
drivers not always vigilant, the dangers of collision are
considerably diminished by the ceaseless peal.
Altogether, the tarantass is well adapted to the conditions in
which it is used. By the curious way in which the horses are
harnessed it recalls the war-chariot of ancient times. The horse
in the shafts is compelled by the bearing-rein to keep his head
high and straight before him--though the movement of his ears shows
plainly that he would very much like to put it somewhere farther
away from the tongue of the bell--but the side horses gallop
freely, turning their heads outwards in classical fashion. I
believe that this position is assumed not from any sympathy on the
part of these animals for the remains of classical art, but rather
from the natural desire to keep a sharp eye on the driver. Every
movement of his right hand they watch with close attention, and as
soon as they discover any symptoms indicating an intention of using
the whip they immediately show a desire to quicken the pace.
Now that the reader has gained some idea of what a tarantass is, we
may return to the modes of travelling through the regions which are
not yet supplied with railways.
However enduring and long-winded horses may be, they must be
allowed sometimes, during a long journey, to rest and feed.
Travelling long distances with one's own horses is therefore
necessarily a slow operation, and is now quite antiquated. People
who value their time prefer to make use of the Imperial Post
organisation. On all the principal lines of communication there
are regular post-stations, at from ten to twenty miles apart, where
a certain number of horses and vehicles are kept for the
convenience of travellers. To enjoy the privilege of this
arrangement, one has to apply to the proper authorities for a
podorozhnaya--a large sheet of paper stamped with the Imperial
Eagle, and bearing the name of the recipient, the destination, and
the number of horses to be supplied. In return, a small sum is
paid for imaginary road-repairs; the rest of the sum is paid by
instalments at the respective stations.
Armed with this document you go to the post-station and demand the
requisite number of horses. Three is the number generally used,
but if you travel lightly and are indifferent to appearances, you
may content yourself with a pair. The vehicle is a kind of
tarantass, but not such as I have just described. The essentials
in both are the same, but those which the Imperial Government
provides resemble an enormous cradle on wheels rather than a
phaeton. An armful of hay spread over the bottom of the wooden box
is supposed to play the part of seats and cushions. You are
expected to sit under the arched covering, and extend your legs so
that the feet lie beneath the driver's seat; but it is advisable,
unless the rain happens to be coming down in torrents, to get this
covering unshipped, and travel without it. When used, it painfully
curtails the little freedom of movement that you enjoy, and when
you are shot upwards by some obstruction on the road it is apt to
arrest your ascent by giving you a violent blow on the top of the
head.
It is to be hoped that you are in no hurry to start, otherwise your
patience may be sorely tried. The horses, when at last produced,
may seem to you the most miserable screws that it was ever your
misfortune to behold; but you had better refrain from expressing
your feelings, for if you use violent, uncomplimentary language, it
may turn out that you have been guilty of gross calumny. I have
seen many a team composed of animals which a third-class London
costermonger would have spurned, and in which it was barely
possible to recognise the equine form, do their duty in highly
creditable style, and go along at the rate of ten or twelve miles
an hour, under no stronger incentive then the voice of the
yamstchik. Indeed, the capabilities of these lean, slouching,
ungainly quadrupeds are often astounding when they are under the
guidance of a man who knows how to drive them. Though such a man
commonly carries a little harmless whip, he rarely uses it except
by waving it horizontally in the air. His incitements are all
oral. He talks to his cattle as he would to animals of his own
species--now encouraging them by tender, caressing epithets, and
now launching at them expressions of indignant scorn. At one
moment they are his "little doves," and at the next they have been
transformed into "cursed hounds." How far they understand and
appreciate this curious mixture of endearing cajolery and
contemptuous abuse it is difficult to say, but there is no doubt
that it somehow has upon them a strange and powerful influence.
Any one who undertakes a journey of this kind should possess a
well-knit, muscular frame and good tough sinews, capable of
supporting an unlimited amount of jolting and shaking; at the same
time he should be well inured to all the hardships and discomforts
incidental to what is vaguely termed "roughing it." When he wishes
to sleep in a post-station, he will find nothing softer than a
wooden bench, unless he can induce the keeper to put for him on the
floor a bundle of hay, which is perhaps softer, but on the whole
more disagreeable than the deal board. Sometimes he will not get
even the wooden bench, for in ordinary post-stations there is but
one room for travellers, and the two benches--there are rarely
more--may be already occupied. When he does obtain a bench, and
succeeds in falling asleep, he must not be astonished if he is
disturbed once or twice during the night by people who use the
apartment as a waiting-room whilst the post-horses are being
changed. These passers-by may even order a samovar, and drink tea,
chat, laugh, smoke, and make themselves otherwise disagreeable,
utterly regardless of the sleepers. Then there are the other
intruders, smaller in size but equally objectionable, of which I
have already spoken when describing the steamers on the Don.
Regarding them I desire to give merely one word of advice: As you
will have abundant occupation in the work of self-defence, learn to
distinguish between belligerents and neutrals, and follow the
simple principle of international law, that neutrals should not be
molested. They may be very ugly, but ugliness does not justify
assassination. If, for instance, you should happen in awaking to
notice a few black or brown beetles running about your pillow,
restrain your murderous hand! If you kill them you commit an act
of unnecessary bloodshed; for though they may playfully scamper
around you, they will do you no bodily harm.
Another requisite for a journey in unfrequented districts is a
knowledge of the language. It is popularly supposed that if you
are familiar with French and German you may travel anywhere in
Russia. So far as the great cities and chief lines of
communication are concerned, this may be true, but beyond that it
is a delusion. The Russian has not, any more than the West-
European, received from Nature the gift of tongues. Educated
Russians often speak one or two foreign languages fluently, but the
peasants know no language but their own, and it is with the
peasantry that one comes in contact. And to converse freely with
the peasant requires a considerable familiarity with the language--
far more than is required for simply reading a book. Though there
are few provincialisms, and all classes of the people use the same
words--except the words of foreign origin, which are used only by
the upper classes--the peasant always speaks in a more laconic and
more idiomatic way than the educated man.
In the winter months travelling is in some respects pleasanter than
in summer, for snow and frost are great macadamisers. If the snow
falls evenly, there is for some time the most delightful road that
can be imagined. No jolts, no shaking, but a smooth, gliding
motion, like that of a boat in calm water, and the horses gallop
along as if totally unconscious of the sledge behind them.
Unfortunately, this happy state of things does not last all through
the winter. The road soon gets cut up, and deep transverse furrows
(ukhaby) are formed. How these furrows come into existence I have
never been able clearly to comprehend, though I have often heard
the phenomenon explained by men who imagined they understood it.
Whatever the cause and mode of formation may be, certain it is that
little hills and valleys do get formed, and the sledge, as it
crosses over them, bobs up and down like a boat in a chopping sea,
with this important difference, that the boat falls into a yielding
liquid, whereas the sledge falls upon a solid substance, unyielding
and unelastic. The shaking and jolting which result may readily be
imagined.
There are other discomforts, too, in winter travelling. So long as
the air is perfectly still, the cold may be very intense without
being disagreeable; but if a strong head wind is blowing, and the
thermometer ever so many degrees below zero, driving in an open
sledge is a very disagreeable operation, and noses may get
frostbitten without their owners perceiving the fact in time to
take preventive measures. Then why not take covered sledges on
such occasions? For the simple reason that they are not to be had;
and if they could be procured, it would be well to avoid using
them, for they are apt to produce something very like seasickness.
Besides this, when the sledge gets overturned, it is pleasanter to
be shot out on to the clean, refreshing snow than to be buried
ignominiously under a pile of miscellaneous baggage.
The chief requisite for winter travelling in these icy regions is a
plentiful supply of warm furs. An Englishman is very apt to be
imprudent in this respect, and to trust too much to his natural
power of resisting cold. To a certain extent this confidence is
justifiable, for an Englishman often feels quite comfortable in an
ordinary great coat when his Russian friends consider it necessary
to envelop themselves in furs of the warmest kind; but it may be
carried too far, in which case severe punishment is sure to follow,
as I once learned by experience. I may relate the incident as a
warning to others:
One day in mid-winter I started from Novgorod, with the intention
of visiting some friends at a cavalry barracks situated about ten
miles from the town. As the sun was shining brightly, and the
distance to be traversed was short, I considered that a light fur
and a bashlyk--a cloth hood which protects the ears--would be quite
sufficient to keep out the cold, and foolishly disregarded the
warnings of a Russian friend who happened to call as I was about to
start. Our route lay along the river due northward, right in the
teeth of a strong north wind. A wintry north wind is always and
everywhere a disagreeable enemy to face; let the reader try to
imagine what it is when the Fahrenheit thermometer is at 30 degrees
below zero--or rather let him refrain from such an attempt, for the
sensation produced cannot be imagined by those who have not
experienced it. Of course I ought to have turned back--at least,
as soon as a sensation of faintness warned me that the circulation
was being seriously impeded--but I did not wish to confess my
imprudence to the friend who accompanied me. When we had driven
about three-fourths of the way we met a peasant-woman, who
gesticulated violently, and shouted something to us as we passed.
I did not hear what she said, but my friend turned to me and said
in an alarming tone--we had been speaking German--"Mein Gott! Ihre
Nase ist abgefroren!" Now the word "abgefroren," as the reader
will understand, seemed to indicate that my nose was frozen off, so
I put up my hand in some alarm to discover whether I had
inadvertently lost the whole or part of the member referred to. It
was still in situ and entire, but as hard and insensible as a bit
of wood.
"You may still save it," said my companion, "if you get out at once
and rub it vigorously with snow."
I got out as directed, but was too faint to do anything vigorously.
My fur cloak flew open, the cold seemed to grasp me in the region
of the heart, and I fell insensible.
How long I remained unconscious I know not. When I awoke I found
myself in a strange room, surrounded by dragoon officers in
uniform, and the first words I heard were, "He is out of danger
now, but he will have a fever."
These words were spoken, as I afterwards discovered, by a very
competent surgeon; but the prophecy was not fulfilled. The
promised fever never came. The only bad consequences were that for
some days my right hand remained stiff, and for a week or two I had
to conceal my nose from public view.
If this little incident justifies me in drawing a general
conclusion, I should say that exposure to extreme cold is an almost
painless form of death; but that the process of being resuscitated
is very painful indeed--so painful, that the patient may be excused
for momentarily regretting that officious people prevented the
temporary insensibility from becoming "the sleep that knows no
waking."
Between the alternate reigns of winter and summer there is always a
short interregnum, during which travelling in Russia by road is
almost impossible. Woe to the ill-fated mortal who has to make a
long road-journey immediately after the winter snow has melted; or,
worse still, at the beginning of winter, when the autumn mud has
been petrified by the frost, and not yet levelled by the snow!
At all seasons the monotony of a journey is pretty sure to be
broken by little unforeseen episodes of a more or less disagreeable
kind. An axle breaks, or a wheel comes off, or there is a
difficulty in procuring horses. As an illustration of the graver
episodes which may occur, I shall make here a quotation from my
note-book:
Early in the morning we arrived at Maikop, a small town commanding
the entrance to one of the valleys which run up towards the main
range of the Caucasus. On alighting at the post-station, we at
once ordered horses for the next stage, and received the laconic
reply, "There are no horses."
"And when will there be some?"
"To-morrow!"
This last reply we took for a piece of playful exaggeration, and
demanded the book in which, according to law, the departure of
horses is duly inscribed, and from which it is easy to calculate
when the first team should be ready to start. A short calculation
proved that we ought to get horses by four o'clock in the
afternoon, so we showed the station-keeper various documents signed
by the Minister of the Interior and other influential personages,
and advised him to avoid all contravention of the postal
regulations.
These documents, which proved that we enjoyed the special
protection of the authorities, had generally been of great service
to us in our dealings with rascally station-keepers; but this
station-keeper was not one of the ordinary type. He was a Cossack,
of herculean proportions, with a bullet-shaped head, short-cropped
bristly hair, shaggy eyebrows, an enormous pendent moustache, a
defiant air, and a peculiar expression of countenance which plainly
indicated "an ugly customer." Though it was still early in the
day, he had evidently already imbibed a considerable quantity of
alcohol, and his whole demeanour showed clearly enough that he was
not of those who are "pleasant in their liquor." After glancing
superciliously at the documents, as if to intimate he could read
them were he so disposed, he threw them down on the table, and,
thrusting his gigantic paws into his capacious trouser-pockets,
remarked slowly and decisively, in something deeper than a double-
bass voice, "You'll have horses to-morrow morning."
Wishing to avoid a quarrel we tried to hire horses in the village,
and when our efforts in that direction proved fruitless, we applied
to the head of the rural police. He came and used all his
influence with the refractory station-keeper, but in vain.
Hercules was not in a mood to listen to officials any more than to
ordinary mortals. At last, after considerable trouble to himself,
our friend of the police contrived to find horses for us, and we
contented ourselves with entering an account of the circumstances
in the Complaint Book, but our difficulties were by no means at an
end. As soon as Hercules perceived that we had obtained horses
without his assistance, and that he had thereby lost his
opportunity of blackmailing us, he offered us one of his own teams,
and insisted on detaining us until we should cancel the complaint
against him. This we refused to do, and our relations with him
became what is called in diplomatic language "extremement tendues."
Again we had to apply to the police.
My friend mounted guard over the baggage whilst I went to the
police office. I was not long absent, but I found, on my return,
that important events had taken place in the interval. A crowd had
collected round the post-station, and on the steps stood the keeper
and his post-boys, declaring that the traveller inside had
attempted to shoot them! I rushed in and soon perceived, by the
smell of gunpowder, that firearms had been used, but found no trace
of casualties. My friend was tramping up and down the little room,
and evidently for the moment there was an armistice.
In a very short time the local authorities had assembled, a candle
had been lit, two armed Cossacks stood as sentries at the door, and
the preliminary investigation had begun. The Chief of Police sat
at the table and wrote rapidly on a sheet of foolscap. The
investigation showed that two shots had been fired from a revolver,
and two bullets were found imbedded in the wall. All those who had
been present, and some who knew nothing of the incident except by
hearsay, were duly examined. Our opponents always assumed that my
friend had been the assailant, in spite of his protestations to the
contrary, and more than once the words pokyshenie na ubiistvo
(attempt to murder) were pronounced. Things looked very black
indeed. We had the prospect of being detained for days and weeks
in the miserable place, till the insatiable demon of official
formality had been propitiated. And then?
When things were thus at their blackest they suddenly took an
unexpected turn, and the deus ex machina appeared precisely at the
right moment, just as if we had all been puppets in a sensation
novel. There was the usual momentary silence, and then, mixed with
the sound of an approaching tarantass, a confused murmur: "There he
is! He is coming!" The "he" thus vaguely and mysteriously
indicated turned out to be an official of the judicial
administration, who had reason to visit the village for an entirely
different affair. As soon as he had been told briefly what had
happened he took the matter in hand and showed himself equal to the
occasion. Unlike the majority of Russian officials he disliked
lengthy procedure, and succeeded in making the case quite clear in
a very short time. There had been, he perceived, no attempt to
murder or anything of the kind. The station-keeper and his two
post-boys, who had no right to be in the traveller's room, had
entered with threatening mien, and when they refused to retire
peaceably, my friend had fired two shots in order to frighten them
and bring assistance. The falsity of their statement that he had
fired at them as they entered the room was proved by the fact that
the bullets were lodged near the ceiling in the wall farthest away
from the door.
I must confess that I was agreeably surprised by this unexpected
turn of affairs. The conclusions arrived at were nothing more than
a simple statement of what had taken place; but I was surprised at
the fact that a man who was at once a lawyer and a Russian official
should have been able to take such a plain, commonsense view of the
case.
Before midnight we were once more free men, driving rapidly in the
clear moonlight to the next station, under the escort of a fully-
armed Circassian Cossack; but the idea that we might have been
detained for weeks in that miserable place haunted us like a
nightmare.
CHAPTER II
IN THE NORTHERN FORESTS
Bird's-eye View of Russia--The Northern Forests--Purpose of my
Journey--Negotiations--The Road--A Village--A Peasant's House--
Vapour-Baths--Curious Custom--Arrival.
There are many ways of describing a country that one has visited.
The simplest and most common method is to give a chronological
account of the journey; and this is perhaps the best way when the
journey does not extend over more than a few weeks. But it cannot
be conveniently employed in the case of a residence of many years.
Did I adopt it, I should very soon exhaust the reader's patience.
I should have to take him with me to a secluded village, and make
him wait for me till I had learned to speak the language. Thence
he would have to accompany me to a provincial town, and spend
months in a public office, whilst I endeavoured to master the
mysteries of local self-government. After this he would have to
spend two years with me in a big library, where I studied the
history and literature of the country. And so on, and so on. Even
my journeys would prove tedious to him, as they often were to
myself, for he would have to drive with me many a score of weary
miles, where even the most zealous diary-writer would find nothing
to record beyond the names of the post-stations.
It will be well for me, then, to avoid the strictly chronological
method, and confine myself to a description of the more striking
objects and incidents that came under my notice. The knowledge
which I derived from books will help me to supply a running
commentary on what I happened to see and hear.
Instead of beginning in the usual way with St. Petersburg, I prefer
for many reasons to leave the description of the capital till some
future time, and plunge at once into the great northern forest
region.
If it were possible to get a bird's-eye view of European Russia,
the spectator would perceive that the country is composed of two
halves widely differing from each other in character. The northern
half is a land of forest and morass, plentifully supplied with
water in the form of rivers, lakes, and marshes, and broken up by
numerous patches of cultivation. The southern half is, as it were,
the other side of the pattern--an immense expanse of rich, arable
land, broken up by occasional patches of sand or forest. The
imaginary undulating line separating those two regions starts from
the western frontier about the 50th parallel of latitude, and runs
in a northeasterly direction till it enters the Ural range at about
56 degrees N.L.
Well do I remember my first experience of travel in the northern
region, and the weeks of voluntary exile which formed the goal of
the journey. It was in the summer of 1870. My reason for
undertaking the journey was this: a few months of life in St.
Petersburg had fully convinced me that the Russian language is one
of those things which can only be acquired by practice, and that
even a person of antediluvian longevity might spend all his life in
that city without learning to express himself fluently in the
vernacular--especially if he has the misfortune of being able to
speak English, French, and German. With his friends and associates
he speaks French or English. German serves as a medium of
communication with waiters, shop keepers, and other people of that
class. It is only with isvoshtchiki--the drivers of the little
open droshkis which fulfil the function of cabs--that he is obliged
to use the native tongue, and with them a very limited vocabulary
suffices. The ordinal numerals and four short, easily-acquired
expressions--poshol (go on), na pravo (to the right), na lyevo (to
the left), and stoi (stop)--are all that is required.
Whilst I was considering how I could get beyond the sphere of West-
European languages, a friend came to my assistance, and suggested
that I should go to his estate in the province of Novgorod, where I
should find an intelligent, amiable parish priest, quite innocent
of any linguistic acquirements. This proposal I at once adopted,
and accordingly found myself one morning at a small station of the
Moscow Railway, endeavouring to explain to a peasant in sheep's
clothing that I wished to be conveyed to Ivanofka, the village
where my future teacher lived. At that time I still spoke Russian
in a very fragmentary and confused way--pretty much as Spanish cows
are popularly supposed to speak French. My first remark therefore
being literally interpreted, was--"Ivanofka. Horses. You can?"
The point of interrogation was expressed by a simultaneous raising
of the voice and the eyebrows.
"Ivanofka?" cried the peasant, in an interrogatory tone of voice.
In Russia, as in other countries, the peasantry when speaking with
strangers like to repeat questions, apparently for the purpose of
gaining time.
"Ivanofka," I replied.
"Now?"
"Now!"
After some reflection the peasant nodded and said something which I
did not understand, but which I assumed to mean that he was open to
consider proposals for transporting me to my destination.
"Roubles. How many?"
To judge by the knitting of the brows and the scratching of the
head, I should say that that question gave occasion to a very
abstruse mathematical calculation. Gradually the look of
concentrated attention gave place to an expression such as children
assume when they endeavour to get a parental decision reversed by
means of coaxing. Then came a stream of soft words which were to
me utterly unintelligible.
I must not weary the reader with a detailed account of the
succeeding negotiations, which were conducted with extreme
diplomatic caution on both sides, as if a cession of territory or
the payment of a war indemnity had been the subject of discussion.
Three times he drove away and three times returned. Each time he
abated his pretensions, and each time I slightly increased my
offer. At last, when I began to fear that he had finally taken his
departure and had left me to my own devices, he re-entered the room
and took up my baggage, indicating thereby that he agreed to my
last offer.
The sum agreed upon would have been, under ordinary circumstances,
more than sufficient, but before proceeding far I discovered that
the circumstances were by no means ordinary, and I began to
understand the pantomimic gesticulation which had puzzled me during
the negotiations. Heavy rain had fallen without interruption for
several days, and now the track on which we were travelling could
not, without poetical license, be described as a road. In some
parts it resembled a water-course, in others a quagmire, and at
least during the first half of the journey I was constantly
reminded of that stage in the work of creation when the water was
not yet separated from the dry land. During the few moments when
the work of keeping my balance and preventing my baggage from being
lost did not engross all my attention, I speculated on the
possibility of inventing a boat-carriage, to be drawn by some
amphibious quadruped. Fortunately our two lean, wiry little horses
did not object to being used as aquatic animals. They took the
water bravely, and plunged through the mud in gallant style. The
telega in which we were seated--a four-wheeled skeleton cart--did
not submit to the ill-treatment so silently. It creaked out its
remonstrances and entreaties, and at the more difficult spots
threatened to go to pieces; but its owner understood its character
and capabilities, and paid no attention to its ominous threats.
Once, indeed, a wheel came off, but it was soon fished out of the
mud and replaced, and no further casualty occurred.
The horses did their work so well that when about midday we arrived
at a village, I could not refuse to let them have some rest and
refreshment--all the more as my own thoughts had begun to turn in
that direction.
The village, like villages in that part of the country generally,
consisted of two long parallel rows of wooden houses. The road--if
a stratum of deep mud can be called by that name--formed the
intervening space. All the houses turned their gables to the
passerby, and some of them had pretensions to architectural
decoration in the form of rude perforated woodwork. Between the
houses, and in a line with them, were great wooden gates and high
wooden fences, separating the courtyards from the road. Into one
of these yards, near the farther end of the village, our horses
turned of their own accord.
"An inn?" I said, in an interrogative tone.
The driver shook his head and said something, in which I detected
the word "friend." Evidently there was no hostelry for man and
beast in the village, and the driver was using a friend's house for
the purpose.
The yard was flanked on the one side by an open shed, containing
rude agricultural implements which might throw some light on the
agriculture of the primitive Aryans, and on the other side by the
dwelling-house and stable. Both the house and stable were built of
logs, nearly cylindrical in form, and placed in horizontal tiers.
Two of the strongest of human motives, hunger and curiosity,
impelled me to enter the house at once. Without waiting for an
invitation, I went up to the door--half protected against the
winter snows by a small open portico--and unceremoniously walked
in. The first apartment was empty, but I noticed a low door in the
wall to the left, and passing through this, entered the principal
room. As the scene was new to me, I noted the principal objects.
In the wall before me were two small square windows looking out
upon the road, and in the corner to the right, nearer to the
ceiling than to the floor, was a little triangular shelf, on which
stood a religious picture. Before the picture hung a curious oil
lamp. In the corner to the left of the door was a gigantic stove,
built of brick, and whitewashed. From the top of the stove to the
wall on the right stretched what might be called an enormous shelf,
six or eight feet in breadth. This is the so-called palati, as I
afterwards discovered, and serves as a bed for part of the family.
The furniture consisted of a long wooden bench attached to the wall
on the right, a big, heavy, deal table, and a few wooden stools.
Whilst I was leisurely surveying these objects, I heard a noise on
the top of the stove, and, looking up, perceived a human face, with
long hair parted in the middle, and a full yellow beard. I was
considerably astonished by this apparition, for the air in the room
was stifling, and I had some difficulty in believing that any
created being--except perhaps a salamander or a negro--could exist
in such a position. I looked hard to convince myself that I was
not the victim of a delusion. As I stared, the head nodded slowly
and pronounced the customary form of greeting.
I returned the greeting slowly, wondering what was to come next.
"Ill, very ill!" sighed the head.
"I'm not astonished at that," I remarked, in an "aside." "If I
were lying on the stove as you are I should be very ill too."
"Hot, very hot?" I remarked, interrogatively.
"Nitchevo"--that is to say, "not particularly." This remark
astonished me all the more as I noticed that the body to which the
head belonged was enveloped in a sheep-skin!
After living some time in Russia I was no longer surprised by such
incidents, for I soon discovered that the Russian peasant has a
marvellous power of bearing extreme heat as well as extreme cold.
When a coachman takes his master or mistress to the theatre or to a
party, he never thinks of going home and returning at an appointed
time. Hour after hour he sits placidly on the box, and though the
cold be of an intensity such as is never experienced in our
temperate climate, he can sleep as tranquilly as the lazzaroni at
midday in Naples. In that respect the Russian peasant seems to be
first-cousin to the polar bear, but, unlike the animals of the
Arctic regions, he is not at all incommoded by excessive heat. On
the contrary, he likes it when he can get it, and never omits an
opportunity of laying in a reserve supply of caloric. He even
delights in rapid transitions from one extreme to the other, as is
amply proved by a curious custom which deserves to be recorded.
The reader must know that in the life of the Russian peasantry the
weekly vapour-bath plays a most important part. It has even a
certain religious signification, for no good orthodox peasant would
dare to enter a church after being soiled by certain kinds of
pollution without cleansing himself physically and morally by means
of the bath. In the weekly arrangements it forms the occupation
for Saturday afternoon, and care is taken to avoid thereafter all
pollution until after the morning service on Sunday. Many villages
possess a public or communal bath of the most primitive
construction, but in some parts of the country--I am not sure how
far the practice extends--the peasants take their vapour-bath in
the household oven in which the bread is baked! In all cases the
operation is pushed to the extreme limit of human endurance--far
beyond the utmost limit that can be endured by those who have not
been accustomed to it from childhood. For my own part, I only made
the experiment once; and when I informed my attendant that my life
was in danger from congestion of the brain, he laughed outright,
and told me that the operation had only begun. Most astounding of
all--and this brings me to the fact which led me into this
digression--the peasants in winter often rush out of the bath and
roll themselves in the snow! This aptly illustrates a common
Russian proverb, which says that what is health to the Russian is
death to the German.
Cold water, as well as hot vapour, is sometimes used as a means of
purification. In the villages the old pagan habit of masquerading
in absurd costumes at certain seasons--as is done during the
carnival in Roman Catholic countries with the approval, or at least
connivance, of the Church--still survives; but it is regarded as
not altogether sinless. He who uses such disguises places himself
to a certain extent under the influence of the Evil One, thereby
putting his soul in jeopardy; and to free himself from this danger
he has to purify himself in the following way: When the annual mid-
winter ceremony of blessing the waters is performed, by breaking a
hole in the ice and immersing a cross with certain religious rites,
he should plunge into the hole as soon as possible after the
ceremony. I remember once at Yaroslavl, on the Volga, two young
peasants successfully accomplished this feat--though the police
have orders to prevent it--and escaped, apparently without evil
consequences, though the Fahrenheit thermometer was below zero.
How far the custom has really a purifying influence, is a question
which must be left to theologians; but even an ordinary mortal can
understand that, if it be regarded as a penance, it must have a
certain deterrent effect. The man who foresees the necessity of
undergoing this severe penance will think twice before putting on a
disguise. So at least it must have been in the good old times; but
in these degenerate days--among the Russian peasantry as elsewhere--
the fear of the Devil, which was formerly, if not the beginning,
at least one of the essential elements, of wisdom, has greatly
decreased. Many a young peasant will now thoughtlessly disguise
himself, and when the consecration of the water is performed, will
stand and look on passively like an ordinary spectator! It would
seem that the Devil, like his enemy the Pope, is destined to lose
gradually his temporal power.
But all this time I am neglecting my new acquaintance on the top of
the stove. In reality I did not neglect him, but listened most
attentively to every word of the long tale that he recited. What
it was all about I could only vaguely guess, for I did not
understand more than ten per cent of the words used, but I assumed
from the tone and gestures that he was relating to me all the
incidents and symptoms of his illness. And a very severe illness
it must have been, for it requires a very considerable amount of
physical suffering to make the patient Russian peasant groan.
Before he had finished his tale a woman entered, apparently his
wife.
To her I explained that I had a strong desire to eat and drink, and
that I wished to know what she would give me. By a good deal of
laborious explanation I was made to understand that I could have
eggs, black bread, and milk, and we agreed that there should be a
division of labour: my hostess should prepare the samovar for
boiling water, whilst I should fry the eggs to my own satisfaction.
In a few minutes the repast was ready, and, though not very
delicate, was highly acceptable. The tea and sugar I had of course
brought with me; the eggs were not very highly flavoured; and the
black rye-bread, strongly intermixed with sand, could be eaten by a
peculiar and easily-acquired method of mastication, in which the
upper molars are never allowed to touch those of the lower jaw. In
this way the grating of the sand between the teeth is avoided.
Eggs, black bread, milk, and tea--these formed my ordinary articles
of food during all my wanderings in Northern Russia. Occasionally
potatoes could be got, and afforded the possibility of varying the
bill of fare. The favourite materials employed in the native
cookery are sour cabbage, cucumbers, and kvass--a kind of very
small beer made from black bread. None of these can be recommended
to the traveller who is not already accustomed to them.
The remainder of the journey was accomplished at a rather more
rapid pace than the preceding part, for the road was decidedly
better, though it was traversed by numerous half-buried roots,
which produced violent jolts. From the conversation of the driver
I gathered that wolves, bears, and elks were found in the forest
through which we were passing.
The sun had long since set when we reached our destination, and I
found to my dismay that the priest's house was closed for the
night. To rouse the reverend personage from his slumbers, and
endeavour to explain to him with my limited vocabulary the object
of my visit, was not to be thought of. On the other hand, there
was no inn of any kind in the vicinity. When I consulted the
driver as to what was to be done, he meditated for a little, and
then pointed to a large house at some distance where there were
still lights. It turned out to be the country-house of the
gentleman who had advised me to undertake the journey, and here,
after a short explanation, though the owner was not at home, I was
hospitably received.
It had been my intention to live in the priest's house, but a short
interview with him on the following day convinced me that that part
of my plan could not be carried out. The preliminary objections
that I should find but poor fare in his humble household, and much
more of the same kind, were at once put aside by my assurance, made
partly by pantomime, that, as an old traveller, I was well
accustomed to simple fare, and could always accommodate myself to
the habits of people among whom my lot happened to be cast. But
there was a more serious difficulty. The priest's family had, as
is generally the case with priests' families, been rapidly
increasing during the last few years, and his house had not been
growing with equal rapidity. The natural consequence of this was
that he had not a room or a bed to spare. The little room which he
had formerly kept for occasional visitors was now occupied by his
eldest daughter, who had returned from a "school for the daughters
of the clergy," where she had been for the last two years. Under
these circumstances, I was constrained to accept the kind proposal
made to me by the representative of my absent friend, that I should
take up my quarters in one of the numerous unoccupied rooms in the
manor-house. This arrangement, I was reminded, would not at all
interfere with my proposed studies, for the priest lived close at
hand, and I might spend with him as much time as I liked.
And now let me introduce the reader to my reverend teacher and one
or two other personages whose acquaintance I made during my
voluntary exile.
CHAPTER III
VOLUNTARY EXILE
Ivanofka--History of the Place--The Steward of the Estate--Slav and
Teutonic Natures--A German's View of the Emancipation--Justices of
the Peace--New School of Morals--The Russian Language--Linguistic
Talent of the Russians--My Teacher--A Big Dose of Current History.
This village, Ivanofka by name, in which I proposed to spend some
months, was rather more picturesque than villages in these northern
forests commonly are. The peasants' huts, built on both sides of a
straight road, were colourless enough, and the big church, with its
five pear-shaped cupolas rising out of the bright green roof and
its ugly belfry in the Renaissance style, was not by any means
beautiful in itself; but when seen from a little distance,
especially in the soft evening twilight, the whole might have been
made the subject of a very pleasing picture. From the point that a
landscape-painter would naturally have chosen, the foreground was
formed by a meadow, through which flowed sluggishly a meandering
stream. On a bit of rising ground to the right, and half concealed
by an intervening cluster of old rich-coloured pines, stood the
manor-house--a big, box-shaped, whitewashed building, with a
verandah in front, overlooking a small plot that might some day
become a flower-garden. To the left of this stood the village, the
houses grouping prettily with the big church, and a little farther
in this direction was an avenue of graceful birches. On the
extreme left were fields, bounded by a dark border of fir-trees.
Could the spectator have raised himself a few hundred feet from the
ground, he would have seen that there were fields beyond the
village, and that the whole of this agricultural oasis was imbedded
in a forest stretching in all directions as far as the eye could
reach.
The history of the place may be told in a few words. In former
times the estate, including the village and all its inhabitants,
had belonged to a monastery, but when, in 1764, the Church lands
were secularised by Catherine, it became the property of the State.
Some years afterwards the Empress granted it, with the serfs and
everything else which it contained, to an old general who had
distinguished himself in the Turkish wars. From that time it had
remained in the K---- family. Some time between the years 1820 and
1840 the big church and the mansion-house had been built by the
actual possessor's father, who loved country life, and devoted a
large part of his time and energies to the management of his
estate. His son, on the contrary, preferred St. Petersburg to the
country, served in one of the public offices, loved passionately
French plays and other products of urban civilisation, and left the
entire management of the property to a German steward, popularly
known as Karl Karl'itch, whom I shall introduce to the reader
presently.
The village annals contained no important events, except bad
harvests, cattle-plagues, and destructive fires, with which the
inhabitants seem to have been periodically visited from time
immemorial. If good harvests were ever experienced, they must have
faded from the popular recollection. Then there were certain
ancient traditions which might have been lessened in bulk and
improved in quality by being subjected to searching historical
criticism. More than once, for instance, a leshie, or wood-sprite,
had been seen in the neighbourhood; and in several households the
domovoi, or brownie, had been known to play strange pranks until he
was properly propitiated. And as a set-off against these
manifestations of evil powers, there were well-authenticated
stories about a miracle-working image that had mysteriously
appeared on the branch of a tree, and about numerous miraculous
cures that had been effected by means of pilgrimages to holy
shrines.
But it is time to introduce the principal personages of this little
community. Of these, by far the most important was Karl Karl'itch,
the steward.
First of all I ought, perhaps, to explain how Karl Schmidt, the son
of a well-to-do Bauer in the Prussian village of Schonhausen,
became Karl Karl'itch, the principal personage in the Russian
village of Ivanofka.
About the time of the Crimean War many of the Russian landed
proprietors had become alive to the necessity of improving the
primitive, traditional methods of agriculture, and sought for this
purpose German stewards for their estates. Among these proprietors
was the owner of Ivanofka. Through the medium of a friend in
Berlin he succeeded in engaging for a moderate salary a young man
who had just finished his studies in one of the German schools of
agriculture--the institution at Hohenheim, if my memory does not
deceive me. This young man had arrived in Russia as plain Karl
Schmidt, but his name was soon transformed into Karl Karl'itch, not
from any desire of his own, but in accordance with a curious
Russian custom. In Russia one usually calls a man not by his
family name, but by his Christian name and patronymic--the latter
being formed from the name of his father. Thus, if a man's name is
Nicholas, and his father's Christian name is--or was--Ivan, you
address him as Nikolai Ivanovitch (pronounced Ivan'itch); and if
this man should happen to have a sister called Mary, you will
address her--even though she should be married--as Marya Ivanovna
(pronounced Ivanna).
Immediately on his arrival young Schmidt had set himself vigorously
to reorganise the estate and improve the method of agriculture.
Some ploughs, harrows, and other implements which had been imported
at a former period were dragged out of the obscurity in which they
had lain for several years, and an attempt was made to farm on
scientific principles. The attempt was far from being completely
successful, for the serfs--this was before the Emancipation--could
not be made to work like regularly trained German labourers. In
spite of all admonitions, threats, and punishments, they persisted
in working slowly, listlessly, inaccurately, and occasionally they
broke the new instruments from carelessness or some more culpable
motive. Karl Karl'itch was not naturally a hard-hearted man, but
he was very rigid in his notions of duty, and could be cruelly
severe when his orders were not executed with an accuracy and
punctuality that seemed to the Russian rustic mind mere useless
pedantry. The serfs did not offer him any open opposition, and
were always obsequiously respectful in their demeanour towards him,
but they invariably frustrated his plans by their carelessness and
stolid, passive resistance.
Thus arose that silent conflict and that smouldering mutual enmity
which almost always result from the contact of the Teuton with the
Slav. The serfs instinctively regretted the good old times, when
they lived under the rough-and-ready patriarchal rule of their
masters, assisted by a native "burmister," or overseer, who was one
of themselves. The burmister had not always been honest in his
dealings with them, and the master had often, when in anger,
ordered severe punishments to be inflicted; but the burmister had
not attempted to make them change their old habits, and had shut
his eves to many little sins of emission and commission, whilst the
master was always ready to assist them in difficulties, and
commonly treated them in a kindly, familiar way. As the old
Russian proverb has it, "Where danger is, there too is kindly
forgiveness." Karl Karl'itch, on the contrary, was the
personification of uncompassionate, inflexible law. Blind rage and
compassionate kindliness were alike foreign to his system of
government. If he had any feeling towards the serfs, it was one of
chronic contempt. The word durak (blockhead) was constantly on his
lips, and when any bit of work was well done, he took it as a
matter of course, and never thought of giving a word of approval or
encouragement.
When it became evident, in 1859, that the emancipation of the serfs
was at hand, Karl Karl'itch confidently predicted that the country
would inevitably go to ruin. He knew by experience that the
peasants were lazy and improvident, even when they lived under the
tutelage of a master, and with the fear of the rod before their
eyes. What would they become when this guidance and salutary
restraint should be removed? The prospect raised terrible
forebodings in the mind of the worthy steward, who had his
employer's interests really at heart; and these forebodings were
considerably increased and intensified when he learned that the
peasants were to receive by law the land which they occupied on
sufferance, and which comprised about a half of the whole arable
land of the estate. This arrangement he declared to be a dangerous
and unjustifiable infraction of the sacred rights of property,
which savoured strongly of communism, and could have but one
practical result: the emancipated peasants would live by the
cultivation of their own land, and would not consent on any terms
to work for their former master.
In the few months which immediately followed the publication of the
Emancipation Edict in 1861, Karl Karl'itch found much to confirm
his most gloomy apprehensions. The peasants showed themselves
dissatisfied with the privileges conferred upon them, and sought to
evade the corresponding duties imposed on them by the new law. In
vain he endeavoured, by exhortations, promises, and threats, to get
the most necessary part of the field-work done, and showed the
peasants the provision of the law enjoining them to obey and work
as of old until some new arrangement should be made. To all his
appeals they replied that, having been freed by the Tsar, they were
no longer obliged to work for their former master; and he was at
last forced to appeal to the authorities. This step had a certain
effect, but the field-work was executed that year even worse than
usual, and the harvest suffered in consequence.
Since that time things had gradually improved. The peasants had
discovered that they could not support themselves and pay their
taxes from the land ceded to them, and had accordingly consented to
till the proprietor's fields for a moderate recompense. "These
last two years," said Karl Karl'itch to me, with an air of honest
self-satisfaction, "I have been able, after paying all expenses, to
transmit little sums to the young master in St. Petersburg. It was
certainly not much, but it shows that things are better than they
were. Still, it is hard, uphill work. The peasants have not been
improved by liberty. They now work less and drink more than they
did in the times of serfage, and if you say a word to them they'll
go away, and not work for you at all." Here Karl Karl'itch
indemnified himself for his recent self-control in the presence of
his workers by using a series of the strongest epithets which the
combined languages of his native and of his adopted country could
supply. "But laziness and drunkenness are not their only faults.
They let their cattle wander into our fields, and never lose an
opportunity of stealing firewood from the forest."
"But you have now for such matters the rural justices of the
peace," I ventured to suggest.
"The justices of the peace!" . . . Here Karl Karl'itch used an
inelegant expression, which showed plainly that he was no
unqualified admirer of the new judicial institutions. "What is the
use of applying to the justices? The nearest one lives six miles
off, and when I go to him he evidently tries to make me lose as
much time as possible. I am sure to lose nearly a whole day, and
at the end of it I may find that I have got nothing for my pains.
These justices always try to find some excuse for the peasant, and
when they do condemn, by way of exception, the affair does not end
there. There is pretty sure to be a pettifogging practitioner
prowling about--some rascally scribe who has been dismissed from
the public offices for pilfering and extorting too openly--and he
is always ready to whisper to the peasant that he should appeal.
The peasant knows that the decision is just, but he is easily
persuaded that by appealing to the Monthly Sessions he gets another
chance in the lottery, and may perhaps draw a prize. He lets the
rascally scribe, therefore, prepare an appeal for him, and I
receive an invitation to attend the Session of Justices in the
district town on a certain day.
"It is a good five-and-thirty miles to the district town, as you
know, but I get up early, and arrive at eleven o'clock, the hour
stated in the official notice. A crowd of peasants are hanging
about the door of the court, but the only official present is the
porter. I enquire of him when my case is likely to come on, and
receive the laconic answer, 'How should I know?' After half an
hour the secretary arrives. I repeat my question, and receive the
same answer. Another half hour passes, and one of the justices
drives up in his tarantass. Perhaps he is a glib-tongued
gentleman, and assures me that the proceedings will commence at
once: 'Sei tchas! sei tchas!' Don't believe what the priest or the
dictionary tells you about the meaning of that expression. The
dictionary will tell you that it means 'immediately,' but that's
all nonsense. In the mouth of a Russian it means 'in an hour,'
'next week,' 'in a year or two,' 'never'--most commonly 'never.'
Like many other words in Russian, 'sei tchas' can be understood
only after long experience. A second justice drives up, and then a
third. No more are required by law, but these gentlemen must first
smoke several cigarettes and discuss all the local news before they
begin work.
"At last they take their seats on the bench--a slightly elevated
platform at one end of the room, behind a table covered with green
baize--and the proceedings commence. My case is sure to be pretty
far down on the list--the secretary takes, I believe, a malicious
pleasure in watching my impatience--and before it is called the
justices have to retire at least once for refreshments and
cigarettes. I have to amuse myself by listening to the other
cases, and some of them, I can assure you, are amusing enough. The
walls of that room must be by this time pretty well saturated with
perjury, and many of the witnesses catch at once the infection.
Perhaps I may tell you some other time a few of the amusing
incidents that I have seen there. At last my case is called. It
is as clear as daylight, but the rascally pettifogger is there with
a long-prepared speech, he holds in his hand a small volume of the
codified law, and quotes paragraphs which no amount of human
ingenuity can make to bear upon the subject. Perhaps the previous
decision is confirmed; perhaps it is reversed; in either case, I
have lost a second day and exhausted more patience than I can
conveniently spare. And something even worse may happen, as I know
by experience. Once during a case of mine there was some little
informality--someone inadvertently opened the door of the
consulting-room when the decision was being written, or some other
little incident of the sort occurred, and the rascally pettifogger
complained to the Supreme Court of Revision, which is a part of the
Senate. The case was all about a few roubles, but it was discussed
in St. Petersburg, and afterwards tried over again by another court
of justices. Now I have paid my Lehrgeld, and go no more to law."
"Then you must expose yourself to all kinds of extortion?"
"Not so much as you might imagine. I have my own way of dispensing
justice. When I catch a peasant's horse or cow in our fields, I
lock it up and make the owner pay a ransom."
"Is it not rather dangerous," I inquired, "to take the law thus
into your own hands? I have heard that the Russian justices are
extremely severe against any one who has recourse to what our
German jurists call Selbsthulfe."
"That they are! So long as you are in Russia, you had much better
let yourself be quietly robbed than use any violence against the
robber. It is less trouble, and it is cheaper in the long run. If
you do not, you may unexpectedly find yourself some fine morning in
prison! You must know that many of the young justices belong to
the new school of morals."
"What is that? I have not heard of any new discoveries lately in
the sphere of speculative ethics."
"Well, to tell you the truth, I am not one of the initiated, and I
can only tell you what I hear. So far as I have noticed, the
representatives of the new doctrine talk chiefly about Gumannost'
and Tchelovetcheskoe dostoinstvo. You know what these words mean?"
"Humanity, or rather humanitarianism and human dignity," I replied,
not sorry to give a proof that I was advancing in my studies.
"There, again, you allow your dictionary and your priest to mislead
you. These terms, when used by a Russian, cover much more than we
understand by them, and those who use them most frequently have
generally a special tenderness for all kinds of malefactors. In
the old times, malefactors were popularly believed to be bad,
dangerous people; but it has been lately discovered that this is a
delusion. A young proprietor who lives not far off assures me that
they are the true Protestants, and the most powerful social
reformers! They protest practically against those imperfections of
social organisation of which they are the involuntary victims. The
feeble, characterless man quietly submits to his chains; the bold,
generous, strong man breaks his fetters, and helps others to do the
same. A very ingenious defence of all kinds of rascality, isn't
it?"
"Well, it is a theory that might certainly be carried too far, and
might easily lead to very inconvenient conclusions; but I am not
sure that, theoretically speaking, it does not contain a certain
element of truth. It ought at least to foster that charity which
we are enjoined to practise towards all men. But perhaps 'all men'
does not include publicans and sinners?"
On hearing these words Karl Karl'itch turned to me, and every
feature of his honest German face expressed the most undisguised
astonishment. "Are you, too, a Nihilist?" he inquired, as soon as
he had partially recovered his breath.
"I really don't know what a Nihilist is, but I may assure you that
I am not an 'ist' of any kind. What is a Nihilist?"
"If you live long in Russia you'll learn that without my telling
you. As I was saying, I am not at all afraid of the peasants
citing me before the justice. They know better now. If they gave
me too much trouble I could starve their cattle."
"Yes, when you catch them in your fields," I remarked, taking no
notice of the abrupt turn which he had given to the conversation.
"I can do it without that. You must know that, by the Emancipation
Law, the peasants received arable land, but they received little or
no pasturage. I have the whip hand of them there!"
The remarks of Karl Karl'itch on men and things were to me always
interesting, for he was a shrewd observer, and displayed
occasionally a pleasant, dry humour. But I very soon discovered
that his opinions were not to be accepted without reserve. His
strong, inflexible Teutonic nature often prevented him from judging
impartially. He had no sympathy with the men and the institutions
around him, and consequently he was unable to see things from the
inside. The specks and blemishes on the surface he perceived
clearly enough, but he had no knowledge of the secret, deep-rooted
causes by which these specks and blemishes were produced. The
simple fact that a man was a Russian satisfactorily accounted, in
his opinion, for any kind of moral deformity; and his knowledge
turned out to be by no means so extensive as I had at first
supposed. Though he had been many years in the country, he knew
very little about the life of the peasants beyond that small part
of it which concerned directly his own interests and those of his
employer. Of the communal organisation, domestic life, religious
beliefs, ceremonial practices, and nomadic habits of his humble
neighbours, he knew little, and the little he happened to know was
far from accurate. In order to gain a knowledge of these matters
it would be better, I perceived, to consult the priest, or, better
still, the peasants themselves. But to do this it would be
necessary to understand easily and speak fluently the colloquial
language, and I was still very far from having, acquired the
requisite proficiency.
Even for one who possesses a natural facility for acquiring foreign
tongues, the learning of Russian is by no means an easy task.
Though it is essentially an Aryan language like our own, and
contains only a slight intermixture of Tartar words,--such as
bashlyk (a hood), kalpak (a night-cap), arbuz (a water-melon),
etc.--it has certain sounds unknown to West-European ears, and
difficult for West-European tongues, and its roots, though in great
part derived from the same original stock as those of the Graeco-
Latin and Teutonic languages, are generally not at all easily
recognised. As an illustration of this, take the Russian word
otets. Strange as it may at first sight appear, this word is
merely another form of our word father, of the German vater, and of
the French pere. The syllable ets is the ordinary Russian
termination denoting the agent, corresponding to the English and
German ending er, as we see in such words as--kup-ets (a buyer),
plov-ets (a swimmer), and many others. The root ot is a mutilated
form of vot, as we see in the word otchina (a paternal
inheritance), which is frequently written votchina. Now vot is
evidently the same root as the German vat in Vater, and the English
fath in father. Quod erat demonstrandum.
All this is simple enough, and goes to prove the fundamental
identity, or rather the community of origin, of the Slav and
Teutonic languages; but it will be readily understood that
etymological analogies so carefully disguised are of little
practical use in helping us to acquire a foreign tongue. Besides
this, the grammatical forms and constructions in Russian are very
peculiar, and present a great many strange irregularities. As an
illustration of this we may take the future tense. The Russian
verb has commonly a simple and a frequentative future. The latter
is always regularly formed by means of an auxiliary with the
infinitive, as in English, but the former is constructed in a
variety of ways, for which no rule can be given, so that the simple
future of each individual verb must be learned by a pure effort of
memory. In many verbs it is formed by prefixing a preposition, but
it is impossible to determine by rule which preposition should be
used. Thus idu (I go) becomes poidu; pishu (I write) becomes
napishu; pyu (I drink) becomes vuipyu, and so on.
Closely akin to the difficulties of pronunciation is the difficulty
of accentuating the proper syllable. In this respect Russian is
like Greek; you can rarely tell a priori on what syllable the
accent falls. But it is more puzzling than Greek, for two reasons:
firstly, it is not customary to print Russian with accents; and
secondly, no one has yet been able to lay down precise rules for
the transposition of the accent in the various inflections of the
same word, Of this latter peculiarity, let one illustration
suffice. The word ruka (hand) has the accent on the last syllable,
but in the accusative (ruku) the accent goes back to the first
syllable. It must not, however, be assumed that in all words of
this type a similar transposition takes place. The word beda
(misfortune), for instance, as well as very many others, always
retains the accent on the last syllable.
These and many similar difficulties, which need not be here
enumerated, can be mastered only by long practice. Serious as they
are, they need not frighten any one who is in the habit of learning
foreign tongues. The ear and the tongue gradually become familiar
with the peculiarities of inflection and accentuation, and practice
fulfils the same function as abstract rules.
It is commonly supposed that Russians have been endowed by Nature
with a peculiar linguistic talent. Their own language, it is said,
is so difficult that they have no difficulty in acquiring others.
This common belief requires, as it seems to me, some explanation.
That highly educated Russians are better linguists than the
educated classes of Western Europe there can be no possible doubt,
for they almost always speak French, and often English and German
also. The question, however, is whether this is the result of a
psychological peculiarity, or of other causes. Now, without
venturing to deny the existence of a natural faculty, I should say
that the other causes have at least exercised a powerful influence.
Any Russian who wishes to be regarded as civilise must possess at
least one foreign language; and, as a consequence of this, the
children of the upper classes are always taught at least French in
their infancy. Many households comprise a German nurse, a French
tutor, and an English governess; and the children thus become
accustomed from their earliest years to the use of these three
languages. Besides this, Russian is phonetically very rich and
contains nearly all the sounds which are to be found in West-
European tongues. Perhaps on the whole it would be well to apply
here the Darwinian theory, and suppose that the Russian Noblesse,
having been obliged for several generations to acquire foreign
languages, have gradually developed a hereditary polyglot talent.
Several circumstances concurred to assist me in my efforts, during
my voluntary exile, to acquire at least such a knowledge of the
language as would enable me to converse freely with the peasantry.
In the first place, my reverend teacher was an agreeable, kindly,
talkative man, who took a great delight in telling interminable
stories, quite independently of any satisfaction which he might
derive from the consciousness of their being understood and
appreciated. Even when walking alone he was always muttering
something to an imaginary listener. A stranger meeting him on such
occasions might have supposed that he was holding converse with
unseen spirits, though his broad muscular form and rubicund face
militated strongly against such a supposition; but no man, woman,
or child living within a radius of ten miles would ever have fallen
into this mistake. Every one in the neighbourhood knew that
"Batushka" (papa), as he was familiarly called, was too prosaical,
practical a man to see things ethereal, that he was an
irrepressible talker, and that when he could not conveniently find
an audience he created one by his own imagination. This
peculiarity of his rendered me good service. Though for some time
I understood very little of what he said, and very often misplaced
the positive and negative monosyllables which I hazarded
occasionally by way of encouragement, he talked vigorously all the
same. Like all garrulous people, he was constantly repeating
himself; but to this I did not object, for the custom--however
disagreeable in ordinary society--was for me highly beneficial, and
when I had already heard a story once or twice before, it was much
easier for me to assume at the proper moment the requisite
expression of countenance.
Another fortunate circumstance was that at Ivanofka there were no
distractions, so that the whole of the day and a great part of the
night could be devoted to study. My chief amusement was an
occasional walk in the fields with Karl Karl'itch; and even this
mild form of dissipation could not always be obtained, for as soon
as rain had fallen it was difficult to go beyond the verandah--the
mud precluding the possibility of a constitutional. The nearest
approach to excitement was mushroom-gathering; and in this
occupation my inability to distinguish the edible from the
poisonous species made my efforts unacceptable. We lived so "far
from the madding crowd" that its din scarcely reached our ears. A
week or ten days might pass without our receiving any intelligence
from the outer world. The nearest post-office was in the district
town, and with that distant point we had no regular system of
communication. Letters and newspapers remained there till called
for, and were brought to us intermittently when some one of our
neighbours happened to pass that way. Current history was thus
administered to us in big doses.
One very big dose I remember well. For a much longer time than
usual no volunteer letter-carrier had appeared, and the delay was
more than usually tantalising, because it was known that war had
broken out between France and Germany. At last a big bundle of a
daily paper called the Golos was brought to me. Impatient to learn
whether any great battle had been fought, I began by examining the
latest number, and stumbled at once on an article headed, "Latest
Intelligence: the Emperor at Wilhelmshohe!!!" The large type in
which the heading was printed and the three marks of exclamation
showed plainly that the article was very important. I began to
read with avidity, but was utterly mystified. What emperor was
this? Probably the Tsar or the Emperor of Austria, for there was
no German Emperor in those days. But no! It was evidently the
Emperor of the French. And how did Napoleon get to Wilhelmshohe?
The French must have broken through the Rhine defences, and pushed
far into Germany. But no! As I read further, I found this theory
equally untenable. It turned out that the Emperor was surrounded
by Germans, and--a prisoner! In order to solve the mystery, I had
to go back to the preceding numbers of the paper, and learned, at a
sitting, all about the successive German victories, the defeat and
capitulation of Macmahon's army at Sedan, and the other great
events of that momentous time. The impression produced can
scarcely be realised by those who have always imbibed current
history in the homeopathic doses administered by the morning and
evening daily papers.
By the useful loquacity of my teacher and the possibility of
devoting all my time to my linguistic studies, I made such rapid
progress in the acquisition of the language that I was able after a
few weeks to understand much of what was said to me, and to express
myself in a vague, roundabout way. In the latter operation I was
much assisted by a peculiar faculty of divination which the
Russians possess in a high degree. If a foreigner succeeds in
expressing about one-fourth of an idea, the Russian peasant can
generally fill up the remaining three-fourths from his own
intuition.
As my powers of comprehension increased, my long conversations with
the priest became more and more instructive. At first his remarks
and stories had for me simply a philological interest, but
gradually I perceived that his talk contained a great deal of
solid, curious information regarding himself and the class to which
he belonged--information of a kind not commonly found in
grammatical exercises. Some of this I now propose to communicate
to the reader.
CHAPTER IV
THE VILLAGE PRIEST
Priests' Names--Clerical Marriages--The White and the Black Clergy--
Why the People do not Respect the Parish Priests--History of the
White Clergy--The Parish Priest and the Protestant Pastor--In What
Sense the Russian People are Religious--Icons--The Clergy and
Popular Education--Ecclesiastical Reform--Premonitory Symptoms of
Change--Two Typical Specimens of the Parochial Clergy of the
Present Day.
In formal introductions it is customary to pronounce in a more or
less inaudible voice the names of the two persons introduced.
Circumstances compel me in the present case to depart from received
custom. The truth is, I do not know the names of the two people
whom I wish to bring together! The reader who knows his own name
will readily pardon one-half of my ignorance, but he may naturally
expect that I should know the name of a man with whom I profess to
be acquainted, and with whom I daily held long conversations during
a period of several months. Strange as it may seem, I do not.
During all the time of my sojourn in Ivanofka I never heard him
addressed or spoken of otherwise than as "Batushka." Now
"Batushka" is not a name at all. It is simply the diminutive form
of an obsolete word meaning "father," and is usually applied to all
village priests. The ushka is a common diminutive termination, and
the root Bat is evidently the same as that which appears in the
Latin pater.
Though I do not happen to know what Batushka's family name was, I
can communicate two curious facts concerning it: he had not
possessed it in his childhood, and it was not the same as his
father's.
The reader whose intuitive powers have been preternaturally
sharpened by a long course of sensation novels will probably leap
to the conclusion that Batushka was a mysterious individual, very
different from what he seemed--either the illegitimate son of some
great personage, or a man of high birth who had committed some
great sin, and who now sought oblivion and expiation in the humble
duties of a parish priest. Let me dispel at once all delusions of
this kind. Batushka was actually as well as legally the legitimate
son of an ordinary parish priest, who was still living, about
twenty miles off, and for many generations all his paternal and
maternal ancestors, male and female, had belonged to the priestly
caste. He was thus a Levite of the purest water, and thoroughly
Levitical in his character. Though he knew by experience something
about the weakness of the flesh, he had never committed any sins of
the heroic kind, and had no reason to conceal his origin. The
curious facts above stated were simply the result of a peculiar
custom which exists among the Russian clergy. According to this
custom, when a boy enters the seminary he receives from the Bishop
a new family name. The name may be Bogoslafski, from a word
signifying "Theology," or Bogolubof, "the love of God," or some
similar term; or it may be derived from the name of the boy's
native village, or from any other word which the Bishop thinks fit
to choose. I know of one instance where a Bishop chose two French
words for the purpose. He had intended to call the boy
Velikoselski, after his native place, Velikoe Selo, which means
"big village"; but finding that there was already a Velikoselski in
the seminary, and being in a facetious frame of mind, he called the
new comer Grandvillageski--a word that may perhaps sorely puzzle
some philologist of the future.
My reverend teacher was a tall, muscular man of about forty years
of age, with a full dark-brown beard, and long lank hair falling
over his shoulders. The visible parts of his dress consisted of
three articles--a dingy-brown robe of coarse material buttoned
closely at the neck and descending to the ground, a wideawake hat,
and a pair of large, heavy boots. As to the esoteric parts of his
attire, I refrained from making investigations. His life had been
an uneventful one. At an early age he had been sent to the
seminary in the chief town of the province, and had made for
himself the reputation of a good average scholar. "The seminary of
that time," he used to say to me, referring to that part of his
life, "was not what it is now. Nowadays the teachers talk about
humanitarianism, and the boys would think that a crime had been
committed against human dignity if one of them happened to be
flogged. But they don't consider that human dignity is at all
affected by their getting drunk, and going to--to--to places that I
never went to. I was flogged often enough, and I don't think that
I am a worse man on that account; and though I never heard then
anything about pedagogical science that they talk so much about
now, I'll read a bit of Latin yet with the best of them.
"When my studies were finished," said Batushka, continuing the
simple story of his life, "the Bishop found a wife for me, and I
succeeded her father, who was then an old man. In that way I
became a priest of Ivanofka, and have remained here ever since. It
is a hard life, for the parish is big, and my bit of land is not
very fertile; but, praise be to God! I am healthy and strong, and
get on well enough."
"You said that the Bishop found a wife for you," I remarked. "I
suppose, therefore, that he was a great friend of yours."
"Not at all. The Bishop does the same for all the seminarists who
wish to be ordained: it is an important part of his pastoral
duties."
"Indeed!" I exclaimed in astonishment. "Surely that is carrying
the system of paternal government a little too far. Why should his
Reverence meddle with things that don't concern him?"
"But these matters do concern him. He is the natural protector of
widows and orphans, especially among the clergy of his own diocese.
When a parish priest dies, what is to become of his wife and
daughters?"
Not perceiving clearly the exact bearing of these last remarks, I
ventured to suggest that priests ought to economise in view of
future contingencies.
"It is easy to speak," replied Batushka: "'A story is soon told,'
as the old proverb has it, 'but a thing is not soon done.' How are
we to economise? Even without saving we have the greatest
difficulty to make the two ends meet."
"Then the widow and daughters might work and gain a livelihood."
"What, pray, could they work at?" asked Batushka, and paused for a
reply. Seeing that I had none to offer him, he continued, "Even
the house and land belong not to them, but to the new priest."
"If that position occurred in a novel," I said, "I could foretell
what would happen. The author would make the new priest fall in
love with and marry one of the daughters, and then the whole
family, including the mother-in-law, would live happily ever
afterwards."
"That is exactly how the Bishop arranges the matter. What the
novelist does with the puppets of his imagination, the Bishop does
with real beings of flesh and blood. As a rational being he cannot
leave things to chance. Besides this, he must arrange the matter
before the young man takes orders, because, by the rules of the
Church, the marriage cannot take place after the ceremony of
ordination. When the affair is arranged before the charge becomes
vacant, the old priest can die with the pleasant consciousness that
his family is provided for."
"Well, Batushka, you certainly put the matter in a very plausible
way, but there seem to be two flaws in the analogy. The novelist
can make two people fall in love with each other, and make them
live happily together with the mother-in-law, but that--with all
due respect to his Reverence, be it said--is beyond the power of a
Bishop."
"I am not sure," said Batushka, avoiding the point of the
objection, "that love-marriages are always the happiest ones; and
as to the mother-in-law, there are--or at least there were until
the emancipation of the serfs--a mother-in-law and several
daughters-in-law in almost every peasant household."
"And does harmony generally reign in peasant households?"
"That depends upon the head of the house. If he is a man of the
right sort, he can keep the women-folks in order." This remark was
made in an energetic tone, with the evident intention of assuring
me that the speaker was himself "a man of the right sort"; but I
did not attribute much importance to it, for I have occasionally
heard henpecked husbands talk in this grandiloquent way when their
wives were out of hearing. Altogether I was by no means convinced
that the system of providing for the widows and orphans of the
clergy by means of mariages de convenance was a good one, but I
determined to suspend my judgment until I should obtain fuller
information.
An additional bit of evidence came to me a week or two later. One
morning, on going into the priest's house, I found that he had a
friend with him--the priest of a village some fifteen miles off.
Before we had got through the ordinary conventional remarks about
the weather and the crops, a peasant drove up to the door in his
cart with a message that an old peasant was dying in a neighbouring
village, and desired the last consolations of religion. Batushka
was thus obliged to leave us, and his friend and I agreed to stroll
leisurely in the direction of the village to which he was going, so
as to meet him on his way home. The harvest was already finished,
so that our road, after emerging from the village, lay through
stubble-fields. Beyond this we entered the pine forest, and by the
time we had reached this point I had succeeded in leading the
conversation to the subject of clerical marriages.
"I have been thinking a good deal on this subject," I said, "and I
should very much like to know your opinion about the system."
My new acquaintance was a tall, lean, black-haired man, with a
sallow complexion and vinegar aspect--evidently one of those
unhappy mortals who are intended by Nature to take a pessimistic
view of all things, and to point out to their fellows the deep
shadows of human life. I was not at all surprised, therefore, when
be replied in a deep, decided tone, "Bad, very bad--utterly bad!"
The way in which these words were pronounced left no doubt as to
the opinion of the speaker, but I was desirous of knowing on what
that opinion was founded--more especially as I seemed to detect in
the tone a note of personal grievance. My answer was shaped
accordingly.
"I suspected that; but in the discussions which I have had I have
always been placed at a disadvantage, not being able to adduce any
definite facts in support of my opinion."
"You may congratulate yourself on being unable to find any in your
own experience. A mother-in-law living in the house does not
conduce to domestic harmony. I don't know how it is in your
country, but so it is with us."
I hastened to assure him that this was not a peculiarity of Russia.
"I know it only too well," he continued. "My mother-in-law lived
with me for some years, and I was obliged at last to insist on her
going to another son-in-law."
"Rather selfish conduct towards your brother-in-law," I said to
myself, and then added audibly, "I hope you have thus solved the
difficulty satisfactorily."
"Not at all. Things are worse now than they were. I agreed to pay
her three roubles a month, and have regularly fulfilled my promise,
but lately she has thought it not enough, and she made a complaint
to the Bishop. Last week I went to him to defend myself, but as I
had not money enough for all the officials in the Consistorium, I
could not obtain justice. My mother-in-law had made all sorts of
absurd accusations against me, and consequently I was laid under an
inhibition for six weeks!"
"And what is the effect of an inhibition?"
"The effect is that I cannot perform the ordinary rites of our
religion. It is really very unjust," he added, assuming an
indignant tone, "and very annoying. Think of all the hardship and
inconvenience to which it gives rise."
As I thought of the hardship and inconvenience to which the
parishioners must be exposed through the inconsiderate conduct of
the old mother-in-law, I could not but sympathise with my new
acquaintance's indignation. My sympathy was, however, somewhat
cooled when I perceived that I was on a wrong tack, and that the
priest was looking at the matter from an entirely different point
of view.
"You see," he said, "it is a most unfortunate time of year. The
peasants have gathered in their harvest, and can give of their
abundance. There are merry-makings and marriages, besides the
ordinary deaths and baptisms. Altogether I shall lose by the thing
more than a hundred roubles!"
I confess I was a little shocked on hearing the priest thus speak
of his sacred functions as if they were an ordinary marketable
commodity, and talk of the inhibition as a pushing undertaker might
talk of sanitary improvements. My surprise was caused not by the
fact that he regarded the matter from a pecuniary point of view--
for I was old enough to know that clerical human nature is not
altogether insensible to pecuniary considerations--but by the fact
that he should thus undisguisedly express his opinions to a
stranger without in the least suspecting that there was anything
unseemly in his way of speaking. The incident appeared to me very
characteristic, but I refrained from all audible comments, lest I
should inadvertently check his communicativeness. With the view of
encouraging it, I professed to be very much interested, as I really
was, in what he said, and I asked him how in his opinion the
present unsatisfactory state of things might be remedied.
"There is but one cure," he said, with a readiness that showed he
had often spoken on the theme already, "and that is freedom and
publicity. We full-grown men are treated like children, and
watched like conspirators. If I wish to preach a sermon--not that
I often wish to do such a thing, but there are occasions when it is
advisable--I am expected to show it first to the Blagotchinny, and--"
"I beg your pardon, who is the Blagotchinny?"
"The Blagotchinny is a parish priest who is in direct relations
with the Consistory of the Province, and who is supposed to
exercise a strict supervision over all the other parish priests of
his district. He acts as the spy of the Consistory, which is
filled with greedy, shameless officials, deaf to any one who does
not come provided with a handful of roubles. The Bishop may be a
good, well-intentioned man, but he always sees and acts through
these worthless subordinates. Besides this, the Bishops and heads
of monasteries, who monopolise the higher places in the
ecclesiastical Administration, all belong to the Black Clergy--that
is to say, they are all monks--and consequently cannot understand
our wants. How can they, on whom celibacy is imposed by the rules
of the Church, understand the position of a parish priest who has
to bring up a family and to struggle with domestic cares of every
kind? What they do is to take all the comfortable places for
themselves, and leave us all the hard work. The monasteries are
rich enough, and you see how poor we are. Perhaps you have heard
that the parish priests extort money from the peasants--refusing to
perform the rites of baptism or burial until a considerable sum has
been paid. It is only too true, but who is to blame? The priest
must live and bring up his family, and you cannot imagine the
humiliations to which he has to submit in order to gain a scanty
pittance. I know it by experience. When I make the periodical
visitation I can see that the peasants grudge every handful of rye
and every egg that they give me. I can overbear their sneers as I
go away, and I know they have many sayings such as--'The priest
takes from the living and from the dead.' Many of them fasten
their doors, pretending to be away from home, and do not even take
the precaution of keeping silent till I am out of hearing."
"You surprise me," I said, in reply to the last part of this long
tirade; "I have always heard that the Russians are a very religious
people--at least the lower classes."
"So they are; but the peasantry are poor and heavily taxed. They
set great importance on the sacraments, and observe rigorously the
fasts, which comprise nearly a half of the year; but they show very
little respect for their priests, who are almost as poor as
themselves."
"But I do not see clearly how you propose to remedy this state of
things."
"By freedom and publicity, as I said before." The worthy man
seemed to have learned this formula by rote. "First of all, our
wants must be made known. In some provinces there have been
attempts to do this by means of provincial assemblies of the
clergy, but these efforts have always been strenuously opposed by
the Consistories, whose members fear publicity above all things.
But in order to have publicity we must have more freedom."
Here followed a long discourse on freedom and publicity, which
seemed to me very confused. So far as I could understand the
argument, there was a good deal of reasoning in a circle. Freedom
was necessary in order to get publicity, and publicity was
necessary in order to get freedom; and the practical result would
be that the clergy would enjoy bigger salaries and more popular
respect. We had only got thus far in the investigation of the
subject when our conversation was interrupted by the rumbling of a
peasant's cart. In a few seconds our friend Batushka appeared, and
the conversation took a different turn.
Since that time I have frequently spoken on this subject with
competent authorities, and nearly all have admitted that the
present condition of the clergy is highly unsatisfactory, and that
the parish priest rarely enjoys the respect of his parishioners.
In a semi-official report, which I once accidentally stumbled upon
when searching for material of a different kind, the facts are
stated in the following plain language: "The people"--I seek to
translate as literally as possible--"do not respect the clergy, but
persecute them with derision and reproaches, and feel them to be a
burden. In nearly all the popular comic stories the priest, his
wife, or his labourer is held up to ridicule, and in all the
proverbs and popular sayings where the clergy are mentioned it is
always with derision. The people shun the clergy, and have
recourse to them not from the inner impulse of conscience, but from
necessity. . . . And why do the people not respect the clergy?
Because it forms a class apart; because, having received a false
kind of education, it does not introduce into the life of the
people the teaching of the Spirit, but remains in the mere dead
forms of outward ceremonial, at the same time despising these forms
even to blasphemy; because the clergy itself continually presents
examples of want of respect to religion, and transforms the service
of God into a profitable trade. Can the people respect the clergy
when they hear how one priest stole money from below the pillow of
a dying man at the moment of confession, how another was publicly
dragged out of a house of ill-fame, how a third christened a dog,
how a fourth whilst officiating at the Easter service was dragged
by the hair from the altar by the deacon? Is it possible for the
people to respect priests who spend their time in the gin-shop,
write fraudulent petitions, fight with the cross in their hands,
and abuse each other in bad language at the altar?
"One might fill several pages with examples of this kind--in each
instance naming the time and place--without overstepping the
boundaries of the province of Nizhni-Novgorod. Is it possible for
the people to respect the clergy when they see everywhere amongst
them simony, carelessness in performing the religious rites, and
disorder in administering the sacraments? Is it possible for the
people to respect the clergy when they see that truth has
disappeared from it, and that the Consistories, guided in their
decisions not by rules, but by personal friendship and bribery,
destroy in it the last remains of truthfulness? If we add to all
this the false certificates which the clergy give to those who do
not wish to partake of the Eucharist, the dues illegally extracted
from the Old Ritualists, the conversion of the altar into a source
of revenue, the giving of churches to priests' daughters as a
dowry, and similar phenomena, the question as to whether the people
can respect the clergy requires no answer."
As these words were written by an orthodox Russian,* celebrated for
his extensive and intimate knowledge of Russian provincial life,
and were addressed in all seriousness to a member of the Imperial
family, we may safely assume that they contain a considerable
amount of truth. The reader must not, however, imagine that all
Russian priests are of the kind above referred to. Many of them
are honest, respectable, well-intentioned men, who conscientiously
fulfil their humble duties, and strive hard to procure a good
education for their children. If they have less learning, culture,
and refinement than the Roman Catholic priesthood, they have at the
same time infinitely less fanaticism, less spiritual pride, and
less intolerance towards the adherents of other faiths.
* Mr. Melnikof, in a "secret" Report to the Grand Duke Constantine
Nikolaievitch.
Both the good and the bad qualities of the Russian priesthood at
the present time can be easily explained by its past history, and
by certain peculiarities of the national character.
The Russian White Clergy--that is to say, the parish priests, as
distinguished from the monks, who are called the Black Clergy--have
had a curious history. In primitive times they were drawn from all
classes of the population, and freely elected by the parishioners.
When a man was elected by the popular vote, he was presented to the
Bishop, and if he was found to be a fit and proper person for the
office, he was at once ordained. But this custom early fell into
disuse. The Bishops, finding that many of the candidates presented
were illiterate peasants, gradually assumed the right of appointing
the priests, with or without the consent of the parishioners; and
their choice generally fell on the sons of the clergy as the men
best fitted to take orders. The creation of Bishops' schools,
afterwards called seminaries, in which the sons of the clergy were
educated, naturally led, in the course of time, to the total
exclusion of the other classes. The policy of the civil Government
led to the same end. Peter the Great laid down the principle that
every subject should in some way serve the State--the nobles as
officers in the army or navy, or as officials in the civil service;
the clergy as ministers of religion; and the lower classes as
soldiers, sailors, or tax-payers. Of these three classes the
clergy had by far the lightest burdens, and consequently many
nobles and peasants would willingly have entered its ranks. But
this species of desertion the Government could not tolerate, and
accordingly the priesthood was surrounded by a legal barrier which
prevented all outsiders from entering it. Thus by the combined
efforts of the ecclesiastical and the civil Administration the
clergy became a separate class or caste, legally and actually
incapable of mingling with the other classes of the population.
The simple fact that the clergy became an exclusive caste, with a
peculiar character, peculiar habits, and peculiar ideals, would in
itself have had a prejudicial influence on the priesthood; but this
was not all. The caste increased in numbers by the process of
natural reproduction much more rapidly than the offices to be
filled, so that the supply of priests and deacons soon far exceeded
the demand; and the disproportion between supply and demand became
every year greater and greater. In this way was formed an ever-
increasing clerical Proletariat, which--as is always the case with
a Proletariat of any kind--gravitated towards the towns. In vain
the Government issued ukazes prohibiting the priests from quitting
their places of domicile, and treated as vagrants and runaways
those who disregarded the prohibition; in vain successive
sovereigns endeavoured to diminish the number of these
supernumeraries by drafting them wholesale into the army. In
Moscow, St. Petersburg, and all the larger towns the cry was,
"Still they come!" Every morning, in the Kremlin of Moscow, a
large crowd of them assembled for the purpose of being hired to
officiate in the private chapels of the rich nobles, and a great
deal of hard bargaining took place between the priests and the
lackeys sent to hire them--conducted in the same spirit, and in
nearly the same forms, as that which simultaneously took place in
the bazaar close by between extortionate traders and thrifty
housewives. "Listen to me," a priest would say, as an ultimatum,
to a lackey who was trying to beat down the price: "if you don't
give me seventy-five kopeks without further ado, I'll take a bite
of this roll, and that will be an end to it!" And that would have
been an end to the bargaining, for, according to the rules of the
Church, a priest cannot officiate after breaking his fast. The
ultimatum, however, could be used with effect only to country
servants who had recently come to town. A sharp lackey,
experienced in this kind of diplomacy, would have laughed at the
threat, and replied coolly, "Bite away, Batushka; I can find plenty
more of your sort!" Amusing scenes of this kind I have heard
described by old people who professed to have been eye-witnesses.
The condition of the priests who remained in the villages was not
much better. Those of them who were fortunate enough to find
places were raised at least above the fear of absolute destitution,
but their position was by no means enviable. They received little
consideration or respect from the peasantry, and still less from
the nobles. When the church was situated not on the State Domains,
but on a private estate, they were practically under the power of
the proprietor--almost as completely as his serfs; and sometimes
that power was exercised in a most humiliating and shameful way. I
have heard, for instance, of one priest who was ducked in a pond on
a cold winter day for the amusement of the proprietor and his
guests--choice spirits, of rough, jovial temperament; and of
another who, having neglected to take off his hat as he passed the
proprietor's house, was put into a barrel and rolled down a hill
into the river at the bottom!
In citing these incidents, I do not at all mean to imply that they
represent the relations which usually existed between proprietors
and village priests, for I am quite aware that wanton cruelty was
not among the ordinary vices of Russian serf-owners. My object in
mentioning the incidents is to show how a brutal proprietor--and it
must be admitted that they were not a few brutal individuals in the
class--could maltreat a priest without much danger of being called
to account for his conduct. Of course such conduct was an offence
in the eyes of the criminal law; but the criminal law of that time
was very shortsighted, and strongly disposed to close its eyes
completely when the offender was an influential proprietor. Had
the incidents reached the ears of the Emperor Nicholas he would
probably have ordered the culprit to be summarily and severely
punished but, as the Russian proverb has it, "Heaven is high, and
the Tsar is far off." A village priest treated in this barbarous
way could have little hope of redress, and, if he were a prudent
man, he would make no attempt to obtain it; for any annoyance which
he might give the proprietor by complaining to the ecclesiastical
authorities would be sure to be paid back to him with interest in
some indirect way.
The sons of the clergy who did not succeed in finding regular
sacerdotal employment were in a still worse position. Many of them
served as scribes or subordinate officials in the public offices,
where they commonly eked out their scanty salaries by unblushing
extortion and pilfering. Those who did not succeed in gaining even
modest employment of this kind had to keep off starvation by less
lawful means, and not unfrequently found their way into the prisons
or to Siberia.
In judging of the Russian priesthood of the present time, we must
call to mind this severe school through which it has passed, and we
must also take into consideration the spirit which has been for
centuries predominant in the Eastern Church--I mean the strong
tendency both in the clergy and in the laity to attribute an
inordinate importance to the ceremonial element of religion.
Primitive mankind is everywhere and always disposed to regard
religion as simply a mass of mysterious rites which have a secret
magical power of averting evil in this world and securing felicity
in the next. To this general rule the Russian peasantry are no
exception, and the Russian Church has not done all it might have
done to eradicate this conception and to bring religion into closer
association with ordinary morality. Hence such incidents as the
following are still possible: A robber kills and rifles a
traveller, but he refrains from eating a piece of cooked meat which
he finds in the cart, because it happens to be a fast-day; a
peasant prepares to rob a young attache of the Austrian Embassy in
St. Petersburg, and ultimately kills his victim, but before going
to the house he enters a church and commends his undertaking to the
protection of the saints; a housebreaker, when in the act of
robbing a church, finds it difficult to extract the jewels from an
Icon, and makes a vow that if a certain saint assists him he will
place a rouble's-worth of tapers before the saint's image! These
facts are within the memory of the present generation. I knew the
young attache, and saw him a few days before his death.
All these are of course extreme cases, but they illustrate a
tendency which in its milder forms is only too general amongst the
Russian people--the tendency to regard religion as a mass of
ceremonies which have a magical rather than a spiritual
significance. The poor woman who kneels at a religious procession
in order that the Icon may he carried over her head, and the rich
merchant who invites the priests to bring some famous Icon to his
house, illustrates this tendency in a more harmless form.
According to a popular saying, "As is the priest, so is the
parish," and the converse proposition is equally true--as is the
parish, so is the priest. The great majority of priests, like the
great majority of men in general, content themselves with simply
striving to perform what is expected of them, and their character
is consequently determined to a certain extent by the ideas and
conceptions of their parishioners. This will become more apparent
if we contrast the Russian priest with the Protestant pastor.
According to Protestant conceptions, the village pastor is a man of
grave demeanour and exemplary conduct, and possesses a certain
amount of education and refinement. He ought to expound weekly to
his flock, in simple, impressive words, the great truths of
Christianity, and exhort his hearers to walk in the paths of
righteousness. Besides this, he is expected to comfort the
afflicted, to assist the needy, to counsel those who are harassed
with doubts, and to admonish those who openly stray from the narrow
path. Such is the ideal in the popular mind, and pastors generally
seek to realise it, if not in very deed, at least in appearance.
The Russian priest, on the contrary, has no such ideal set before
him by his parishioners. He is expected merely to conform to
certain observances, and to perform punctiliously the rites and
ceremonies prescribed by the Church. If he does this without
practising extortion his parishioners are quite satisfied. He
rarely preaches or exhorts, and neither has nor seeks to have a
moral influence over his flock. I have occasionally heard of
Russian priests who approach to what I have termed the Protestant
ideal, and I have even seen one or two of them, but I fear they are
not numerous.
In the above contrast I have accidentally omitted one important
feature. The Protestant clergy have in all countries rendered
valuable service to the cause of popular education. The reason of
this is not difficult to find. In order to be a good Protestant it
is necessary to "search the Scriptures," and to do this, one must
be able at least to read. To be a good member of the Greek
Orthodox Church, on the contrary, according to popular conceptions,
the reading of the Scriptures is not necessary, and therefore
primary education has not in the eyes of the Greek Orthodox priest
the same importance which it has in the eyes of the Protestant
pastor.
It must be admitted that the Russian people are in a certain sense
religions. They go regularly to church on Sundays and holy-days,
cross themselves repeatedly when they pass a church or Icon, take
the Holy Communion at stated seasons, rigorously abstain from
animal food--not only on Wednesdays and Fridays, but also during
Lent and the other long fasts--make occasional pilgrimages to holy
shrines, and, in a word, fulfil punctiliously the ceremonial
observances which they suppose necessary for salvation. But here
their religiousness ends. They are generally profoundly ignorant
of religious doctrine, and know little or nothing of Holy Writ. A
peasant, it is said, was once asked by a priest if he could name
the three Persons of the Trinity, and replied without a moment's
hesitation, "How can one not know that, Batushka? Of course it is
the Saviour, the Mother of God, and Saint Nicholas the miracle-
worker!
That answer represents fairly enough the theological attainments of
a very large section of the peasantry. The anecdote is so often
repeated that it is probably an invention, but it is not a calumny
of theology and of what Protestants term the "inner religious life"
the orthodox Russian peasant--of Dissenters, to whom these remarks
do not apply, if shall speak later--has no conception. For him the
ceremonial part of religion suffices, and he has the most
unbounded, childlike confidence in the saving efficacy of the rites
which he practises. If he has been baptised in infancy, has
regularly observed the fasts, has annually partaken of the Holy
Communion, and has just confessed and received extreme unction, he
feels death approach with the most perfect tranquillity. He is
tormented with no doubts as to the efficacy of faith or works, and
has no fears that his past life may possibly have rendered him
unfit for eternal felicity. Like a man in a sinking ship who has
buckled on his life-preserver, he feels perfectly secure. With no
fear for the future and little regret for the present or the past,
he awaits calmly the dread summons, and dies with a resignation
which a Stoic philosopher might envy.
In the above paragraph I have used the word Icon, and perhaps the
reader may not clearly understand the word. Let me explain then,
briefly, what an Icon is--a very necessary explanation, for the
Icons play an important part in the religious observances of the
Russian people.
Icons are pictorial, usually half-length, representations of the
Saviour, of the Madonna, or of a saint, executed in archaic
Byzantine style, on a yellow or gold ground, and varying in size
from a square inch to several square feet. Very often the whole
picture, with the exception of the face and hands of the figure, is
covered with a metal plaque, embossed so as to represent the form
of the figure and the drapery. When this plaque is not used, the
crown and costume are often adorned with pearls and other precious
stones--sometimes of great price.
In respect of religions significance, Icons are of two kinds:
simple, and miraculous or miracle-working (tchudotvorny). The
former are manufactured in enormous quantities--chiefly in the
province of Vladimir, where whole villages are employed in this
kind of work--and are to be found in every Russian house, from the
hut of the peasant to the palace of the Emperor. They are
generally placed high up in a corner facing the door, and good
orthodox Christians on entering bow in that direction, making at
the same time the sign of the cross. Before and after meals the
same short ceremony is always performed. On the eve of fete-days a
small lamp is kept burning before at least one of the Icons in the
house.
The wonder-working Icons are comparatively few in number, and are
always carefully preserved in a church or chapel. They are
commonly believed to have been "not made with hands," and to have
appeared in a miraculous way. A monk, or it may be a common
mortal, has a vision, in which he is informed that he may find a
miraculous Icon in such a place, and on going to the spot indicated
he finds it, sometimes buried, sometimes hanging on a tree. The
sacred treasure is then removed to a church, and the news spreads
like wildfire through the district. Thousands flock to prostrate
themselves before the heaven-sent picture, and some are healed of
their diseases--a fact that plainly indicates its miracle-working
power. The whole affair is then officially reported to the Most
Holy Synod, the highest ecclesiastical authority in Russia, in
order that the existence of the miracle-working power may be fully
and regularly proved. The official recognition of the fact is by
no means a mere matter of form, for the Synod is well aware that
wonder-working Icons are always a rich source of revenue to the
monasteries where they are kept, and that zealous Superiors are
consequently apt in such cases to lean to the side of credulity,
rather than that of over-severe criticism. A regular investigation
is therefore made, and the formal recognition is not granted till
the testimony of the finder is thoroughly examined and the alleged
miracles duly authenticated. If the recognition is granted, the
Icon is treated with the greatest veneration, and is sure to be
visited by pilgrims from far and near.
Some of the most revered Icons--as, for instance, the Kazan
Madonna--have annual fete-days instituted in their honour; or, more
correctly speaking, the anniversary of their miraculous appearance
is observed as a religions holiday. A few of them have an
additional title to popular respect and veneration: that of being
intimately associated with great events in the national history.
The Vladimir Madonna, for example, once saved Moscow from the
Tartars; the Smolensk Madonna accompanied the army in the glorious
campaign against Napoleon in 1812; and when in that year it was
known in Moscow that the French were advancing on the city, the
people wished the Metropolitan to take the Iberian Madonna, which
may still be seen near one of the gates of the Kremlin, and to lead
them out armed with hatchets against the enemy.
If the Russian priests have done little to advance popular
education, they have at least never intentionally opposed it.
Unlike their Roman Catholic brethren, they do not hold that "a
little learning is a dangerous thing," and do not fear that faith
may be endangered by knowledge. Indeed, it is a remarkable fact
that the Russian Church regards with profound apathy those various
intellectual movements which cause serious alarm to many thoughtful
Christians in Western Europe. It considers religion as something
so entirely apart that its votaries do not feel the necessity of
bringing their theological beliefs into logical harmony with their
scientific conceptions. A man may remain a good orthodox Christian
long after he has adopted scientific opinions irreconcilable with
Eastern Orthodoxy, or, indeed, with dogmatic Christianity of any
kind. In the confessional the priest never seeks to ferret out
heretical opinions; and I can recall no instance in Russian history
of a man being burnt at the stake on the demand of the
ecclesiastical authorities, as so often happened in the Roman
Catholic world, for his scientific views. This tolerance proceeds
partly, no doubt, from the fact that the Eastern Church in general,
and the Russian Church in particular, have remained for centuries
in a kind of intellectual torpor. Even such a fervent orthodox
Christian as the late Ivan Aksakof perceived this absence of
healthy vitality, and he did not hesitate to declare his conviction
that neither the Russian nor the Slavonic world will be
resuscitated . . . so long as the Church remains in such
lifelessness (mertvennost'), which is not a matter of chance, but
the legitimate fruit of some organic defect." *
* Solovyoff, "Otcherki ig istorii Russkoi Literaturi XIX. veka."
St. Petersburg, 1903, p. 269.
Though the unsatisfactory condition of the parochial clergy is
generally recognised by the educated classes, very few people take
the trouble to consider seriously how it might be improved. During
the Reform enthusiasm which raged for some years after the Crimean
War ecclesiastical affairs were entirely overlooked. Many of the
reformers of those days were so very "advanced" that religion in
all its forms seemed to them an old-world superstition which tended
to retard rather than accelerate social progress, and which
consequently should be allowed to die as tranquilly as possible;
whilst the men of more moderate views found they had enough to do
in emancipating the serfs and reforming the corrupt civil and
judicial Administration. During the subsequent reactionary period,
which culminated in the reign of the late Emperor, Alexander III.,
much more attention was devoted to Church matters, and it came to
be recognised in official circles that something ought to be done
for the parish clergy in the way of improving their material
condition so as to increase their moral influence. With this
object in view, M. Pobedonostsef, the Procurator of the Holy Synod,
induced the Government in 1893 to make a State-grant of about
6,500,000 roubles, which should be increased every year, but the
sum was very inadequate, and a large portion of it was devoted to
purposes of political propaganda in the form of maintaining Greek
Orthodox priests in districts where the population was Protestant
or Roman Catholic. Consequently, of the 35,865 parishes which
Russia contains, only 18,936, or a little more than one-half, were
enabled to benefit by the grant. In an optimistic, semi-official
statement published as late as 1896 it is admitted that "the means
for the support of the parish clergy must even now be considered
insufficient and wanting in stability, making the priests dependent
on the parishioners, and thereby preventing the establishment of
the necessary moral authority of the spiritual father over his
flock."
In some places the needs of the Church are attended to by voluntary
parish-curatorships which annually raise a certain sum of money,
and the way in which they distribute it is very characteristic of
the Russian people, who have a profound veneration for the Church
and its rites, but very little consideration for the human beings
who serve at the altar. In 14,564 parishes possessing such
curatorships no less than 2,500,000 roubles were collected, but of
this sum 2,000,000 were expended on the maintenance and
embellishment of churches, and only 174,000 were devoted to the
personal wants of the clergy. According to the semi-official
document from which these figures are taken the whole body of the
Russian White Clergy in 1893 numbered 99,391, of whom 42,513 were
priests, 12,953 deacons, and 43,925 clerks.
In more recent observations among the parochial clergy I have
noticed premonitory symptoms of important changes. This may be
illustrated by an entry in my note-book, written in a village of
one of the Southern provinces, under date of 30th September, 1903:
"I have made here the acquaintance of two good specimens of the
parish clergy, both excellent men in their way, but very different
from each other. The elder one, Father Dmitri, is of the old
school, a plain, practical man, who fulfils his duties
conscientiously according to his lights, but without enthusiasm.
His intellectual wants are very limited, and he devotes his
attention chiefly to the practical affairs of everyday life, which
he manages very successfully. He does not squeeze his parishioners
unduly, but he considers that the labourer is worthy of his hire,
and insists on his flock providing for his wants according to their
means. At the same time he farms on his own account and attends
personally to all the details of his farming operations. With the
condition and doings of every member of his flock he is intimately
acquainted, and, on the whole, as he never idealised anything or
anybody, he has not a very high opinion of them.
"The younger priest, Father Alexander, is of a different type, and
the difference may be remarked even in his external appearance.
There is a look of delicacy and refinement about him, though his
dress and domestic surroundings are of the plainest, and there is
not a tinge of affectation in his manner. His language is less
archaic and picturesque. He uses fewer Biblical and semi-Slavonic
expressions--I mean expressions which belong to the antiquated
language of the Church Service rather than to modern parlance--and
his armoury of terse popular proverbs which constitute such a
characteristic trait of the peasantry, is less frequently drawn on.
When I ask him about the present condition of the peasantry, his
account does not differ substantially from that of his elder
colleague, but he does not condemn their sins in the same forcible
terms. He laments their shortcomings in an evangelical spirit and
has apparently aspirations for their future improvement. Admitting
frankly that there is a great deal of lukewarmness among them, he
hopes to revive their interest in ecclesiastical affairs and he has
an idea of constituting a sort of church committee for attending to
the temporal affairs of the village church and for works of
charity, but he looks to influencing the younger rather than the
older generation.
"His interest in his parishioners is not confined to their
spiritual welfare, but extends to their material well-being. Of
late an association for mutual credit has been founded in the
village, and he uses his influence to induce the peasants to take
advantage of the benefits it offers, both to those who are in need
of a little ready money and to those who might invest their
savings, instead of keeping them hidden away in an old stocking or
buried in an earthen pot. The proposal to create a local
agricultural society meets also with his sympathy."
If the number of parish priests of this type increase, the clergy
may come to exercise great moral influence on the common people.
CHAPTER V
A MEDICAL CONSULTATION
Unexpected Illness--A Village Doctor--Siberian Plague--My Studies--
Russian Historians--A Russian Imitator of Dickens--A ci-devant
Domestic Serf--Medicine and Witchcraft--A Remnant of Paganism--
Credulity of the Peasantry--Absurd Rumours--A Mysterious Visit from
St. Barbara--Cholera on Board a Steamer--Hospitals--Lunatic
Asylums--Amongst Maniacs.
In enumerating the requisites for travelling in the less frequented
parts of Russia, I omitted to mention one important condition: the
traveller should be always in good health, and in case of illness
be ready to dispense with regular medical attendance. This I
learned by experience during my stay at Ivanofka.
A man who is accustomed to be always well, and has consequently
cause to believe himself exempt from the ordinary ills that flesh
is heir to, naturally feels aggrieved--as if some one had inflicted
upon him an undeserved injury--when he suddenly finds himself ill.
At first he refuses to believe the fact, and, as far as possible,
takes no notice of the disagreeable symptoms.
Such was my state of mind on being awakened early one morning by
peculiar symptoms which I had never before experienced. Unwilling
to admit to myself the possibility of being ill, I got up, and
endeavoured to dress as usual, but very soon discovered that I was
unable to stand. There was no denying the fact; not only was I
ill, but the malady, whatever it was, surpassed my powers of
diagnosis; and when the symptoms increased steadily all that day
and the following night, I was constrained to take the humiliating
decision of asking for medical advice. To my inquiries whether
there was a doctor in the neighbourhood, the old servant replied,
"There is not exactly a doctor, but there is a Feldsher in the
village."
"And what is a Feldsher?"
"A Feldsher is . . . . is a Feldsher."
"I am quite aware of that, but I would like to know what you mean
by the word. What is this Feldsher?"
"He's an old soldier who dresses wounds and gives physic."
The definition did not predispose me in favour of the mysterious
personage, but as there was nothing better to be had I ordered him
to be sent for, notwithstanding the strenuous opposition of the old
servant, who evidently did not believe in feldshers.
In about half an hour a tall, broad-shouldered man entered, and
stood bolt upright in the middle of the room in the attitude which
is designated in military language by the word "Attention." His
clean-shaven chin, long moustache, and closely-cropped hair
confirmed one part of the old servant's definition; he was
unmistakably an old soldier.
"You are a Feldsher," I said, making use of the word which I had
recently added to my vocabulary.
"Exactly so, your Nobility!" These words, the ordinary form of
affirmation used by soldiers to their officers, were pronounced in
a loud, metallic, monotonous tone, as if the speaker had been an
automaton conversing with a brother automaton at a distance of
twenty yards. As soon as the words were pronounced the mouth of
the machine closed spasmodically, and the head, which had been
momentarily turned towards me, reverted to its former position with
a jerk as if it had received the order "Eyes front!"
"Then please to sit down here, and I'll tell you about my ailment."
Upon this the figure took three paces to the front, wheeled to the
right-about, and sat down on the edge of the chair, retaining the
position of "Attention" as nearly as the sitting posture would
allow. When the symptoms had been carefully described, he knitted
his brows, and after some reflection remarked, "I can give you a
dose of . . . ." Here followed a long word which I did not
understand.
"I don't wish you to give me a dose of anything till I know what is
the matter with me. Though a bit of a doctor myself, I have no
idea what it is, and, pardon me, I think you are in the same
position." Noticing a look of ruffled professional dignity on his
face, I added, as a sedative, "It is evidently something very
peculiar, so that if the first medical practitioner in the country
were present he would probably be as much puzzled as ourselves."
The sedative had the desired effect. "Well, sir, to tell you the
truth," he said, in a more human tone of voice, "I do not clearly
understand what it is."
"Exactly; and therefore I think we had better leave the cure to
Nature, and not interfere with her mode of treatment."
"Perhaps it would be better."
"No doubt. And now, since I have to lie here on my back, and feel
rather lonely, I should like to have a talk with you. You are not
in a hurry, I hope?"
"Not at all. My assistant knows where I am, and will send for me
if I am required."
"So you have an assistant, have you?"
"Oh, yes; a very sharp young fellow, who has been two years in the
Feldsher school, and has now come here to help me and learn more by
practice. That is a new way. I never was at a school of the kind
myself, and had to pick up what I could when a servant in the
hospital. There were, I believe, no such schools in my time. The
one where my assistant learned was opened by the Zemstvo."
"The Zemstvo is the new local administration, is it not?"
"Exactly so. And I could not do without the assistant," continued
my new acquaintance, gradually losing his rigidity, and showing
himself, what he really was, a kindly, talkative man. "I have
often to go to other villages, and almost every day a number of
peasants come here. At first I had very little to do, for the
people thought I was an official, and would make them pay dearly
for what I should give them; but now they know that they don't
require to pay, and come in great numbers. And everything I give
them--though sometimes I don't clearly understand what the matter
is--seems to do them good. I believe that faith does as much as
physic."
"In my country," I remarked, "there is a sect of doctors who get
the benefit of that principle. They give their patients two or
three little balls no bigger than a pin's head, or a few drops of
tasteless liquid, and they sometimes work wonderful cures."
"That system would not do for us. The Russian muzhik would have no
faith if he swallowed merely things of that kind. What he believes
in is something with a very bad taste, and lots of it. That is his
idea of a medicine; and he thinks that the more he takes of a
medicine the better chance he has of getting well. When I wish to
give a peasant several doses I make him come for each separate
dose, for I know that if I did not he would probably swallow the
whole as soon as he was out of sight. But there is not much
serious disease here--not like what I used to see on the Sheksna.
You have been on the Sheksna?"
"Not yet, but I intend going there." The Sheksna is a river which
falls into the Volga, and forms part of the great system of water-
communication connecting the Volga with the Neva.
"When you go there you will see lots of diseases. If there is a
hot summer, and plenty of barges passing, something is sure to
break out--typhus, or black small-pox, or Siberian plague, or
something of the kind. That Siberian plague is a curious thing.
Whether it really comes from Siberia, God only knows. So soon as
it breaks out the horses die by dozens, and sometimes men and women
are attacked, though it is not properly a human disease. They say
that flies carry the poison from the dead horses to the people.
The sign of it is a thing like a boil, with a dark-coloured rim.
If this is cut open in time the person may recover, but if it is
not, the person dies. There is cholera, too, sometimes."
"What a delightful country," I said to myself, "for a young doctor
who wishes to make discoveries in the science of disease!"
The catalogue of diseases inhabiting this favoured region was
apparently not yet complete, but it was cut short for the moment by
the arrival of the assistant, with the announcement that his
superior was wanted.
This first interview with the feldsher was, on the whole,
satisfactory. He had not rendered me any medical assistance, but
he had helped me to pass an hour pleasantly, and had given me a
little information of the kind I desired. My later interviews with
him were equally agreeable. He was naturally an intelligent,
observant man, who had seen a great deal of the Russian world, and
could describe graphically what he had seen. Unfortunately the
horizontal position to which I was condemned prevented me from
noting down at the time the interesting things which he related to
me. His visits, together with those of Karl Karl'itch and of the
priest, who kindly spent a great part of his time with me, helped
me to while away many an hour which would otherwise have been
dreary enough.
During the intervals when I was alone I devoted myself to reading--
sometimes Russian history and sometimes works of fiction. The
history was that of Karamzin, who may fairly be called the Russian
Livy. It interested me much by the facts which it contained, but
irritated me not a little by the rhetorical style in which it is
written. Afterwards, when I had waded through some twenty volumes
of the gigantic work of Solovyoff--or Solovief, as the name is
sometimes unphonetically written--which is simply a vast collection
of valuable but undigested material, I was much less severe on the
picturesque descriptions and ornate style of his illustrious
predecessor. The first work of fiction which I read was a
collection of tales by Grigorovitch, which had been given to me by
the author on my departure from St. Petersburg. These tales,
descriptive of rural life in Russia, had been written, as the
author afterwards admitted to me, under the influence of Dickens.
Many of the little tricks and affectations which became painfully
obtrusive in Dickens's later works I had no difficulty in
recognising under their Russian garb. In spite of these I found
the book very pleasant reading, and received from it some new
notions--to be afterwards verified, of course--about Russian
peasant life.
One of these tales made a deep impression upon me, and I still
remember the chief incidents. The story opens with the description
of a village in late autumn. It has been raining for some time
heavily, and the road has become covered with a deep layer of black
mud. An old woman--a small proprietor--is sitting at home with a
friend, drinking tea and trying to read the future by means of a
pack of cards. This occupation is suddenly interrupted by the
entrance of a female servant, who announces that she has discovered
an old man, apparently very ill, lying in one of the outhouses.
The old woman goes out to see her uninvited guest, and, being of a
kindly nature, prepares to have him removed to a more comfortable
place, and properly attended to; but her servant whispers to her
that perhaps he is a vagrant, and the generous impulse is thereby
checked. When it is discovered that the suspicion is only too well
founded, and that the man has no passport, the old woman becomes
thoroughly alarmed. Her imagination pictures to her the terrible
consequences that would ensue if the police should discover that
she had harboured a vagrant. All her little fortune might be
extorted from her. And if the old man should happen to die in her
house or farmyard! The consequences in that case might be very
serious. Not only might she lose everything, but she might even be
dragged to prison. At the sight of these dangers the old woman
forgets her tender-heartedness, and becomes inexorable. The old
man, sick unto death though he be, must leave the premises
instantly. Knowing full well that he will nowhere find a refuge,
he walks forth into the cold, dark, stormy night, and next morning
a dead body is found at a short distance from the village.
Why this story, which was not strikingly remarkable for artistic
merit, impressed me so deeply I cannot say. Perhaps it was because
I was myself ill at the time, and imagined how terrible it would be
to be turned out on the muddy road on a cold, wet October night.
Besides this, the story interested me as illustrating the terror
which the police inspired during the reign of Nicholas I. The
ingenious devices which they employed for extorting money formed
the subject of another sketch, which I read shortly afterwards, and
which has likewise remained in my memory. The facts were as
follows: An officer of rural police, when driving on a country
road, finds a dead body by the wayside. Congratulating himself on
this bit of good luck, he proceeds to the nearest village, and lets
the inhabitants know that all manner of legal proceedings will be
taken against them, so that the supposed murderer may be
discovered. The peasants are of course frightened, and give him a
considerable sum of money in order that he may hush up the affair.
An ordinary officer of police would have been quite satisfied with
this ransom, but this officer is not an ordinary man, and is very
much in need of money; he conceives, therefore, the brilliant idea
of repeating the experiment. Taking up the dead body, he takes it
away in his tarantass, and a few hours later declares to the
inhabitants of a village some miles off that some of them have been
guilty of murder, and that he intends to investigate the matter
thoroughly. The peasants of course pay liberally in order to
escape the investigation, and the rascally officer, emboldened by
success, repeats the trick in different villages until he has
gathered a large sum.
Tales and sketches of this kind were very much in fashion during
the years which followed the death of the great autocrat, Nicholas
I., when the long-pent-up indignation against his severe,
repressive regime was suddenly allowed free expression, and they
were still much read during the first years of my stay in the
country. Now the public taste has changed. The reform enthusiast
has evaporated, and the existing administrative abuses, more
refined and less comical than their predecessors, receive
comparatively little attention from the satirists.
When I did not feel disposed to read, and had none of my regular
visitors with me, I sometimes spent an hour or two in talking with
the old man-servant who attended me. Anton was decidedly an old
man, but what his age precisely was I never could discover; either
he did not know himself, or he did not wish to tell me. In
appearance he seemed about sixty, but from certain remarks which he
made I concluded that he must be nearer seventy, though he had
scarcely a grey hair on his head. As to who his father was he
seemed, like the famous Topsy, to have no very clear ideas, but he
had an advantage over Topsy with regard to his maternal ancestry.
His mother had been a serf who had fulfilled for some time the
functions of a lady's maid, and after the death of her mistress had
been promoted to a not very clearly defined position of
responsibility in the household. Anton, too, had been promoted in
his time. His first function in the household had been that of
assistant-keeper of the tobacco-pipes, from which humble office he
had gradually risen to a position which may be roughly designated
as that of butler. All this time he had been, of course, a serf,
as his mother had been before him; but being naturally a man of
sluggish intellect, he had never thoroughly realised the fact, and
had certainly never conceived the possibility of being anything
different from what he was. His master was master, and he himself
was Anton, obliged to obey his master, or at least conceal
disobedience--these were long the main facts in his conception of
the universe, and, as philosophers generally do with regard to
fundamental facts or axioms, he had accepted them without
examination. By means of these simple postulates he had led a
tranquil life, untroubled by doubts, until the year 1861, when the
so-called freedom was brought to Ivanofka. He himself had not gone
to the church to hear Batushka read the Tsar's manifesto, but his
master, on returning from the ceremony, had called him and said,
"Anton, you are free now, but the Tsar says you are to serve as you
have done for two years longer."
To this startling announcement Anton had replied coolly,
"Slushayus," or, as we would say, "Yes, sir," and without further
comment had gone to fetch his master's breakfast; but what he saw
and heard during the next few weeks greatly troubled his old
conceptions of human society and the fitness of things. From that
time must be dated, I suppose, the expression of mental confusion
which his face habitually wore.
The first thing that roused his indignation was the conduct of his
fellow-servants. Nearly all the unmarried ones seemed to be
suddenly attacked by a peculiar matrimonial mania. The reason of
this was that the new law expressly gave permission to the
emancipated serfs to marry as they chose without the consent of
their masters, and nearly all the unmarried adults hastened to take
advantage of their newly-acquired privilege, though many of them
had great difficulty in raising the capital necessary to pay the
priest's fees. Then came disorders among the peasantry, the death
of the old master, and the removal of the family first to St.
Petersburg, and afterwards to Germany. Anton's mind had never been
of a very powerful order, and these great events had exercised a
deleterious influence upon it. When Karl Karl'itch, at the expiry
of the two years, informed him that he might now go where he chose,
he replied, with a look of blank, unfeigned astonishment, "Where
can I go to?" He had never conceived the possibility of being
forced to earn his bread in some new way, and begged Karl Karl'itch
to let him remain where he was. This request was readily granted,
for Anton was an honest, faithful servant, and sincerely attached
to the family, and it was accordingly arranged that he should
receive a small monthly salary, and occupy an intermediate position
between those of major-domo and head watch-dog.
Had Anton been transformed into a real watch-dog he could scarcely
have slept more than he did. His power of sleeping, and his
somnolence when he imagined he was awake, were his two most
prominent characteristics. Out of consideration for his years and
his love of repose, I troubled him as little as possible; but even
the small amount of service which I demanded he contrived to
curtail in an ingenious way. The time and exertion required for
traversing the intervening space between his own room and mine
might, he thought, be more profitably employed; and accordingly he
extemporised a bed in a small ante-chamber, close to my door, and
took up there his permanent abode. If sonorous snoring be
sufficient proof that the performer is asleep, then I must conclude
that Anton devoted about three-fourths of his time to sleeping and
a large part of the remaining fourth to yawning and elongated
guttural ejaculations. At first this little arrangement
considerably annoyed me, but I bore it patiently, and afterwards
received my reward, for during my illness I found it very
convenient to have an attendant within call. And I must do Anton
the justice to say that he served me well in his own somnolent
fashion. He seemed to have the faculty of hearing when asleep, and
generally appeared in my room before he had succeeded in getting
his eyes completely open.
Anton had never found time, during his long life, to form many
opinions, but he had somehow imbibed or inhaled a few convictions,
all of a decidedly conservative kind, and one of these was that
feldshers were useless and dangerous members of society. Again and
again he had advised me to have nothing to do with the one who
visited me, and more than once he recommended to me an old woman of
the name of Masha, who lived in a village a few miles off. Masha
was what is known in Russia as a znakharka--that is to say, a woman
who is half witch, half medical practitioner--the whole permeated
with a strong leaven of knavery. According to Anton, she could
effect by means of herbs and charms every possible cure short of
raising from the dead, and even with regard to this last operation
he cautiously refrained from expressing an opinion.
The idea of being subjected to a course of herbs and charms by an
old woman who probably knew very little about the hidden properties
of either, did not seem to me inviting, and more than once I flatly
refused to have recourse to such unhallowed means. On due
consideration, however, I thought that a professional interview
with the old witch would be rather amusing, and then a brilliant
idea occurred to me! I would bring together the feldsher and the
znakharka, who no doubt hated each other with a Kilkenny-cat
hatred, and let them fight out their differences before me for the
benefit of science and my own delectation.
The more I thought of my project, the more I congratulated myself
on having conceived such a scheme; but, alas! in this very
imperfectly organised world of ours brilliant ideas are seldom
realised, and in this case I was destined to be disappointed. Did
the old woman's black art warn her of approaching danger, or was
she simply actuated by a feeling of professional jealousy and
considerations of professional etiquette? To this question I can
give no positive answer, but certain it is that she could not be
induced to pay me a visit, and I was thus balked of my expected
amusement. I succeeded, however, in learning indirectly something
about the old witch. She enjoyed among her neighbours that solid,
durable kind of respect which is founded on vague, undefinable
fear, and was believed to have effected many remarkable cures. In
the treatment of syphilitic diseases, which are fearfully common
among the Russian peasantry, she was supposed to be specially
successful, and I have no doubt, from the vague descriptions which
I received, that the charm which she employed in these cases was of
a mercurial kind. Some time afterward I saw one of her victims.
Whether she had succeeded in destroying the poison I know not, but
she had at least succeeded in destroying most completely the
patient's teeth. How women of this kind obtain mercury, and how
they have discovered its medicinal properties, I cannot explain.
Neither can I explain how they have come to know the peculiar
properties of ergot of rye, which they frequently employ for
illicit purposes familiar to all students of medical jurisprudence.
The znakharka and the feldsher represent two very different periods
in the history of medical science--the magical and the scientific.
The Russian peasantry have still many conceptions which belong to
the former. The great majority of them are already quite willing,
under ordinary circumstances, to use the scientific means of
healing; but as soon as a violent epidemic breaks out, and the
scientific means prove unequal to the occasion, the old faith
revives, and recourse is had to magical rites and incantations. Of
these rites many are very curious. Here, for instance, is one
which had been performed in a village near which I afterwards lived
for some time. Cholera had been raging in the district for several
weeks. In the village in question no case had yet occurred, but
the inhabitants feared that the dreaded visitor would soon arrive,
and the following ingenious contrivance was adopted for warding off
the danger. At midnight, when the male population was supposed to
be asleep, all the maidens met in nocturnal costume, according to a
preconcerted plan, and formed a procession. In front marched a
girl, holding an Icon. Behind her came her companions, dragging a
sokha--the primitive plough commonly used by the peasantry--by
means of a long rope. In this order the procession made the
circuit of the entire village, and it was confidently believed that
the cholera would not be able to overstep the magical circle thus
described. Many of the males probably knew, or at least suspected,
what was going on; but they prudently remained within doors,
knowing well that if they should be caught peeping indiscreetly at
the mystic ceremony, they would be unmercifully beaten by those who
were taking part in it.
This custom is doubtless a survival of old pagan superstitions.
The introduction of the Icon is a modern innovation, which
illustrates that curious blending of paganism and Christianity
which is often to be met with in Russia, and of which I shall have
more to say in another chapter.
Sometimes, when an epidemic breaks out, the panic produced takes a
more dangerous form. The people suspect that it is the work of the
doctors, or that some ill-disposed persons have poisoned the wells,
and no amount of reasoning will convince them that their own
habitual disregard of the most simple sanitary precautions has
something to do with the phenomenon. I know of one case where an
itinerant photographer was severely maltreated in consequence of
such suspicions; and once, in St. Petersburg, during the reign of
Nicholas I., a serious riot took place. The excited populace had
already thrown several doctors out of the windows of the hospital,
when the Emperor arrived, unattended, in an open carriage, and
quelled the disturbance by his simple presence, aided by his
stentorian voice.
Of the ignorant credulity of the Russian peasantry I might relate
many curious illustrations. The most absurd rumours sometimes
awaken consternation throughout a whole district. One of the most
common reports of this kind is that a female conscription is about
to take place. About the time of the Duke of Edinburgh's marriage
with the daughter of Alexander II. this report was specially
frequent. A large number of young girls were to be kidnapped and
sent to England in a red ship. Why the ship was to be red I can
easily explain, because in the peasants' language the conceptions
of red and beautiful are expressed by the same word (krasny), and
in the popular legends the epithet is indiscriminately applied to
everything connected with princes and great personages; but what
was to be done with the kidnapped maidens when they arrived at
their destination, I never succeeded in discovering.
The most amusing instance of credulity which I can recall was the
following, related to me by a peasant woman who came from the
village where the incident had occurred. One day in winter, about
the time of sunset, a peasant family was startled by the entrance
of a strange visitor, a female figure, dressed as St. Barbara is
commonly represented in the religious pictures. All present were
very much astonished by this apparition; but the figure told them,
in a low, soft voice, to be of good cheer, for she was St. Barbara,
and had come to honour the family with a visit as a reward for
their piety. The peasant thus favoured was not remarkable for his
piety, but he did not consider it necessary to correct the mistake
of his saintly visitor, and requested her to be seated. With
perfect readiness she accepted the invitation, and began at once to
discourse in an edifying way.
Meanwhile the news of this wonderful apparition spread like
wildfire, and all the inhabitants of the village, as well as those
of a neighbouring village about a mile distant, collected in and
around the house. Whether the priest was among those who came my
informant did not know. Many of those who had come could not get
within hearing, but those at the outskirts of the crowd hoped that
the saint might come out before disappearing. Their hopes were
gratified. About midnight the mysterious visitor announced that
she would go and bring St. Nicholas, the miracle-worker, and
requested all to remain perfectly still during her absence. The
crowd respectfully made way for her, and she passed out into the
darkness. With breathless expectation all awaited the arrival of
St. Nicholas, who is the favourite saint of the Russian peasantry;
but hours passed, and he did not appear. At last, toward sunrise,
some of the less zealous spectators began to return home, and those
of them who had come from the neighbouring village discovered to
their horror that during their absence their horses had been
stolen! At once they raised the hue-and-cry; and the peasants
scoured the country in all directions in search of the soi-disant
St. Barbara and her accomplices, but they never recovered the
stolen property. "And serve them right, the blockheads!" added my
informant, who had herself escaped falling into the trap by being
absent from the village at the time.
It is but fair to add that the ordinary Russian peasant, though in
some respects extremely credulous, and, like all other people,
subject to occasional panics, is by no means easily frightened by
real dangers. Those who have seen them under fire will readily
credit this statement. For my own part, I have had opportunities
of observing them merely in dangers of a non-military kind, and
have often admired the perfect coolness displayed. Even an
epidemic alarms them only when it attains a certain degree of
intensity. Once I had a good opportunity of observing this on
board a large steamer on the Volga. It was a very hot day in the
early autumn. As it was well known that there was a great deal of
Asiatic cholera all over the country, prudent people refrained from
eating much raw fruit; but Russian peasants are not generally
prudent men, and I noticed that those on board were consuming
enormous quantities of raw cucumbers and water-melons. This
imprudence was soon followed by its natural punishment. I refrain
from describing the scene that ensued, but I may say that those who
were attacked received from the others every possible assistance.
Had no unforeseen accident happened, we should have arrived at
Kazan on the following morning, and been able to send the patients
to the hospital of that town; but as there was little water in the
river, we had to cast anchor for the night, and next morning we ran
aground and stuck fast. Here we had to remain patiently till a
smaller steamer hove in sight. All this time there was not the
slightest symptom of panic, and when the small steamer came
alongside there was no frantic rush to get away from the infected
vessel, though it was quite evident that only a few of the
passengers could be taken off. Those who were nearest the gangway
went quietly on board the small steamer, and those who were less
fortunate remained patiently till another steamer happened to pass.
The old conceptions of disease, as something that may be most
successfully cured by charms and similar means, are rapidly
disappearing. The Zemstvo--that is to say, the new local self-
government--has done much towards this end by enabling the people
to procure better medical attendance. In the towns there are
public hospitals, which generally are--or at least seem to an
unprofessional eye--in a very satisfactory condition. The resident
doctors are daily besieged by a crowd of peasants, who come from
far and near to ask advice and receive medicines. Besides this, in
some provinces feldshers are placed in the principal villages, and
the doctor makes frequent tours of inspection. The doctors are
generally well-educated men, and do a large amount of work for a
very small remuneration.
Of the lunatic asylums, which are generally attached to the larger
hospitals, I cannot speak very favourably. Some of the great
central ones are all that could be desired, but others are badly
constructed and fearfully overcrowded. One or two of those I
visited appeared to me to be conducted on very patriarchal
principles, as the following incident may illustrate.
I had been visiting a large hospital, and had remained there so
long that it was already dark before I reached the adjacent lunatic
asylum. Seeing no lights in the windows, I proposed to my
companion, who was one of the inspectors, that we should delay our
visit till the following morning, but he assured me that by the
regulations the lights ought not to be extinguished till
considerably later, and consequently there was no objection to our
going in at once. If there was no legal objection, there was at
least a physical obstruction in the form of a large wooden door,
and all our efforts to attract the attention of the porter or some
other inmate were unavailing. At last, after much ringing,
knocking, and shouting, a voice from within asked us who we were
and what we wanted. A brief reply from my companion, not couched
in the most polite or amiable terms, made the bolts rattle and the
door open with surprising rapidity, and we saw before us an old man
with long dishevelled hair, who, as far as appearance went, might
have been one of the lunatics, bowing obsequiously and muttering
apologies.
After groping our way along a dark corridor we entered a still
darker room, and the door was closed and locked behind us. As the
key turned in the rusty lock a wild scream rang through the
darkness! Then came a yell, then a howl, and then various sounds
which the poverty of the English language prevents me from
designating--the whole blending into a hideous discord that would
have been at home in some of the worst regions of Dante's Inferno.
As to the cause of it I could not even form a conjecture.
Gradually my eyes became accustomed to the darkness, and I could
dimly perceive white figures flitting about the room. At the same
time I felt something standing near me, and close to my shoulder I
saw a pair of eyes and long streaming hair. On my other side,
equally close, was something very like a woman's night-cap. Though
by no means of a nervous temperament, I felt uncomfortable. To be
shut up in a dark room with an indefinite number of excited maniacs
is not a comfortable position. How long the imprisonment lasted I
know not--probably not more than two or three minutes, but it
seemed a long time. At last a light was procured, and the whole
affair was explained. The guardians, not expecting the visit of an
inspector at so late an hour, had retired for the night much
earlier than usual, and the old porter had put us into the nearest
ward until he could fetch a light--locking the door behind us lest
any of the lunatics should escape. The noise had awakened one of
the unfortunate inmates of the ward, and her hysterical scream had
terrified the others.
By the influence of asylums, hospitals, and similar institutions,
the old conceptions of disease, as I have said, are gradually dying
out, but the znakharka still finds practice. The fact that the
znakharka is to be found side by side not only with the feldsher,
but also with the highly trained bacteriologist, is very
characteristic of Russian civilisation, which is a strange
conglomeration of products belonging to very different periods.
The enquirer who undertakes the study of it will sometimes be
scarcely less surprised than would be the naturalist who should
unexpectedly stumble upon antediluvian megatheria grazing
tranquilly in the same field with prize Southdowns. He will
discover the most primitive institutions side by side with the
latest products of French doctrinairism, and the most childish
superstitions in close proximity with the most advanced free-
thinking.
CHAPTER VI
A PEASANT FAMILY OF THE OLD TYPE
Ivan Petroff--His Past Life--Co-operative Associations--
Constitution of a Peasant's Household--Predominance of Economic
Conceptions over those of Blood-relationship--Peasant Marriages--
Advantages of Living in Large Families--Its Defects--Family
Disruptions and their Consequences.
My illness had at least one good result. It brought me into
contact with the feldsher, and through him, after my recovery, I
made the acquaintance of several peasants living in the village.
Of these by far the most interesting was an old man called Ivan
Petroff.
Ivan must have been about sixty years of age, but was still robust
and strong, and had the reputation of being able to mow more hay in
a given time than any other peasant in the village. His head would
have made a line study for a portrait-painter. Like Russian
peasants in genera], he wore his hair parted in the middle--a
custom which perhaps owes its origin to the religious pictures.
The reverend appearance given to his face by his long fair beard,
slightly tinged with grey, was in part counteracted by his eyes,
which had a strange twinkle in them--whether of humour or of
roguery, it was difficult to say. Under all circumstances--whether
in his light, nondescript summer costume, or in his warm sheep-
skin, or in the long, glossy, dark-blue, double-breasted coat which
he put on occasionally on Sundays and holidays--he always looked a
well-fed, respectable, prosperous member of society; whilst his
imperturbable composure, and the entire absence of obsequiousness
or truculence in his manner, indicated plainly that he possessed no
small amount of calm, deep-rooted self-respect. A stranger, on
seeing him, might readily have leaped to the conclusion that he
must be the Village Elder, but in reality he was a simple member of
the Commune, like his neighbour, poor Zakhar Leshkof, who never let
slip an opportunity of getting drunk, was always in debt, and, on
the whole, possessed a more than dubious reputation.
Ivan had, it is true, been Village Elder some years before. When
elected by the Village Assembly, against his own wishes, he had
said quietly, "Very well, children; I will serve my three years";
and at the end of that period, when the Assembly wished to re-elect
him, he had answered firmly, "No, children; I have served my term.
It is now the turn of some one who is younger, and has more time.
There's Peter Alekseyef, a good fellow, and an honest; you may
choose him." And the Assembly chose the peasant indicated; for
Ivan, though a simple member of the Commune, had more influence in
Communal affairs than any other half-dozen members put together.
No grave matter was decided without his being consulted, and there
was at least one instance on record of the Village Assembly
postponing deliberations for a week because he happened to be
absent in St. Petersburg.
No stranger casually meeting Ivan would ever for a moment have
suspected that that big man, of calm, commanding aspect, had been
during a great part of his life a serf. And yet a serf he had been
from his birth till he was about thirty years of age--not merely a
serf of the State, but the serf of a proprietor who had lived
habitually on his property. For thirty years of his life he had
been dependent on the arbitrary will of a master who had the legal
power to flog him as often and as severely as he considered
desirable. In reality he had never been subjected to corporal
punishment, for the proprietor to whom he had belonged had been,
though in some respects severe, a just and intelligent master.
Ivan's bright, sympathetic face had early attracted the master's
attention, and it was decided that he should learn a trade. For
this purpose he was sent to Moscow, and apprenticed there to a
carpenter. After four years of apprenticeship he was able not only
to earn his own bread, but to help the household in the payment of
their taxes, and to pay annually to his master a fixed yearly sum--
first ten, then twenty, then thirty, and ultimately, for some years
immediately before the Emancipation, seventy roubles. In return
for this annual sum he was free to work and wander about as he
pleased, and for some years he had made ample use of his
conditional liberty. I never succeeded in extracting from him a
chronological account of his travels, but I could gather from his
occasional remarks that he had wandered over a great part of
European Russia. Evidently he had been in his youth what is
colloquially termed "a roving blade," and had by no means confined
himself to the trade which he had learned during his four years of
apprenticeship. Once he had helped to navigate a raft from Vetluga
to Astrakhan, a distance of about two thousand miles. At another
time he had been at Archangel and Onega, on the shores of the White
Sea. St. Petersburg and Moscow were both well known to him, and he
had visited Odessa.
The precise nature of Ivan's occupations during these wanderings I
could not ascertain; for, with all his openness of manner, he was
extremely reticent regarding his commercial affairs. To all my
inquiries on this topic he was wont to reply vaguely, "Lesnoe
dyelo"--that is to say, "Timber business"; and from this I
concluded that his chief occupation had been that of a timber
merchant. Indeed, when I knew him, though he was no longer a
regular trader, he was always ready to buy any bit of forest that
could be bought in the vicinity for a reasonable price.
During all this nomadic period of his life Ivan had never entirely
severed his connection with his native village or with agricultural
life. When about the age of twenty he had spent several months at
home, taking part in the field labour, and had married a wife--a
strong, healthy young woman, who had been selected for him by his
mother, and strongly recommended to him on account of her good
character and her physical strength. In the opinion of Ivan's
mother, beauty was a kind of luxury which only nobles and rich
merchants could afford, and ordinary comeliness was a very
secondary consideration--so secondary as to be left almost entirely
out of sight. This was likewise the opinion of Ivan's wife. She
had never been comely herself, she used to say, but she had been a
good wife to her husband. He had never complained about her want
of good looks, and had never gone after those who were considered
good-looking. In expressing this opinion she always first bent
forward, then drew herself up to her full length, and finally gave
a little jerky nod sideways, so as to clench the statement. Then
Ivan's bright eye would twinkle more brightly than usual, and he
would ask her how she knew that--reminding her that he was not
always at home. This was Ivan's stereotyped mode of teasing his
wife, and every time he employed it he was called an "old
scarecrow," or something of the kind.
Perhaps, however, Ivan's jocular remark had more significance in it
than his wife cared to admit, for during the first years of their
married life they had seen very little of each other. A few days
after the marriage, when according to our notions the honeymoon
should be at its height, Ivan had gone to Moscow for several
months, leaving his young bride to the care of his father and
mother. The young bride did not consider this an extraordinary
hardship, for many of her companions had been treated in the same
way, and according to public opinion in that part of the country
there was nothing abnormal in the proceeding. Indeed, it may be
said in general that there is very little romance or sentimentality
about Russian peasant marriages. In this as in other respects the
Russian peasantry are, as a class, extremely practical and matter-
of-fact in their conceptions and habits, and are not at all prone
to indulge in sublime, ethereal sentiments of any kind. They have
little or nothing of what may be termed the Hermann and Dorothea
element in their composition, and consequently know very little
about those sentimental, romantic ideas which we habitually
associate with the preliminary steps to matrimony. Even those
authors who endeavour to idealise peasant life have rarely ventured
to make their story turn on a sentimental love affair. Certainly
in real life the wife is taken as a helpmate, or in plain language
a worker, rather than as a companion, and the mother-in-law leaves
her very little time to indulge in fruitless dreaming.
As time wore on, and his father became older and frailer, Ivan's
visits to his native place became longer and more frequent, and
when the old man was at last incapable of work, Ivan settled down
permanently and undertook the direction of the household. In the
meantime his own children had been growing up. When I knew the
family it comprised--besides two daughters who had married early
and gone to live with their parents-in-law--Ivan and his wife, two
sons, three daughters-in-law, and an indefinite and frequently
varying number of grandchildren. The fact that there were three
daughters-in-law and only two sons was the result of the
Conscription, which had taken away the youngest son shortly after
his marriage. The two who remained spent only a small part of the
year at home. The one was a carpenter and the other a bricklayer,
and both wandered about the country in search of employment, as
their father had done in his younger days. There was, however, one
difference. The father had always shown a leaning towards
commercial transactions, rather than the simple practice of his
handicraft, and consequently he had usually lived and travelled
alone. The sons, on the contrary, confined themselves to their
handicrafts, and were always during the working season members of
an artel.
The artel in its various forms is a curious institution. Those to
which Ivan's sons belonged were simply temporary, itinerant
associations of workmen, who during the summer lived together, fed
together, worked together, and periodically divided amongst
themselves the profits. This is the primitive form of the
institution, and is now not very often met with. Here, as
elsewhere, capital has made itself felt, and destroyed that
equality which exists among the members of an artel in the above
sense of the word. Instead of forming themselves into a temporary
association, the workmen now generally make an engagement with a
contractor who has a little capital, and receive from him fixed
monthly wages. The only association which exists in this case is
for the purchase and preparation of provisions, and even these
duties are very often left to the contractor.
In some of the larger towns there are artels of a much more complex
kind--permanent associations, possessing a large capital, and
pecuniarily responsible for the acts of the individual members. Of
these, by far the most celebrated is that of the Bank Porters.
These men have unlimited opportunities of stealing, and are often
entrusted with the guarding or transporting of enormous sums; but
the banker has no cause for anxiety, because he knows that if any
defalcations occur they will be made good to him by the artel.
Such accidents very rarely happen, and the fact is by no means so
extraordinary as many people suppose. The artel, being responsible
for the individuals of which it is composed, is very careful in
admitting new members, and a man when admitted is closely watched,
not only by the regularly constituted office-bearers, but also by
all his fellow-members who have an opportunity of observing him.
If he begins to spend money too freely or to neglect his duties,
though his employer may know nothing of the fact, suspicions are at
once aroused among his fellow-members, and an investigation ensues--
ending in summary expulsion if the suspicions prove to have been
well founded. Mutual responsibility, in short, creates a very
effective system of mutual supervision.
Of Ivan's sons, the one who was a carpenter visited his family only
occasionally, and at irregular intervals; the bricklayer, on the
contrary, as building is impossible in Russia during the cold
weather, spent the greater part of the winter at home. Both of
them paid a large part of their earnings into the family treasury,
over which their father exercised uncontrolled authority. If he
wished to make any considerable outlay, he consulted his sons on
the subject; but as he was a prudent, intelligent man, and enjoyed
the respect and confidence of the family, he never met with any
strong opposition. All the field work was performed by him with
the assistance of his daughters-in-law; only at harvest time he
hired one or two labourers to help him.
Ivan's household was a good specimen of the Russian peasant family
of the old type. Previous to the Emancipation in 1861 there were
many households of this kind, containing the representatives of
three generations. All the members, young and old, lived together
in patriarchal fashion under the direction and authority of the
Head of the House, called usually the Khozain--that is to say, the
Administrator; or, in some districts, the Bolshak, which means
literally "the Big One." Generally speaking, this important
position was occupied by the grandfather, or, if he was dead, by
the eldest brother, but the rule was not very strictly observed.
If, for instance, the grandfather became infirm, or if the eldest
brother was incapacitated by disorderly habits or other cause, the
place of authority was taken by some other member--it might be by a
woman--who was a good manager, and possessed the greatest moral
influence.
The relations between the Head of the Household and the other
members depended on custom and personal character, and they
consequently varied greatly in different families. If the Big One
was an intelligent man, of decided, energetic character, like my
friend Ivan, there was probably perfect discipline in the
household, except perhaps in the matter of female tongues, which do
not readily submit to the authority even of their owners; but very
often it happened that the Big One was not thoroughly well fitted
for his post, and in that case endless quarrels and bickerings
inevitably took place. Those quarrels were generally caused and
fomented by the female members of the family--a fact which will not
seem strange if we try to realise how difficult it must be for
several sisters-in-law to live together, with their children and a
mother-in-law, within the narrow limits of a peasant's household.
The complaints of the young bride, who finds that her mother-in-law
puts all the hard work on her shoulders, form a favourite motive in
the popular poetry.
The house, with its appurtenances, the cattle, the agricultural
implements, the grain and other products, the money gained from the
sale of these products--in a word, the house and nearly everything
it contained--were the joint property of the family. Hence nothing
was bought or sold by any member--not even by the Big One himself,
unless he possessed an unusual amount of authority--without the
express or tacit consent of the other grown-up males, and all the
money that was earned was put into the common purse. When one of
the sons left home to work elsewhere, he was expected to bring or
send home all his earnings, except what he required for food,
lodgings, and other necessary expenses; and if he understood the
word "necessary" in too lax a sense, he had to listen to very
plain-spoken reproaches when he returned. During his absence,
which might last for a whole year or several years, his wife and
children remained in the house as before, and the money which he
earned could be devoted to the payment of the family taxes.
The peasant household of the old type is thus a primitive labour
association, of which the members have all things in common, and it
is not a little remarkable that the peasant conceives it as such
rather than as a family. This is shown by the customary
terminology, for the Head of the Household is not called by any
word corresponding to Paterfamilias, but is termed, as I have said,
Khozain, or Administrator--a word that is applied equally to a
farmer, a shopkeeper or the head of an industrial undertaking, and
does not at all convey the idea of blood-relationship. It is
likewise shown by what takes place when a household is broken up.
On such occasions the degree of blood-relationship is not taken
into consideration in the distribution of the property. All the
adult male members share equally. Illegitimate and adopted sons,
if they have contributed their share of labour, have the same
rights as the sons born in lawful wedlock. The married daughter,
on the contrary--being regarded as belonging to her husband's
family--and the son who has previously separated himself from the
household, are excluded from the succession. Strictly speaking,
the succession or inheritance is confined to the wearing apparel
and any little personal effects of a deceased member. The house
and all that it contains belong to the little household community;
and, consequently, when it is broken up, by the death of the
Khozain or other cause, the members do not inherit, but merely
appropriate individually what they had hitherto possessed
collectively. Thus there is properly no inheritance or succession,
but simply liquidation and distribution of the property among the
members. The written law of inheritance founded on the conception
of personal property, is quite unknown to the peasantry, and quite
inapplicable to their mode of life. In this way a large and most
important section of the Code remains a dead letter for about four-
fifths of the population.
This predominance of practical economic considerations is
exemplified also by the way in which marriages are arranged in
these large families. In the primitive system of agriculture
usually practised in Russia, the natural labour-unit--if I may use
such a term--comprises a man, a woman, and a horse. As soon,
therefore, as a boy becomes an able-bodied labourer he ought to be
provided with the two accessories necessary for the completion of
the labour-unit. To procure a horse, either by purchase or by
rearing a foal, is the duty of the Head of the House; to procure a
wife for the youth is the duty of "the female Big One" (Bolshukha).
And the chief consideration in determining the choice is in both
cases the same. Prudent domestic administrators are not to be
tempted by showy horses or beautiful brides; what they seek is not
beauty, but physical strength and capacity for work. When the
youth reaches the age of eighteen he is informed that he ought to
marry at once, and as soon as he gives his consent negotiations are
opened with the parents of some eligible young person. In the
larger villages the negotiations are sometimes facilitated by
certain old women called svakhi, who occupy themselves specially
with this kind of mediation; but very often the affair is arranged
directly by, or through the agency of, some common friend of the
two houses.
Care must of course be taken that there is no legal obstacle, and
these obstacles are not always easily avoided in a small village,
the inhabitants of which have been long in the habit of
intermarrying. According to Russian ecclesiastical law, not only
is marriage between first-cousins illegal, but affinity is
considered as equivalent to consanguinity--that is to say a mother-
in-law and a sister-in-law are regarded as a mother and a sister--
and even the fictitious relationship created by standing together
at the baptismal font as godfather and godmother is legally
recognised, and may constitute a bar to matrimony. If all the
preliminary negotiations are successful, the marriage takes place,
and the bridegroom brings his bride home to the house of which he
is a member. She brings nothing with her as a dowry except her
trousseau, but she brings a pair of good strong arms, and thereby
enriches her adopted family. Of course it happens occasionally--
for human nature is everywhere essentially the same--that a young
peasant falls in love with one of his former playmates, and brings
his little romance to a happy conclusion at the altar; but such
cases are very rare, and as a rule it may be said that the
marriages of the Russian peasantry are arranged under the influence
of economic rather than sentimental considerations.
The custom of living in large families has many economic
advantages. We all know the edifying fable of the dying man who
showed to his sons by means of a piece of wicker-work the
advantages of living together and assisting each other. In
ordinary times the necessary expenses of a large household of ten
members are considerably less than the combined expenses of two
households comprising five members each, and when a "black day"
comes a large family can bear temporary adversity much more
successfully than a small one. These are principles of world-wide
application, but in the life of the Russian peasantry they have a
peculiar force. Each adult peasant possesses, as I shall hereafter
explain, a share of the Communal land, but this share is not
sufficient to occupy all his time and working power. One married
pair can easily cultivate two shares--at least in all provinces
where the peasant allotments are not very large. Now, if a family
is composed of two married couples, one of the men can go elsewhere
and earn money, whilst the other, with his wife and sister-in-law,
can cultivate the two combined shares of land. If, on the contrary
a family consists merely of one pair with their children, the man
must either remain at home--in which case he may have difficulty in
finding work for the whole of his time--or he must leave home, and
entrust the cultivation of his share of the land to his wife, whose
time must be in great part devoted to domestic affairs.
In the time of serfage the proprietors clearly perceived these and
similar advantages, and compelled their serfs to live together in
large families. No family could be broken up without the
proprietor's consent, and this consent was not easily obtained
unless the family had assumed quite abnormal proportions and was
permanently disturbed by domestic dissension. In the matrimonial
affairs of the serfs, too, the majority of the proprietors
systematically exercised a certain supervision, not necessarily
from any paltry meddling spirit, but because their own material
interests were thereby affected. A proprietor would not, for
instance, allow the daughter of one of his serfs to marry a serf
belonging to another proprietor--because he would thereby lose a
female labourer--unless some compensation were offered. The
compensation might be a sum of money, or the affair might be
arranged on the principle of reciprocity by the master of the
bridegroom allowing one of his female serfs to marry a serf
belonging to the master of the bride.
However advantageous the custom of living in large families may
appear when regarded from the economic point of view, it has very
serious defects, both theoretical and practical.
That families connected by the ties of blood-relationship and
marriage can easily live together in harmony is one of those social
axioms which are accepted universally and believed by nobody. We
all know by our own experience, or by that of others, that the
friendly relations of two such families are greatly endangered by
proximity of habitation. To live in the same street is not
advisable; to occupy adjoining houses is positively dangerous; and
to live under the same roof is certainly fatal to prolonged amity.
There may be the very best intentions on both sides, and the
arrangement may be inaugurated by the most gushing expressions of
undying affection and by the discovery of innumerable secret
affinities, but neither affinities, affection, nor good intentions
can withstand the constant friction and occasional jerks which
inevitably ensue.
Now the reader must endeavour to realise that Russian peasants,
even when clad in sheep-skins, are human beings like ourselves.
Though they are often represented as abstract entities--as figures
in a table of statistics or dots on a diagram--they have in reality
"organs, dimensions, senses, affections, passions." If not exactly
"fed with the same food," they are at least "hurt with the same
weapons, subject to the same diseases, healed by the same means,"
and liable to be irritated by the same annoyances as we are. And
those of them who live in large families are subjected to a kind of
probation that most of us have never dreamed of. The families
comprising a large household not only live together, but have
nearly all things in common. Each member works, not for himself,
but for the household, and all that he earns is expected to go into
the family treasury. The arrangement almost inevitably leads to
one of two results--either there are continual dissensions, or
order is preserved by a powerful domestic tyranny.
It is quite natural, therefore, that when the authority of the
landed proprietors was abolished in 1861, the large peasant
families almost all crumbled to pieces. The arbitrary rule of the
Khozain was based on, and maintained by, the arbitrary rule of the
proprietor, and both naturally fell together. Households like that
of our friend Ivan were preserved only in exceptional cases, where
the Head of the House happened to possess an unusual amount of
moral influence over the other members.
This change has unquestionably had a prejudicial influence on the
material welfare of the peasantry, but it must have added
considerably to their domestic comfort, and may perhaps produce
good moral results. For the present, however, the evil
consequences are by far the most prominent. Every married peasant
strives to have a house of his own, and many of them, in order to
defray the necessary expenses, have been obliged to contract debts.
This is a very serious matter. Even if the peasants could obtain
money at five or six per cent., the position of the debtors would
be bad enough, but it is in reality much worse, for the village
usurers consider twenty or twenty-five per cent. a by no means
exorbitant rate of interest. A laudable attempt has been made to
remedy this state of things by village banks, but these have proved
successful only in certain exceptional localities. As a rule the
peasant who contracts debts has a hard struggle to pay the interest
in ordinary times, and when some misfortune overtakes him--when,
for instance, the harvest is bad or his horse is stolen--he
probably falls hopelessly into pecuniary embarrassments. I have
seen peasants not specially addicted to drunkenness or other
ruinous habits sink to a helpless state of insolvency. Fortunately
for such insolvent debtors, they are treated by the law with
extreme leniency. Their house, their share of the common land,
their agricultural implements, their horse--in a word, all that is
necessary for their subsistence, is exempt from sequestration. The
Commune, however, may bring strong pressure to bear on those who do
not pay their taxes. When I lived among the peasantry in the
seventies, corporal punishment inflicted by order of the Commune
was among the means usually employed; and though the custom was
recently prohibited by an Imperial decree of Nicholas II, I am not
at all sure that it has entirely disappeared.
CHAPTER VII
THE PEASANTRY OF THE NORTH
Communal Land--System of Agriculture--Parish Fetes--Fasting--
Winter Occupations--Yearly Migrations--Domestic Industries--
Influence of Capital and Wholesale Enterprise--The State Peasants--
Serf-dues--Buckle's "History of Civilisation"--A precocious
Yamstchik--"People Who Play Pranks"--A Midnight Alarm--The Far
North.
Ivanofka may be taken as a fair specimen of the villages in the
northern half of the country, and a brief description of its
inhabitants will convey a tolerably correct notion of the northern
peasantry in general.
Nearly the whole of the female population, and about one-half of
the male inhabitants, are habitually engaged in cultivating the
Communal land, which comprises about two thousand acres of a light
sandy soil. The arable part of this land is divided into three
large fields, each of which is cut up into long narrow strips. The
first field is reserved for the winter grain--that is to say, rye,
which forms, in the shape of black bread, the principal food of the
rural population. In the second are raised oats for the horses,
and buckwheat, which is largely used for food. The third lies
fallow, and is used in the summer as pasturage for the cattle.
All the villagers in this part of the country divide the arable
land in this way, in order to suit the triennial rotation of crops.
This triennial system is extremely simple. The field which is used
this year for raising winter grain will be used next year for
raising summer grain, and in the following year will lie fallow.
Before being sown with winter grain it ought to receive a certain
amount of manure. Every family possesses in each of the two fields
under cultivation one or more of the long narrow strips or belts
into which they are divided.
The annual life of the peasantry is that of simple husbandman,
inhabiting a country where the winter is long and severe. The
agricultural year begins in April with the melting of the snow.
Nature has been lying dormant for some months. Awaking now from
her long sleep, and throwing off her white mantle, she strives to
make up for lost time. No sooner has the snow disappeared than the
fresh young grass begins to shoot up, and very soon afterwards the
shrubs and trees begin to bud. The rapidity of this transition
from winter to spring astonishes the inhabitants of more temperate
climes.
On St. George's Day (April 23rd*) the cattle are brought out for
the first time, and sprinkled with holy water by the priest. They
are never very fat, but at this period of the year their appearance
is truly lamentable. During the winter they have been cooped up in
small unventilated cow-houses, and fed almost exclusively on straw;
now, when they are released from their imprisonment, they look like
the ghosts of their former emaciated selves. All are lean and
weak, many are lame, and some cannot rise to their feet without
assistance.
* With regard to saints' days, I always give the date according to
the old style. To find the date according to our calendar,
thirteen days must be added.
Meanwhile the peasants are impatient to begin the field labour. An
old proverb which they all know says: "Sow in mud and you will be a
prince"; and they always act in accordance with this dictate of
traditional wisdom. As soon as it is possible to plough they begin
to prepare the land for the summer grain, and this labour occupies
them probably till the end of May. Then comes the work of carting
out manure and preparing the fallow field for the winter grain,
which will last probably till about St. Peter's Day (June 29th),
when the hay-making generally begins. After the hay-making comes
the harvest, by far the busiest time of the year. From the middle
of July--especially from St. Elijah's Day (July 20th), when the
saint is usually heard rumbling along the heavens in his chariot of
fire*--until the end of August, the peasant may work day and night,
and yet he will find that he has barely time to get all his work
done. In little more than a month he has to reap and stack his
grain--rye, oats, and whatever else he may have sown either in
spring or in the preceding autumn--and to sow the winter grain for
next year. To add to his troubles, it sometimes happens that the
rye and the oats ripen almost simultaneously, and his position is
then still more difficult.
* It is thus that the peasants explain the thunder, which is often
heard at that season.
Whether the seasons favour him or not, the peasant has at this time
a hard task, for he can rarely afford to hire the requisite number
of labourers, and has generally the assistance merely of his wife
and family; but he can at this season work for a short time at high
pressure, for he has the prospect of soon obtaining a good rest and
an abundance of food. About the end of September the field labour
is finished, and on the first day of October the harvest festival
begins--a joyous season, during which the parish fetes are commonly
celebrated.
To celebrate a parish fete in true orthodox fashion it is necessary
to prepare beforehand a large quantity of braga--a kind of home-
brewed small beer--and to bake a plentiful supply of piroghi or
meat pies. Oil, too, has to be procured, and vodka (rye spirit) in
goodly quantity. At the same time the big room of the izba, as the
peasant's house is called, has to be cleared, the floor washed, and
the table and benches scrubbed. The evening before the fete, while
the piroghi are being baked, a little lamp burns before the Icon in
the corner of the room, and perhaps one or two guests from a
distance arrive in order that they may have on the morrow a full
day's enjoyment.
On the morning of the fete the proceedings begin by a long service
in the church, at which all the inhabitants are present in their
best holiday costumes, except those matrons and young women who
remain at home to prepare the dinner. About mid-day dinner is
served in each izba for the family and their friends. In general
the Russian peasant's fare is of the simplest kind, and rarely
comprises animal food of any sort--not from any vegetarian
proclivities, but merely because beef, mutton, and pork are too
expensive; but on a holiday, such as a parish fete, there is always
on the dinner table a considerable variety of dishes. In the house
of a well-to-do family there will be not only greasy cabbage-soup
and kasha--a dish made from buckwheat--but also pork, mutton, and
perhaps even beef. Braga will be supplied in unlimited quantities,
and more than once vodka will be handed round. When the repast is
finished, all rise together, and, turning towards the Icon in the
corner, bow and cross themselves repeatedly. The guests then say
to their host, "Spasibo za khelb za sol"--that is to say, "Thanks
for your hospitality," or more literally, "Thanks for bread and
salt"; and the host replies, "Do not be displeased, sit down once
more for good luck"--or perhaps he puts the last part of his
request into the form of a rhyming couplet to the following effect:
"Sit down, that the hens may brood, and that the chickens and bees
may multiply!" All obey this request, and there is another round
of vodka.
After dinner some stroll about, chatting with their friends, or go
to sleep in some shady nook, whilst those who wish to make merry go
to the spot where the young people are singing, playing, and
amusing themselves in various ways. As the sun sinks towards the
horizon, the more grave, staid guests wend their way homewards, but
many remain for supper; and as evening advances the effects of the
vodka become more and more apparent. Sounds of revelry are heard
more frequently from the houses, and a large proportion of the
inhabitants and guests appear on the road in various degrees of
intoxication. Some of these vow eternal affection to their
friends, or with flaccid gestures and in incoherent tones harangue
invisible audiences; others stagger about aimlessly in besotted
self-contentment, till they drop down in a state of complete
unconsciousness. There they will lie tranquilly till they are
picked up by their less intoxicated friends, or more probably till
they awake of their own accord next morning.
As a whole, a village fete in Russia is a saddening spectacle. It
affords a new proof--where, alas! no new proof was required--that
we northern nations, who know so well how to work, have not yet
learned the art of amusing ourselves.
If the Russian peasant's food were always as good and plentiful as
at this season of the year, he would have little reason to
complain; but this is by no means the case. Gradually, as the
harvest-time recedes, it deteriorates in quality, and sometimes
diminishes in quantity. Besides this, during a great part of the
year the peasant is prevented, by the rules of the Church, from
using much that he possesses.
In southern climes, where these rules were elaborated and first
practised, the prescribed fasts are perhaps useful not only in a
religious, but also in a sanitary sense. Having abundance of fruit
and vegetables, the inhabitants do well to abstain occasionally
from animal food. But in countries like Northern and Central
Russia the influence of these rules is very different. The Russian
peasant cannot get as much animal food as he requires, whilst sour
cabbage and cucumbers are probably the only vegetables he can
procure, and fruit of any kind is for him an unattainable luxury.
Under these circumstances, abstinence from eggs and milk in all
their forms during several months of the year seems to the secular
mind a superfluous bit of asceticism. If the Church would direct
her maternal solicitude to the peasant's drinking, and leave him to
eat what he pleases, she might exercise a beneficial influence on
his material and moral welfare. Unfortunately she has a great deal
too much inherent immobility to attempt anything of the kind, so
the muzhik, while free to drink copiously whenever he gets the
chance, must fast during the seven weeks of Lent, during two or
three weeks in June, from the beginning of November till Christmas,
and on all Wednesdays and Fridays during the remainder of the year.
From the festival time till the following spring there is no
possibility of doing any agricultural work, for the ground is hard
as iron, and covered with a deep layer of snow. The male peasants,
therefore, who remain in the villages, have very little to do, and
may spend the greater part of their time in lying idly on the
stove, unless they happen to have learned some handicraft that can
be practised at home. Formerly, many of them were employed in
transporting the grain to the market town, which might be several
hundred miles distant; but now this species of occupation has been
greatly diminished by the extension of railways.
Another winter occupation which was formerly practised, and has now
almost fallen into disuse, was that of stealing wood in the forest.
This was, according to peasant morality, no sin, or at most a very
venial offence, for God plants and waters the trees, and therefore
forests belong properly to no one. So thought the peasantry, but
the landed proprietors and the Administration of the Domains held a
different theory of property, and consequently precautions had to
be taken to avoid detection. In order to ensure success it was
necessary to choose a night when there was a violent snowstorm,
which would immediately obliterate all traces of the expedition;
and when such a night was found, the operation was commonly
performed with success. During the hours of darkness a tree would
be felled, stripped of its branches, dragged into the village, and
cut up into firewood, and at sunrise the actors would be tranquilly
sleeping on the stove as if they had spent the night at home. In
recent years the judicial authorities have done much towards
putting down this practice and eradicating the loose conceptions of
property with which it was connected.
For the female part of the population the winter used to be a busy
time, for it was during these four or five months that the spinning
and weaving had to be done, but now the big factories, with their
cheap methods of production, are rapidly killing the home
industries, and the young girls are not learning to work at the
jenny and the loom as their mothers and grandmothers did.
In many of the northern villages, where ancient usages happen to be
preserved, the tedium of the long winter evenings is relieved by
so-called Besedy, a word which signifies literally conversazioni.
A Beseda, however, is not exactly a conversazione as we understand
the term, but resembles rather what is by some ladies called a
Dorcas meeting, with this essential difference, that those present
work for themselves and not for any benevolent purposes. In some
villages as many as three Besedy regularly assemble about sunset;
one for the children, the second for the young people, and the
third for the matrons. Each of the three has its peculiar
character. In the first, the children work and amuse themselves
under the superintendence of an old woman, who trims the torch* and
endeavours to keep order. The little girls spin flax in a
primitive way without the aid of a jenny, and the boys, who are, on
the whole, much less industrious, make simple bits of wicker-work.
Formerly--I mean within my own recollection--many of them used to
make rude shoes of plaited bark, called lapty, but these are being
rapidly supplanted by leather boots. These occupations do not
prevent an almost incessant hum of talk, frequent discordant
attempts to sing in chorus, and occasional quarrels requiring the
energetic interference of the old woman who controls the
proceedings. To amuse her noisy flock she sometimes relates to
them, for the hundredth time, one of those wonderful old stories
that lose nothing by repetition, and all listen to her attentively,
as if they had never heard the story before.
* The torch (lutchina) has now almost entirely disappeared and been
replaced by the petroleum lamp.
The second Beseda is held in another house by the young people of a
riper age. Here the workers are naturally more staid, less given
to quarrelling, sing more in harmony, and require no one to look
after them. Some people, however, might think that a chaperon or
inspector of some kind would be by no means out of place, for a
good deal of flirtation goes on, and if village scandal is to be
trusted, strict propriety in thought, word, and deed is not always
observed. How far these reports are true I cannot pretend to say,
for the presence of a stranger always acts on the company like the
presence of a severe inspector. In the third Beseda there is
always at least strict decorum. Here the married women work
together and talk about their domestic concerns, enlivening the
conversation occasionally by the introduction of little bits of
village scandal.
Such is the ordinary life of the peasants who live by agriculture;
but many of the villagers live occasionally or permanently in the
towns. Probably the majority of the peasants in this region have
at some period of their lives gained a living elsewhere. Many of
the absentees spend yearly a few months at home, whilst others
visit their families only occasionally, and, it may be, at long
intervals. In no case, however, do they sever their connection
with their native village. Even the peasant who becomes a rich
merchant and settles permanently with his family in Moscow or St.
Petersburg remains probably a member of the Village Commune, and
pays his share of the taxes, though he does not enjoy any of the
corresponding privileges. Once I remember asking a rich man of
this kind, the proprietor of several large houses in St.
Petersburg, why he did not free himself from all connection with
his native Commune, with which he had no longer any interests in
common. His answer was, "It is all very well to be free, and I
don't want anything from the Commune now; but my old father lives
there, my mother is buried there, and I like to go back to the old
place sometimes. Besides, I have children, and our affairs are
commercial (nashe dyelo torgovoe). Who knows but my children may
he very glad some day to have a share of the Commune land?"
In respect to these non-agricultural occupations, each district has
its specialty. The province of Yaroslavl, for instance, supplies
the large towns with waiters for the traktirs, or lower class of
restaurants, whilst the best hotels in Petersburg are supplied by
the Tartars of Kasimof, celebrated for their sobriety and honesty.
One part of the province of Kostroma has a special reputation for
producing carpenters and stove-builders, whilst another part, as I
once discovered to my surprise, sends yearly to Siberia--not as
convicts, but as free laborours--a large contingent of tailors and
workers in felt! On questioning some youngsters who were
accompanying as apprentices one of these bands, I was informed by a
bright-eyed youth of about sixteen that he had already made the
journey twice, and intended to go every winter. "And you always
bring home a big pile of money with you?" I inquired. "Nitchevo!"
replied the little fellow, gaily, with an air of pride and self-
confidence; "last year I brought home three roubles!" This answer
was, at the moment, not altogether welcome, for I had just been
discussing with a Russian fellow-traveller as to whether the
peasantry can fairly be called industrious, and the boy's reply
enabled my antagonist to score a point against me. "You hear
that!" he said, triumphantly. "A Russian peasant goes all the way
to Siberia and back for three roubles! Could you get an Englishman
to work at that rate?" "Perhaps not," I replied, evasively,
thinking at the same time that if a youth were sent several times
from Land's End to John o' Groat's House, and obliged to make the
greater part of the journey in carts or on foot, he would probably
expect, by way of remuneration for the time and labour expended,
rather more than seven and sixpence!
Very often the peasants find industrial occupations without leaving
home, for various industries which do not require complicated
machinery are practised in the villages by the peasants and their
families. Wooden vessels, wrought iron, pottery, leather, rush-
matting, and numerous other articles are thus produced in enormous
quantities. Occasionally we find not only a whole village, but
even a whole district occupied almost exclusively with some one
kind of manual industry. In the province of Vladimir, for example,
a large group of villages live by Icon-painting; in one locality
near Nizhni-Novgorod nineteen villages are occupied with the
manufacture of axes; round about Pavlovo, in the same province,
eighty villages produce almost nothing but cutlery; and in a
locality called Ouloma, on the borders of Novgorod and Tver, no
less than two hundred villages live by nail-making.
These domestic industries have long existed, and were formerly an
abundant source of revenue--providing a certain compensation for
the poverty of the soil. But at present they are in a very
critical position. They belong to the primitive period of economic
development, and that period in Russia, as I shall explain in a
future chapter, is now rapidly drawing to a close. Formerly the
Head of a Household bought the raw material, had it worked up at
home, and sold with a reasonable profit the manufactured articles
at the bazaars, as the local fairs are called, or perhaps at the
great annual yarmarkt* of Nizhni-Novgorod. This primitive system
is now rapidly becoming obsolete. Capital and wholesale enterprise
have come into the field and are revolutionising the old methods of
production and trade. Already whole groups of industrial villages
have fallen under the power of middle-men, who advance money to the
working households and fix the price of the products. Attempts are
frequently made to break their power by voluntary co-operative
associations, organised by the local authorities or benevolent
landed proprietors of the neighbourhood--like the benevolent people
in England who try to preserve the traditional cottage industries--
and some of the associations work very well; but the ultimate
success of such "efforts to stem the current of capitalism" is
extremely doubtful. At the same time, the periodical bazaars and
yarmarki, at which producers and consumers transacted their affairs
without mediation, are being replaced by permanent stores and by
various classes of tradesmen--wholesale and retail.
* This term is a corruption of the German word Jahrmarkt.
To the political economist of the rigidly orthodox school this
important change may afford great satisfaction. According to his
theories it is a gigantic step in the right direction, and must
necessarily redound to the advantage of all parties concerned. The
producer now receives a regular supply of raw material, and
regularly disposes of the articles manufactured; and the time and
trouble which he formerly devoted to wandering about in search of
customers he can now employ more profitably in productive work.
The creation of a class between the producers and the consumers is
an important step towards that division and specialisation of
labour which is a necessary condition of industrial and commercial
prosperity. The consumer no longer requires to go on a fixed day
to some distant point, on the chance of finding there what he
requires, but can always buy what he pleases in the permanent
stores. Above all, the production is greatly increased in amount,
and the price of manufactured goods is proportionally lessened.
All this seems clear enough in theory, and any one who values
intellectual tranquillity will feel disposed to accept this view of
the case without questioning its accuracy; but the unfortunate
traveller who is obliged to use his eyes as well as his logical
faculties may find some little difficulty in making the facts fit
into the a priori formula. Far be it from me to question the
wisdom of political economists, but I cannot refrain from remarking
that of the three classes concerned--small producers, middle-men,
and consumers--two fail to perceive and appreciate the benefits
which have been conferred upon them. The small producers complain
that on the new system they work more and gain less; and the
consumers complain that the manufactured articles, if cheaper and
more showy in appearance, are far inferior in quality. The
middlemen, who are accused, rightly or wrongly, of taking for
themselves the lion's share of the profits, alone seem satisfied
with the new arrangement.
Interesting as this question undoubtedly is, it is not of permanent
importance, because the present state of things is merely
transitory. Though the peasants may continue for a time to work at
home for the wholesale dealers, they cannot in the long run compete
with the big factories and workshops, organised on the European
model with steam-power and complicated machinery, which already
exist in many provinces. Once a country has begun to move forward
on the great highway of economic progress, there is no possibility
of stopping halfway.
Here again the orthodox economists find reason for congratulation,
because big factories and workshops are the cheapest and most
productive form of manufacturing industry; and again, the observant
traveller cannot shut his eyes to ugly facts which force themselves
on his attention. He notices that this cheapest and most
productive form of manufacturing industry does not seem to advance
the material and moral welfare of the population. Nowhere is there
more disease, drunkenness, demoralisation and misery than in the
manufacturing districts.
The reader must not imagine that in making these statements I wish
to calumniate the spirit of modern enterprise, or to advocate a
return to primitive barbarism. All great changes produce a mixture
of good and evil, and at first the evil is pretty sure to come
prominently forward. Russia is at this moment in a state of
transition, and the new condition of things is not yet properly
organised. With improved organisation many of the existing evils
will disappear. Already in recent years I have noticed sporadic
signs of improvement. When factories were first established no
proper arrangements were made for housing and feeding the workmen,
and the consequent hardships were specially felt when the factories
were founded, as is often the case, in rural districts. Now, the
richer and more enterprising manufacturers build large barracks for
the workmen and their families, and provide them with common
kitchens, wash-houses, steam-baths, schools, and similar requisites
of civilised life. At the same time the Government appoints
inspectors to superintend the sanitary arrangements and see that
the health and comfort of the workers are properly attended to.
On the whole we must assume that the activity of these inspectors
tends to improve the condition of the working-classes. Certainly
in some instances it has that effect. I remember, for example,
some thirty years ago, visiting a lucifer-match factory in which
the hands employed worked habitually in an atmosphere impregnated
with the fumes of phosphorus, which produce insidious and very
painful diseases. Such a thing is hardly possible nowadays. On
the other hand, official inspection, like Factory Acts, everywhere
gives rise to a good deal of dissatisfaction and does not always
improve the relations between employers and employed. Some of the
Russian inspectors, if I may credit the testimony of employers, are
young gentlemen imbued with socialist notions, who intentionally
stir up discontent or who make mischief from inexperience. An
amusing illustration of the current complaints came under my notice
when, in 1903, I was visiting a landed proprietor of the southern
provinces, who has a large sugar factory on his estate. The
inspector objected to the traditional custom of the men sleeping in
large dormitories and insisted on sleeping-cots being constructed
for them individually. As soon as the change was made the workmen
came to the proprietor to complain, and put their grievance in an
interrogative form: "Are we cattle that we should be thus couped up
in stalls?"
To return to the northern agricultural region, the rural population
have a peculiar type, which is to be accounted for by the fact that
they never experienced to its full extent the demoralising
influence of serfage. A large proportion of them were settled on
State domains and were governed by a special branch of the Imperial
administration, whilst others lived on the estates of rich absentee
landlords, who were in the habit of leaving the management of their
properties to a steward acting under a code of instructions. In
either case, though serfs in the eye of the law, they enjoyed
practically a very large amount of liberty. By paying a small sum
for a passport they could leave their villages for an indefinite
period, and as long as they sent home regularly the money required
for taxes and dues, they were in little danger of being molested.
Many of them, though officially inscribed as domiciled in their
native communes, lived permanently in the towns, and not a few
succeeded in amassing large fortunes. The effect of this
comparative freedom is apparent even at the present day. These
peasants of the north are more energetic, more intelligent, more
independent, and consequently less docile and pliable than those of
the fertile central provinces. They have, too, more education. A
large proportion of them can read and write, and occasionally one
meets among them men who have a keen desire for knowledge. Several
times I encountered peasants in this region who had a small
collection of books, and twice I found in such collections, much to
my astonishment, a Russian translation of Buckle's "History of
Civilisation."
How, it may be asked, did a work of this sort find its way to such
a place? If the reader will pardon a short digression, I shall
explain the fact.
Immediately after the Crimean War there was a curious intellectual
movement--of which I shall have more to say hereafter--among the
Russian educated classes. The movement assumed various forms, of
which two of the most prominent were a desire for encyclopaedic
knowledge, and an attempt to reduce all knowledge to a scientific
form. For men in this state of mind Buckle's great work had
naturally a powerful fascination. It seemed at first sight to
reduce the multifarious conflicting facts of human history to a few
simple principles, and to evolve order out of chaos. Its success,
therefore, was great. In the course of a few years no less than
four independent translations were published and sold. Every one
read, or at least professed to have read, the wonderful book, and
many believed that its author was the greatest genius of his time.
During the first year of my residence in Russia (1870), I rarely
had a serious conversation without hearing Buckle's name mentioned;
and my friends almost always assumed that he had succeeded in
creating a genuine science of history on the inductive method. In
vain I pointed out that Buckle had merely thrown out some hints in
his introductory chapter as to how such a science ought to be
constructed, and that he had himself made no serious attempt to use
the method which he commended. My objections had little or no
effect: the belief was too deep-rooted to be so easily eradicated.
In books, periodicals, newspapers, and professional lectures the
name of Buckle was constantly cited--often violently dragged in
without the slightest reason--and the cheap translations of his
work were sold in enormous quantities. It is not, then, so very
wonderful after all that the book should have found its way to two
villages in the province of Yaroslavl.
The enterprising, self-reliant, independent spirit which is often
to be found among those peasants manifests itself occasionally in
amusing forms among the young generation. Often in this part of
the country I have encountered boys who recalled young America
rather than young Russia. One of these young hopefuls I remember
well. I was waiting at a post-station for the horses to be
changed, when he appeared before me in a sheep-skin, fur cap, and
gigantic double-soled boots--all of which articles had been made on
a scale adapted to future rather than actual requirements. He must
have stood in his boots about three feet eight inches, and he could
not have been more than twelve years of age; but he had already
learned to look upon life as a serious business, wore a commanding
air, and knitted his innocent little brows as if the cares of an
empire weighed on his diminutive shoulders. Though he was to act
as yamstchik he had to leave the putting in of the horses to larger
specimens of the human species, but he took care that all was done
properly. Putting one of his big boots a little in advance, and
drawing himself up to his full shortness, he watched the operation
attentively, as if the smallness of his stature had nothing to do
with his inactivity. When all was ready, he climbed up to his
seat, and at a signal from the station-keeper, who watched with
paternal pride all the movements of the little prodigy, we dashed
off at a pace rarely attained by post-horses. He had the faculty
of emitting a peculiar sound--something between a whirr and a
whistle--that appeared to have a magical effect on the team and
every few minutes he employed this incentive. The road was rough,
and at every jolt he was shot upwards into the air, but he always
fell back into his proper position, and never lost for a moment his
self-possession or his balance. At the end of the journey I found
we had made nearly fourteen miles within the hour.
Unfortunately this energetic, enterprising spirit sometimes takes
an illegitimate direction. Not only whole villages, but even whole
districts, have in this way acquired a bad reputation for robbery,
the manufacture of paper-money, and similar offences against the
criminal law. In popular parlance, these localities are said to
contain "people who play pranks" (narod shalit). I must, however,
remark that, if I may judge by my own experience, these so-called
"playful" tendencies are greatly exaggerated. Though I have
travelled hundreds of miles at night on lonely roads, I was never
robbed or in any way molested. Once, indeed, when travelling at
night in a tarantass, I discovered on awaking that my driver was
bending over me, and had introduced his hand into one of my
pockets; but the incident ended without serious consequences. When
I caught the delinquent hand, and demanded an explanation from the
owner, he replied, in an apologetic, caressing tone, that the night
was cold, and he wished to warm his fingers; and when I advised him
to use for that purpose his own pockets rather than mine, he
promised to act in future according to my advice. More than once,
it is true, I believed that I was in danger of being attacked, but
on every occasion my fears turned out to be unfounded, and
sometimes the catastrophe was ludicrous rather than tragical. Let
the following serve as an illustration.
I had occasion to traverse, in company with a Russian friend, the
country lying to the east of the river Vetluga--a land of forest
and morass, with here and there a patch of cultivation. The
majority of the population are Tcheremiss, a Finnish tribe; but
near the banks of the river there are villages of Russian peasants,
and these latter have the reputation of "playing pranks." When we
were on the point of starting from Kozmodemiansk a town on the bank
of the Volga, we received a visit from an officer of rural police,
who painted in very sombre colours the habits and moral character--
or, more properly, immoral character--of the people whose
acquaintance we were about to make. He related with melodramatic
gesticulation his encounters with malefactors belonging to the
villages through which we had to pass, and ended the interview with
a strong recommendation to us not to travel at night, and to keep
at all times our eyes open and our revolver ready. The effect of
his narrative was considerably diminished by the prominence of the
moral, which was to the effect that there never had been a police-
officer who had shown so much zeal, energy, and courage in the
discharge of his duty as the worthy man before us. We considered
it, however, advisable to remember his hint about keeping our eyes
open.
In spite of our intention of being very cautious, it was already
dark when we arrived at the village which was to be our halting-
place for the night, and it seemed at first as if we should be
obliged to spend the night in the open air. The inhabitants had
already retired to rest, and refused to open their doors to unknown
travellers. At length an old woman, more hospitable than her
neighbours, or more anxious to earn an honest penny, consented to
let us pass the night in an outer apartment (seni), and this
permission we gladly accepted. Mindful of the warnings of the
police officer, we barricaded the two doors and the window, and the
precaution was evidently not superfluous, for almost as soon as the
light was extinguished we could hear that an attempt was being made
stealthily to effect an entrance. Notwithstanding my efforts to
remain awake, and on the watch, I at last fell asleep, and was
suddenly aroused by some one grasping me tightly by the arm.
Instantly I sprang to my feet and endeavoured to close with my
invisible assailant. In vain! He dexterously eluded my grasp, and
I stumbled over my portmanteau, which was lying on the floor; but
my prompt action revealed who the intruder was, by producing a wild
flutter and a frantic cackling! Before my companion could strike a
light the mysterious attack was fully explained. The supposed
midnight robber and possible assassin was simply a peaceable hen
that had gone to roost on my arm, and, on finding her position
unsteady, had dug her claws into what she mistook for a roosting-
pole!
When speaking of the peasantry of the north I have hitherto had in
view the inhabitants of the provinces of Old-Novgorod, Tver,
Yaroslavl, Nizhni-Novgorod, Kostroma, Kazan, and Viatka, and I have
founded my remarks chiefly on information collected on the spot.
Beyond this lies what may be called the Far North. Though I cannot
profess to have the same personal acquaintance with the peasantry
of that region, I may perhaps be allowed to insert here some
information regarding them which I collected from various
trustworthy sources.
If we draw a wavy line eastward from a point a little to the north
of St. Petersburg, as is shown in the map facing page 1 of this
volume, we shall have between that line and the Polar Ocean what
may be regarded as a distinct, peculiar region, differing in many
respects from the rest of Russia. Throughout the whole of it the
climate is very severe. For about half of the year the ground is
covered by deep snow, and the rivers are frozen. By far the
greater part of the land is occupied by forests of pine, fir,
larch, and birch, or by vast, unfathomable morasses. The arable
land and pasturage taken together form only about one and a half
per cent, of the area. The population is scarce--little more than
one to the English square mile--and settled chiefly along the banks
of the rivers. The peasantry support themselves by fishing,
hunting, felling and floating timber, preparing tar and charcoal,
cattle-breeding, and, in the extreme north, breeding reindeer.
These are their chief occupations, but the people do not entirely
neglect agriculture. They make the most of their short summer by
means of a peculiar and ingenious mode of farming, well adapted to
the peculiar local conditions. The peasant knows of course nothing
about agronomical chemistry, but he, as well as his forefathers,
have observed that if wood be burnt on a field, and the ashes be
mixed with the soil, a good harvest may be confidently expected.
On this simple principle his system of farming is based. When
spring comes round and the leaves begin to appear on the trees, a
band of peasants, armed with their hatchets, proceed to some spot
in the woods previously fixed upon. Here they begin to make a
clearing. This is no easy matter, for tree-felling is hard and
tedious work; but the process does not take so much time as might
be expected, for the workmen have been brought up to the trade, and
wield their axes with marvellous dexterity. When they have felled
all the trees, great and small, they return to their homes, and
think no more about their clearing till the autumn, when they
return, in order to strip the fallen trees of the branches, to pick
out what they require for building purposes or firewood, and to
pile up the remainder in heaps. The logs for building or firewood
are dragged away by horses as soon as the first fall of snow has
made a good slippery road, but the piles are allowed to remain till
the following spring, when they are stirred up with long poles and
ignited. The flames rapidly spread in all directions till they
join together and form a gigantic bonfire, such as is never seen in
more densely-populated countries. If the fire does its work
properly, the whole of the space is covered with a layer of ashes;
and when these have been slightly mixed with soil by means of a
light plough, the seed is sown.
On the field prepared in this original fashion is sown barley, rye,
or flax, and the harvests, nearly always good, sometimes border on
the miraculous. Barley or rye may be expected to produce about
sixfold in ordinary years, and they may produce as much as thirty-
fold under peculiarly favourable circumstances. The fertility is,
however, short-lived. If the soil is poor and stony, not more than
two crops can be raised; if it is of a better quality, it may give
tolerable harvests for six or seven successive years. In most
countries this would be an absurdly expensive way of manuring, for
wood is much too valuable a commodity to be used for such a
purpose; but in this northern region the forests are boundless, and
in the districts where there is no river or stream by which timber
may be floated, the trees not used in this way rot from old age.
Under these circumstances the system is reasonable, but it must be
admitted that it does not give a very large return for the amount
of labour expended, and in bad seasons it gives almost no return at
all.
The other sources of revenue are scarcely less precarious. With
his gun and a little parcel of provisions the peasant wanders about
in the trackless forests, and too often returns after many days
with a very light bag; or he starts in autumn for some distant
lake, and comes back after five or six weeks with nothing better
than perch and pike. Sometimes he tries his luck at deep-sea
fishing. In this case he starts in February--probably on foot--for
Kem, on the shore of the White Sea, or perhaps for the more distant
Kola, situated on a small river which falls into the Arctic Ocean.
There, in company with three or four comrades, he starts on a
fishing cruise along the Murman coast, or, it may be, off the coast
of Spitzbergen. His gains will depend on the amount caught, for it
is a joint-venture; but in no case can they be very great, for
three-fourths of the fish brought into port belongs to the owner of
the craft and tackle. Of the sum realised, he brings home perhaps
only a small part, for he has a strong temptation to buy rum, tea,
and other luxuries, which are very dear in those northern
latitudes. If the fishing is good and he resists temptation, he
may save as much as 100 roubles--about 10 pounds--and thereby live
comfortably all winter; but if the fishing season is bad, he may
find himself at the end of it not only with empty pockets, but in
debt to the owner of the boat. This debt he may pay off, if he has
a horse, by transporting the dried fish to Kargopol, St.
Petersburg, or some other market.
It is here in the Far North that the ancient folk-lore--popular
songs, stories, and fragments of epic poetry--has been best
preserved; but this is a field on which I need not enter, for the
reader can easily find all that he may desire to know on the
subject in the brilliant writings of M. Rambaud and the very
interesting, conscientious works of the late Mr. Ralston,* which
enjoy a high reputation in Russia.
* Rambaud, "La Russie Epique," Paris, 1876; Ralston, "The Songs of
the Russian People," London, 1872; and "Russian Folk-tales,"
London, 1873.
CHAPTER VIII
THE MIR, OR VILLAGE COMMUNITY
Social and Political Importance of the Mir--The Mir and the Family
Compared--Theory of the Communal System--Practical Deviations from
the Theory--The Mir a Good Specimen of Constitutional Government of
the Extreme Democratic Type--The Village Assembly--Female Members--
The Elections--Distribution of the Communal Land.
When I had gained a clear notion of the family-life and occupations
of the peasantry, I turned my attention to the constitution of the
village. This was a subject which specially interested me, because
I was aware that the Mir is the most peculiar of Russian
institutions. Long before visiting Russia I had looked into
Haxthausen's celebrated work, by which the peculiarities of the
Russian village system were first made known to Western Europe, and
during my stay in St. Petersburg I had often been informed by
intelligent, educated Russians that the rural Commune presented a
practical solution of many difficult social problems with which the
philosophers and statesmen of the West had long been vainly
struggling. "The nations of the West"--such was the substance of
innumerable discourses which I had heard--"are at present on the
high-road to political and social anarchy, and England has the
unenviable distinction of being foremost in the race. The natural
increase of population, together with the expropriation of the
small landholders by the great landed proprietors, has created a
dangerous and ever-increasing Proletariat--a great disorganised
mass of human beings, without homes, without permanent domicile,
without property of any kind, without any stake in the existing
institutions. Part of these gain a miserable pittance as
agricultural labourers, and live in a condition infinitely worse
than serfage. The others have been forever uprooted from the soil,
and have collected in the large towns, where they earn a precarious
living in the factories and workshops, or swell the ranks of the
criminal classes. In England you have no longer a peasantry in the
proper sense of the term, and unless some radical measures be very
soon adopted, you will never be able to create such a class, for
men who have been long exposed to the unwholesome influences of
town life are physically and morally incapable of becoming
agriculturists.
"Hitherto," the disquisition proceeded, "England has enjoyed, in
consequence of her geographical position, her political freedom,
and her vast natural deposits of coal and iron, a wholly
exceptional position in the industrial world. Fearing no
competition, she has proclaimed the principles of Free Trade, and
has inundated the world with her manufactures--using unscrupulously
her powerful navy and all the other forces at her command for
breaking down every barrier tending to check the flood sent forth
from Manchester and Birmingham. In that way her hungry Proletariat
has been fed. But the industrial supremacy of England is drawing
to a close. The nations have discovered the perfidious fallacy of
Free-Trade principles, and are now learning to manufacture for
their own wants, instead of paying England enormous sums to
manufacture for them. Very soon English goods will no longer find
foreign markets, and how will the hungry Proletariat then be fed?
Already the grain production of England is far from sufficient for
the wants of the population, so that, even when the harvest is
exceptionally abundant, enormous quantities of wheat are imported
from all quarters of the globe. Hitherto this grain has been paid
for by the manufactured goods annually exported, but how will it be
procured when these goods are no longer wanted by foreign
consumers? And what then will the hungry Proletariat do?"*
* This passage was written, precisely as it stands, long before the
fiscal question was raised by Mr. Chamberlain. It will be found in
the first edition of this work, published in 1877. (Vol. I., pp.
179-81.)
This sombre picture of England's future had often been presented to
me, and on nearly every occasion I had been assured that Russia had
been saved from these terrible evils by the rural Commune--an
institution which, in spite of its simplicity and incalculable
utility, West Europeans seemed utterly incapable of understanding
and appreciating.
The reader will now easily conceive with what interest I took to
studying this wonderful institution, and with what energy I
prosecuted my researches. An institution which professes to solve
satisfactorily the most difficult social problems of the future is
not to be met with every day, even in Russia, which is specially
rich in material for the student of social science.
On my arrival at Ivanofka my knowledge of the institution was of
that vague, superficial kind which is commonly derived from men who
are fonder of sweeping generalisations and rhetorical declamation
than of serious, patient study of phenomena. I knew that the chief
personage in a Russian village is the Selski Starosta, or Village
Elder, and that all important Communal affairs are regulated by the
Selski Skhod, or Village Assembly. Further, I was aware that the
land in the vicinity of the village belongs to the Commune, and is
distributed periodically among the members in such a way that every
able-bodied peasant possesses a share sufficient, or nearly
sufficient, for his maintenance. Beyond this elementary
information I knew little or nothing.
My first attempt at extending my knowledge was not very successful.
Hoping that my friend Ivan might be able to assist me, and knowing
that the popular name for the Commune is Mir, which means also "the
world," I put to him the direct, simple question, "What is the
Mir?"
Ivan was not easily disconcerted, but for once he looked puzzled,
and stared at me vacantly. When I endeavoured to explain to him my
question, he simply knitted his brows and scratched the back of his
head. This latter movement is the Russian peasant's method of
accelerating cerebral action; but in the present instance it had no
practical result. In spite of his efforts, Ivan could not get much
further than the "Kak vam skazat'?" that is to say, "How am I to
tell you?"
It was not difficult to perceive that I had adopted an utterly
false method of investigation, and a moment's reflection sufficed
to show me the absurdity of my question. I had asked from an
uneducated man a philosophical definition, instead of extracting
from him material in the form of concrete facts, and constructing
therefrom a definition for myself. These concrete facts Ivan was
both able and willing to supply; and as soon as I adopted a
rational mode of questioning, I obtained from him all I wanted.
The information he gave me, together with the results of much
subsequent conversation and reading, I now propose to present to
the reader in my own words.
The peasant family of the old type is, as we have just seen, a kind
of primitive association in which the members have nearly all
things in common. The village may be roughly described as a
primitive association on a larger scale.
Between these two social units there are many points of analogy.
In both there are common interests and common responsibilities. In
both there is a principal personage, who is in a certain sense
ruler within and representative as regards the outside world: in
the one case called Khozain, or Head of the Household, and in the
other Starosta, or Village Elder. In both the authority of the
ruler is limited: in the one case by the adult members of the
family, and in the other by the Heads of Households. In both there
is a certain amount of common property: in the one case the house
and nearly all that it contains, and in the other the arable land
and possibly a little pasturage. In both cases there is a certain
amount of common responsibility: in the one case for all the debts,
and in the other for all the taxes and Communal obligations. And
both are protected to a certain extent against the ordinary legal
consequences of insolvency, for the family cannot be deprived of
its house or necessary agricultural implements, and the Commune
cannot be deprived of its land, by importunate creditors.
On the other hand, there are many important points of contrast. The
Commune is, of course, much larger than the family, and the mutual
relations of its members are by no means so closely interwoven.
The members of a family all farm together, and those of them who
earn money from other sources are expected to put their savings
into the common purse; whilst the households composing a Commune
farm independently, and pay into the common treasury only a certain
fixed sum.
From these brief remarks the reader will at once perceive that a
Russian village is something very different from a village in our
sense of the term, and that the villagers are bound together by
ties quite unknown to the English rural population. A family
living in an English village has little reason to take an interest
in the affairs of its neighbours. The isolation of the individual
families is never quite perfect, for man, being a social animal,
takes necessarily a certain interest in the affairs of those around
him, and this social duty is sometimes fulfilled by the weaker sex
with more zeal than is absolutely indispensable for the public
welfare; but families may live for many years in the same village
without ever becoming conscious of common interests. So long as
the Jones family do not commit any culpable breach of public order,
such as putting obstructions on the highway or habitually setting
their house on fire, their neighbour Brown takes probably no
interest in their affairs, and has no ground for interfering with
their perfect liberty of action. Amongst the families composing a
Russian village, such a state of isolation is impossible. The
Heads of Households must often meet together and consult in the
Village Assembly, and their daily occupation must be influenced by
the Communal decrees. They cannot begin to mow the hay or plough
the fallow field until the Village Assembly has passed a resolution
on the subject. If a peasant becomes a drunkard, or takes some
equally efficient means to become insolvent, every family in the
village has a right to complain, not merely in the interests of
public morality, but from selfish motives, because all the families
are collectively responsible for his taxes.* For the same reason
no peasant can permanently leave the village without the consent of
the Commune, and this consent will not be granted until the
applicant gives satisfactory security for the fulfilment of his
actual and future liabilities. If a peasant wishes to go away for
a short time, in order to work elsewhere, he must obtain a written
permission, which serves him as a passport during his absence; and
he may be recalled at any moment by a Communal decree. In reality
he is rarely recalled so long as he sends home regularly the full
amount of his taxes--including the dues which he has to pay for the
temporary passport--but sometimes the Commune uses the power of
recall for purposes of extortion. If it becomes known, for
instance, that an absent member is receiving a good salary or
otherwise making money, he may one day receive a formal order to
return at once to his native village, but he is probably informed
at the same time, unofficially, that his presence will be dispensed
with if he will send to the Commune a certain specified sum. The
money thus sent is generally used by the Commune for convivial
purposes. **
* This common responsibility for the taxes was abolished in 1903 by
the Emperor, on the advice of M. Witte, and the other Communal
fetters are being gradually relaxed. A peasant may now, if he
wishes, cease to be a member of the Commune altogether, as soon as
he has defrayed all his outstanding obligations.
** With the recent relaxing of the Communal fetters, referred to in
the foregoing note, this abuse should disappear.
In all countries the theory of government and administration
differs considerably from the actual practice. Nowhere is this
difference greater than in Russia, and in no Russian institution is
it greater than in the Village Commune. It is necessary,
therefore, to know both theory and practice; and it is well to
begin with the former, because it is the simpler of the two. When
we have once thoroughly mastered the theory, it is easy to
understand the deviations that are made to suit peculiar local
conditions.
According, then, to theory, all male peasants in every part of the
Empire are inscribed in census-lists, which form the basis of the
direct taxation. These lists are revised at irregular intervals,
and all males alive at the time of the "revision," from the newborn
babe to the centenarian, are duly inscribed. Each Commune has a
list of this kind, and pays to the Government an annual sum
proportionate to the number of names which the list contains, or,
in popular language, according to the number of "revision souls."
During the intervals between the revisions the financial
authorities take no notice of the births and deaths. A Commune
which has a hundred male members at the time of the revision may
have in a few years considerably more or considerably less than
that number, but it has to pay taxes for a hundred members all the
same until a new revision is made for the whole Empire.
Now in Russia, so far at least as the rural population is
concerned, the payment of taxes is inseparably connected with the
possession of land. Every peasant who pays taxes is supposed to
have a share of the land belonging to the Commune. If the Communal
revision lists contain a hundred names, the Communal land ought to
be divided into a hundred shares, and each "revision soul" should
enjoy his share in return for the taxes which he pays.
The reader who has followed my explanations up to this point may
naturally conclude that the taxes paid by the peasants are in
reality a species of rent for the land which they enjoy. Such a
conclusion would not be altogether justified. When a man rents a
bit of land he acts according to his own judgment, and makes a
voluntary contract with the proprietor; but the Russian peasant is
obliged to pay his taxes whether he desires to enjoy land or not.
The theory, therefore, that the taxes are simply the rent of the
land will not bear even superficial examination. Equally untenable
is the theory that they are a species of land-tax. In any
reasonable system of land-dues the yearly sum imposed bears some
kind of proportion to the quantity and quality of the land enjoyed;
but in Russia it may be that the members of one Commune possess six
acres of bad land, and the members of the neighbouring Commune
seven acres of good land, and yet the taxes in both cases are the
same. The truth is that the taxes are personal, and are calculated
according to the number of male "souls," and the Government does
not take the trouble to inquire how the Communal land is
distributed. The Commune has to pay into the Imperial Treasury a
fixed yearly sum, according to the number of its "revision souls,"
and distributes the land among its members as it thinks fit.
How, then, does the Commune distribute the land? To this question
it is impossible to reply in brief, general terms, because each
Commune acts as it pleases!* Some act strictly according to the
theory. These divide their land at the time of the revision into a
number of portions or shares corresponding to the number of
revision souls, and give to each family a number of shares
corresponding to the number of revision souls which it contains.
This is from the administrative point of view by far the simplest
system. The census-list determines how much land each family will
enjoy, and the existing tenures are disturbed only by the revisions
which take place at irregular intervals.** But, on the other hand,
this system has serious defects. The revision-list represents
merely the numerical strength of the families, and the numerical
strength is often not at all in proportion to the working power.
Let us suppose, for example, two families, each containing at the
time of the revision five male members. According to the census-
list these two families are equal, and ought to receive equal
shares of the land; but in reality it may happen that the one
contains a father in the prime of life and four able-bodies sons,
whilst the other contains a widow and five little boys. The wants
and working power of these two families are of course very
different; and if the above system of distribution be applied, the
man with four sons and a goodly supply of grandchildren will
probably find that he has too little land, whilst the widow with
her five little boys will find it difficult to cultivate the five
shares alloted to her, and utterly impossible to pay the
corresponding amount of taxation--for in all cases, it must be
remembered, the Communal burdens are distributed in the same
proportion as the land.
* A long list of the various systems of allotment to be found in
individual Communes in different parts of the country is given in
the opening chapter of a valuable work by Karelin, entitled
"Obshtchinnoye Vladyenie v Rossii" (St. Petersburg, 1893). As my
object is to convey to the reader merely a general idea of the
institution, I refrain from confusing him by an enumeration of the
endless divergencies from the original type.
** Since 1719 eleven revisions have been made, the last in 1897.
The intervals varied from six to forty-one years.
But why, it may be said, should the widow not accept provisionally
the five shares, and let to others the part which she does not
require? The balance of rent after payment of the taxes might help
her to bring up her young family.
So it seems to one acquainted only with the rural economy of
England, where land is scarce, and always gives a revenue more than
sufficient to defray the taxes. But in Russia the possession of a
share of Communal land is often not a privilege, but a burden. In
some Communes the land is so poor and abundant that it cannot be
let at any price. In others the soil will repay cultivation, but a
fair rent will not suffice to pay the taxes and dues.
To obviate these inconvenient results of the simpler system, many
Communes have adopted the expedient of allotting the land, not
according to the number of revision souls, but according to the
working power of the families. Thus, in the instance above
supposed, the widow would receive perhaps two shares, and the large
household, containing five workers, would receive perhaps seven or
eight. Since the breaking-up of the large families, such
inequality as I have supposed is, of course, rare; but inequality
of a less extreme kind does still occur, and justifies a departure
from the system of allotment according to the revision-lists.
Even if the allotment be fair and equitable at the time of the
revision, it may soon become unfair and burdensome by the natural
fluctuations of the population. Births and deaths may in the
course of a very few years entirely alter the relative working
power of the various families. The sons of the widow may grow up
to manhood, whilst two or three able-bodied members of the other
family may be cut off by an epidemic. Thus, long before a new
revision takes place, the distribution of the land may be no longer
in accordance with the wants and capacities of the various families
composing the Commune. To correct this, various expedients are
employed. Some Communes transfer particular lots from one family
to another, as circumstances demand; whilst others make from time
to time, during the intervals between the revisions, a complete
redistribution and reallotment of the land. Of these two systems
the former is now more frequently employed.
The system of allotment adopted depends entirely on the will of the
particular Commune. In this respect the Communes enjoy the most
complete autonomy, and no peasant ever dreams of appealing against
a Communal decree.* The higher authorities not only abstain from
all interference in the allotment of the Communal lands, but remain
in profound ignorance as to which system the Communes habitually
adopt. Though the Imperial Administration has a most voracious
appetite for symmetrically constructed statistical tables--many of
them formed chiefly out of materials supplied by the mysterious
inner consciousness of the subordinate officials--no attempt has
yet been made, so far as I know, to collect statistical data which
might throw light on this important subject. In spite of the
systematic and persistent efforts of the centralised bureaucracy to
regulate minutely all departments of the national life, the rural
Communes, which contain about five-sixths of the population, remain
in many respects entirely beyond its influence, and even beyond its
sphere of vision! But let not the reader be astonished overmuch.
He will learn in time that Russia is the land of paradoxes; and
meanwhile he is about to receive a still more startling bit of
information. In "the great stronghold of Caesarian despotism and
centralised bureaucracy," these Village Communes, containing about
five-sixths of the population, are capital specimens of
representative Constitutional government of the extreme democratic
type!
* This has been somewhat modified by recent legislation. According
to the Emancipation Law of 1861, redistribution of the land could
take place at any time provided it was voted by a majority of two-
thirds at the Village Assembly. By a law of 1893 redistribution
cannot take place oftener than once in twelve years, and must
receive the sanction of certain local authorities.
When I say that the rural Commune is a good specimen of
Constitutional government, I use the phrase in the English, and not
in the Continental sense. In the Continental languages a
Constitutional regime implies the existence of a long, formal
document, in which the functions of the various institutions, the
powers of the various authorities, and the methods of procedure are
carefully defined. Such a document was never heard of in Russian
Village Communes, except those belonging to the Imperial Domains,
and the special legislation which formerly regulated their affairs
was repealed at the time of the Emancipation. At the present day
the Constitution of all the Village Communes is of the English
type--a body of unwritten, traditional conceptions, which have
grown up and modified themselves under the influence of ever-
changing practical necessity. No doubt certain definitions of the
functions and mutual relations of the Communal authorities might be
extracted from the Emancipation Law and subsequent official
documents, but as a rule neither the Village Elder nor the members
of the Village Assembly ever heard of such definitions; and yet
every peasant knows, as if by instinct, what each of these
authorities can do and cannot do. The Commune is, in fact, a
living institution, whose spontaneous vitality enables it to
dispense with the assistance and guidance of the written law, and
its constitution is thoroughly democratic. The Elder represents
merely the executive power. The real authority resides in the
Assembly, of which all Heads of Households are members.*
* An attempt was made by Alexander III. in 1884 to bring the rural
Communes under supervision and control by the appointment of rural
officials called Zemskiye Natchalniki. Of this so-called reform I
shall have occasion to speak later.
The simple procedure, or rather the absence of all formal
procedure, at the Assemblies, illustrates admirably the essentially
practical character of the institution. The meetings are held in
the open air, because in the village there is no building--except
the church, which can be used only for religious purposes--large
enough to contain all the members; and they almost always take
place on Sundays or holidays, when the peasants have plenty of
leisure. Any open space may serve as a Forum. The discussions are
occasionally very animated, but there is rarely any attempt at
speech-making. If any young member should show an inclination to
indulge in oratory, he is sure to be unceremoniously interrupted by
some of the older members, who have never any sympathy with fine
talking. The assemblage has the appearance of a crowd of people
who have accidentally come together and are discussing in little
groups subjects of local interest. Gradually some one group,
containing two or three peasants who have more moral influence than
their fellows, attracts the others, and the discussion becomes
general. Two or more peasants may speak at a time, and interrupt
each other freely--using plain, unvarnished language, not at all
parliamentary--and the discussion may become a confused,
unintelligible din; but at the moment when the spectator imagines
that the consultation is about to be transformed into a free fight,
the tumult spontaneously subsides, or perhaps a general roar of
laughter announces that some one has been successfully hit by a
strong argumentum ad hominem, or biting personal remark. In any
case there is no danger of the disputants coming to blows. No
class of men in the world are more good-natured and pacific than
the Russian peasantry. When sober they never fight, and even when
under the influence of alcohol they are more likely to be violently
affectionate than disagreeably quarrelsome. If two of them take to
drinking together, the probability is that in a few minutes, though
they may never have seen each other before, they will be expressing
in very strong terms their mutual regard and affection, confirming
their words with an occasional friendly embrace.
Theoretically speaking, the Village Parliament has a Speaker, in
the person of the Village Elder. The word Speaker is
etymologically less objectionable than the term President, for the
personage in question never sits down, but mingles in the crowd
like the ordinary members. Objection may be taken to the word on
the ground that the Elder speaks much less than many other members,
but this may likewise be said of the Speaker of the House of
Commons. Whatever we may call him, the Elder is officially the
principal personage in the crowd, and wears the insignia of office
in the form of a small medal suspended from his neck by a thin
brass chain. His duties, however, are extremely light. To call to
order those who interrupt the discussion is no part of his
functions. If he calls an honourable member "Durak" (blockhead),
or interrupts an orator with a laconic "Moltchi!" (hold your
tongue!), he does so in virtue of no special prerogative, but
simply in accordance with a time-honoured privilege, which is
equally enjoyed by all present, and may be employed with impunity
against himself. Indeed, it may be said in general that the
phraseology and the procedure are not subjected to any strict
rules. The Elder comes prominently forward only when it is
necessary to take the sense of the meeting. On such occasions he
may stand back a little from the crowd and say, "Well, orthodox,
have you decided so?" and the crowd will probably shout, "Ladno!
ladno!" that is to say, "Agreed! agreed!"
Communal measures are generally carried in this way by acclamation;
but it sometimes happens that there is such a diversity of opinion
that it is difficult to tell which of the two parties has a
majority. In this case the Elder requests the one party to stand
to the right and the other to the left. The two groups are then
counted, and the minority submits, for no one ever dreams of
opposing openly the will of the Mir.
During the reign of Nicholas I. an attempt was made to regulate by
the written law the procedure of Village Assemblies amongst the
peasantry of the State Domains, and among other reforms voting by
ballot was introduced; but the new custom never struck root. The
peasants did not regard with favour the new method, and persisted
in calling it, contemptuously, "playing at marbles." Here, again,
we have one of those wonderful and apparently anomalous facts which
frequently meet the student of Russian affairs: the Emperor
Nicholas I., the incarnation of autocracy and the champion of the
Reactionary Party throughout Europe, forces the ballot-box, the
ingenious invention of extreme radicals, on several millions of his
subjects!
In the northern provinces, where a considerable portion of the male
population is always absent, the Village Assembly generally
includes a good many female members. These are women who, on
account of the absence or death of their husbands, happen to be for
the moment Heads of Households. As such they are entitled to be
present, and their right to take part in the deliberations is never
called in question. In matters affecting the general welfare of
the Commune they rarely speak, and if they do venture to enounce an
opinion on such occasions they have little chance of commanding
attention, for the Russian peasantry are as yet little imbued with
the modern doctrines of female equality, and express their opinion
of female intelligence by the homely adage: "The hair is long, but
the mind is short." According to one proverb, seven women have
collectively but one soul, and, according to a still more ungallant
popular saying, women have no souls at all, but only a vapour.
Woman, therefore, as woman, is not deserving of much consideration,
but a particular woman, as Head of a Household, is entitled to
speak on all questions directly affecting the household under her
care. If, for instance, it be proposed to increase or diminish her
household's share of the land and the burdens, she will be allowed
to speak freely on the subject, and even to indulge in personal
invective against her male opponents. She thereby exposes herself,
it is true, to uncomplimentary remarks; but any which she happens
to receive she is pretty sure to repay with interest--referring,
perhaps, with pertinent virulence to the domestic affairs of those
who attack her. And when argument and invective fail, she can try
the effect of pathetic appeal, supported by copious tears.
As the Village Assembly is really a representative institution in
the full sense of the term, it reflects faithfully the good and the
bad qualities of the rural population. Its decisions are therefore
usually characterised by plain, practical common sense, but it is
subject to occasional unfortunate aberrations in consequence of
pernicious influences, chiefly of an alcoholic kind. An instance
of this fact occurred during my sojourn at Ivanofka. The question
under discussion was whether a kabak, or gin-shop, should be
established in the village. A trader from the district town
desired to establish one, and offered to pay to the Commune a
yearly sum for the necessary permission. The more industrious,
respectable members of the Commune, backed by the whole female
population, were strongly opposed to the project, knowing full well
that a kabak would certainly lead to the ruin of more than one
household; but the enterprising trader had strong arguments
wherewith to seduce a large number of the members, and succeeded in
obtaining a decision in his favour.
The Assembly discusses all matters affecting the Communal welfare,
and, as these matters have never been legally defined, its
recognised competence is very wide. It fixes the time for making
the hay, and the day for commencing the ploughing of the fallow
field; it decrees what measures shall be employed against those who
do not punctually pay their taxes; it decides whether a new member
shall be admitted into the Commune, and whether an old member shall
be allowed to change his domicile; it gives or withholds permission
to erect new buildings on the Communal land; it prepares and signs
all contracts which the Commune makes with one of its own members
or with a stranger; it interferes whenever it thinks necessary in
the domestic affairs of its members; it elects the Elder--as well
as the Communal tax-collector and watchman, where such offices
exist--and the Communal herd-boy; above all, it divides and allots
the Communal land among the members as it thinks fit.
Of all these various proceedings the English reader may naturally
assume that the elections are the most noisy and exciting. In
reality this is a mistake. The elections produce little
excitement, for the simple reason that, as a rule, no one desires
to be elected. Once, it is said, a peasant who had been guilty of
some misdemeanor was informed by an Arbiter of the Peace--a species
of official of which I shall have occasion to speak in the sequel--
that he would be no longer capable of filling any Communal office;
and instead of regretting this diminution of his civil rights, he
bowed very low, and respectfully expressed his thanks for the new
privilege which he had acquired. This anecdote may not be true,
but it illustrates the undoubted fact that the Russian peasant
regards office as a burden rather than as an honour. There is no
civic ambition in those little rural commonwealths, whilst the
privilege of wearing a bronze medal, which commands no respect, and
the reception of a few roubles as salary afford no adequate
compensation for the trouble, annoyance, and responsibility which a
Village Elder has to bear. The elections are therefore generally
very tame and uninteresting. The following description may serve
as an illustration:
It is a Sunday afternoon. The peasants, male and female, have
turned out in Sunday attire, and the bright costumes of the women
help the sunshine to put a little rich colour into the scene, which
is at ordinary times monotonously grey. Slowly the crowd collects
on the open space at the side of the church. All classes of the
population are represented. On the extreme outskirts are a band of
fair-haired, merry children--some of them standing or lying on the
grass and gazing attentively at the proceedings, and others running
about and amusing themselves. Close to these stand a group of
young girls, convulsed with half-suppressed laughter. The cause of
their merriment is a youth of some seventeen summers, evidently the
wag of the village, who stands beside them with an accordion in his
hand, and relates to them in a half-whisper how he is about to be
elected Elder, and what mad pranks he will play in that capacity.
When one of the girls happens to laugh outright, the matrons who
are standing near turn round and scowl; and one of them, stepping
forward, orders the offender, in a tone of authority, to go home at
once if she cannot behave herself. Crestfallen, the culprit
retires, and the youth who is the cause of the merriment makes the
incident the subject of a new joke. Meanwhile the deliberations
have begun. The majority of the members are chatting together, or
looking at a little group composed of three peasants and a woman,
who are standing a little apart from the others. Here alone the
matter in hand is being really discussed. The woman is explaining,
with tears in her eyes, and with a vast amount of useless
repetition, that her "old man," who is Elder for the time being, is
very ill, and cannot fulfil his duties.
"But he has not yet served a year, and he'll get better," remarks
one peasant, evidently the youngest of the little group.
"Who knows?" replies the woman, sobbing. "It is the will of God,
but I don't believe that he'll ever put his foot to the ground
again. The Feldsher has been four times to see him, and the doctor
himself came once, and said that he must be brought to the
hospital."
"And why has he not been taken there?"
"How could he be taken? Who is to carry him? Do you think he's a
baby? The hospital is forty versts off. If you put him in a cart
he would die before he had gone a verst. And then, who knows what
they do with people in the hospital?" This last question contained
probably the true reason why the doctor's orders had been
disobeyed.
"Very well, that's enough; hold your tongue," says the grey-beard
of the little group to the woman; and then, turning to the other
peasants, remarks, "There is nothing to be done. The Stanovoi
[officer of rural police] will be here one of these days, and will
make a row again if we don't elect a new Elder. Whom shall we
choose?"
As soon as this question is asked several peasants look down to the
ground, or try in some other way to avoid attracting attention,
lest their names should be suggested. When the silence has
continued a minute or two, the greybeard says, "There is Alexei
Ivanof; he has not served yet!"
"Yes, yes, Alexei Ivanof!" shout half-a-dozen voices, belonging
probably to peasants who fear they may be elected.
Alexei protests in the strongest terms. He cannot say that he is
ill, because his big ruddy face would give him the lie direct, but
he finds half-a-dozen other reasons why he should not be chosen,
and accordingly requests to be excused. But his protestations are
not listened to, and the proceedings terminate. A new Village
Elder has been duly elected.
Far more important than the elections is the redistribution of the
Communal land. It can matter but little to the Head of a Household
how the elections go, provided he himself is not chosen. He can
accept with perfect equanimity Alexei, or Ivan, or Nikolai, because
the office-bearers have very little influence in Communal affairs.
But he cannot remain a passive, indifferent spectator when the
division and allotment of the land come to be discussed, for the
material welfare of every household depends to a great extent on
the amount of land and of burdens which it receives.
In the southern provinces, where the soil is fertile, and the taxes
do not exceed the normal rent, the process of division and
allotment is comparatively simple. Here each peasant desires to
get as much land as possible, and consequently each household
demands all the land to which it is entitled--that is to say, a
number of shares equal to the number of its members inscribed in
the last revision list. The Assembly has therefore no difficult
questions to decide. The Communal revision list determines the
number of shares into which the land must be divided, and the
number of shares to be allotted to each family. The only
difficulty likely to arise is as to which particular shares a
particular family shall receive, and this difficulty is commonly
obviated by the custom of drawing lots. There may be, it is true,
some difference of opinion as to when a redistribution should be
made, but this question is easily decided by a vote of the
Assembly.
Very different is the process of division and allotment in many
Communes of the northern provinces. Here the soil is often very
unfertile and the taxes exceed the normal rent, and consequently it
may happen that the peasants strive to have as little land as
possible. In these cases such scenes as the following may occur:
Ivan is being asked how many shares of the Communal land he will
take, and replies in a slow, contemplative way, "I have two sons,
and there is myself, so I'll take three shares, or somewhat less,
if it is your pleasure."
"Less!" exclaims a middle-aged peasant, who is not the Village
Elder, but merely an influential member, and takes the leading part
in the proceedings. "You talk nonsense. Your two sons are already
old enough to help you, and soon they may get married, and so bring
you two new female labourers."
"My eldest son," explains Ivan, "always works in Moscow, and the
other often leaves me in summer."
"But they both send or bring home money, and when they get married,
the wives will remain with you."
"God knows what will be," replies Ivan, passing over in silence the
first part of his opponent's remark. "Who knows if they will
marry?"
"You can easily arrange that!"
"That I cannot do. The times are changed now. The young people do
as they wish, and when they do get married they all wish to have
houses of their own. Three shares will be heavy enough for me!"
"No, no. If they wish to separate from you, they will take some
land from you. You must take at least four. The old wives there
who have little children cannot take shares according to the number
of souls."
"He is a rich muzhik!" says a voice in the crowd. "Lay on him five
souls!" (that is to say, give him five shares of the land and of
the burdens).
"Five souls I cannot! By God, I cannot!"
"Very well, you shall have four," says the leading spirit to Ivan;
and then, turning to the crowd, inquires, "Shall it be so?"
"Four! four!" murmurs the crowd; and the question is settled.
Next comes one of the old wives just referred to. Her husband is a
permanent invalid, and she has three little boys, only one of whom
is old enough for field labour. If the number of souls were taken
as the basis of distribution, she would receive four shares; but
she would never be able to pay four shares of the Communal burdens.
She must therefore receive less than that amount. When asked how
many she will take, she replies with downcast eyes, "As the Mir
decides, so be it!"
"Then you must take three."
"What do you say, little father?" cries the woman, throwing off
suddenly her air of submissive obedience. "Do you hear that, ye
orthodox? They want to lay upon me three souls! Was such a thing
ever heard of? Since St. Peter's Day my husband has been
bedridden--bewitched, it seems, for nothing does him good. He
cannot put a foot to the ground--all the same as if he were dead;
only he eats bread!"
"You talk nonsense," says a neighbour; "he was in the kabak [gin-
shop] last week."
"And you!" retorts the woman, wandering from the subject in hand;
"what did YOU do last parish fete? Was it not you who got drunk
and beat your wife till she roused the whole village with her
shrieking? And no further gone than last Sunday--pfu!"
"Listen!" says the old man, sternly cutting short the torrent of
invective. "You must take at least two shares and a half. If you
cannot manage it yourself, you can get some one to help you."
"How can that be? Where am I to get the money to pay a labourer?"
asks the woman, with much wailing and a flood of tears. "Have
pity, ye orthodox, on the poor orphans! God will reward you!" and
so on, and so on.
I need not worry the reader with a further description of these
scenes, which are always very long and sometimes violent. All
present are deeply interested, for the allotment of the land is by
far the most important event in Russian peasant life, and the
arrangement cannot be made without endless talking and discussion.
After the number of shares for each family has been decided, the
distribution of the lots gives rise to new difficulties. The
families who have plentifully manured their land strive to get back
their old lots, and the Commune respects their claims so far as
these are consistent with the new arrangement; but often it happens
that it is impossible to conciliate private rights and Communal
interests, and in such cases the former are sacrificed in a way
that would not be tolerated by men of Anglo-Saxon race. This
leads, however, to no serious consequences. The peasants are
accustomed to work together in this way, to make concessions for
the Communal welfare, and to bow unreservedly to the will of the
Mir. I know of many instances where the peasants have set at
defiance the authority of the police, of the provincial governor,
and of the central Government itself, but I have never heard of any
instance where the will of the Mir was openly opposed by one of its
members.
In the preceding pages I have repeatedly spoken about "shares of
the Communal land." To prevent misconception I must explain
carefully what this expression means. A share does not mean simply
a plot or parcel of land; on the contrary, it always contains at
least four, and may contain a large number of distinct plots. We
have here a new point of difference between the Russian village and
the villages of Western Europe.
Communal land in Russia is of three kinds: the land on which the
village is built, the arable land, and the meadow or hay-field, if
the village is fortunate enough to possess one. On the first of
these each family possesses a house and garden, which are the
hereditary property of the family, and are never affected by the
periodical redistributions. The other two kinds are both subject
to redistribution, but on somewhat different principles.
The whole of the Communal arable land is first of all divided into
three fields, to suit the triennial rotation of crops already
described, and each field is divided into a number of long narrow
strips--corresponding to the number of male members in the Commune--
as nearly as possible equal to each other in area and quality.
Sometimes it is necessary to divide the field into several
portions, according to the quality of the soil, and then to
subdivide each of these portions into the requisite number of
strips. Thus in all cases every household possesses at least one
strip in each field; and in those cases where subdivision is
necessary, every household possesses a strip in each of the
portions into which the field is subdivided. It often happens,
therefore, that the strips are very narrow, and the portions
belonging to each family very numerous. Strips six feet wide are
by no means rare. In 124 villages of the province of Moscow,
regarding which I have special information, they varied in width
from 3 to 45 yards, with an average of 11 yards. Of these narrow
strips a household may possess as many as thirty in a single field!
The complicated process of division and subdivision is accomplished
by the peasants themselves, with the aid of simple measuring-rods,
and the accuracy of the result is truly marvellous.
The meadow, which is reserved for the production of hay, is divided
into the same number of shares as the arable land. There, however,
the division and distribution take place, not at irregular
intervals, but annually. Every year, on a day fixed by the
Assembly, the villagers proceed in a body to this part of their
property, and divide it into the requisite number of portions.
Lots are then cast, and each family at once mows the portion
allotted to it. In some Communes the meadow is mown by all the
peasants in common, and the hay afterwards distributed by lot among
the families; but this system is by no means so frequently used.
As the whole of the Communal land thus resembles to some extent a
big farm, it is necessary to make certain rules concerning
cultivation. A family may sow what it likes in the land allotted
to it, but all families must at least conform to the accepted
system of rotation. In like manner, a family cannot begin the
autumn ploughing before the appointed time, because it would
thereby interfere with the rights of the other families, who use
the fallow field as pasturage.
It is not a little strange that this primitive system of land
tenure should have succeeded in living into the twentieth century,
and still more remarkable that the institution of which it forms an
essential part should be regarded by many intelligent people as one
of the great institutions of the future, and almost as a panacea
for social and political evils. The explanation of these facts
will form the subject of the next chapter.
CHAPTER IX
HOW THE COMMUNE HAS BEEN PRESERVED, AND WHAT IT IS TO EFFECT IN THE
FUTURE
Sweeping Reforms after the Crimean War--Protest Against the Laissez
Faire Principle--Fear of the Proletariat--English and Russian
Methods of Legislation Contrasted--Sanguine Expectations--Evil
Consequences of the Communal System--The Commune of the Future--
Proletariat of the Towns--The Present State of Things Merely
Temporary.
The reader is probably aware that immediately after the Crimean War
Russia was subjected to a series of sweeping reforms, including the
emancipation of the serfs and the creation of a new system of local
self-government, and he may naturally wonder how it came to pass
that a curious, primitive institution like the rural Commune
succeeded in weathering the bureaucratic hurricane. This strange
phenomena I now proceed to explain, partly because the subject is
in itself interesting, and partly because I hope thereby to throw
some light on the peculiar intellectual condition of the Russian
educated classes.
When it became evident, in 1857, that the serfs were about to be
emancipated, it was at first pretty generally supposed that the
rural Commune would be entirely abolished, or at least radically
modified. At that time many Russians were enthusiastic,
indiscriminate admirers of English institutions, and believed, in
common with the orthodox school of political economists, that
England had acquired her commercial and industrial superiority by
adopting the principle of individual liberty and unrestricted
competition, or, as French writers term it, the "laissez faire"
principle. This principle is plainly inconsistent with the rural
Commune, which compels the peasantry to possess land, prevents an
enterprising peasant from acquiring the land of his less
enterprising neighbours, and places very considerable restrictions
on the freedom of action of the individual members. Accordingly it
was assumed that the rural Commune, being inconsistent with the
modern spirit of progress, would find no place in the new regime of
liberty which was about to be inaugurated.
No sooner had these ideas been announced in the Press than they
called forth strenuous protests. In the crowd of protesters were
two well-defined groups. On the one hand there were the so-called
Slavophils, a small band of patriotic, highly educated Moscovites,
who were strongly disposed to admire everything specifically
Russian, and who habitually refused to bow the knee to the wisdom
of Western Europe. These gentlemen, in a special organ which they
had recently founded, pointed out to their countrymen that the
Commune was a venerable and peculiarly Russian institution, which
had mitigated in the past the baneful influence of serfage, and
would certainly in the future confer inestimable benefits on the
emancipated peasantry. The other group was animated by a very
different spirit. They had no sympathy with national
peculiarities, and no reverence for hoary antiquity. That the
Commune was specifically Russian or Slavonic, and a remnant of
primitive times, was in their eyes anything but a recommendation in
its favour. Cosmopolitan in their tendencies, and absolutely free
from all archaeological sentimentality, they regarded the
institution from the purely utilitarian point of view. They
agreed, however, with the Slavophils in thinking that its
preservation would have a beneficial influence on the material and
moral welfare of the peasantry.
For the sake of convenience it is necessary to designate this
latter group by some definite name, but I confess I have some
difficulty in making a choice. I do not wish to call these
gentlemen Socialists, because many people habitually and
involuntarily attach a stigma to the word, and believe that all to
whom the term is applied must be first-cousins to the petroleuses.
To avoid misconceptions of this kind, it will be well to designate
them simply by the organ which most ably represented their views,
and to call them the adherents of The Contemporary.
The Slavophils and the adherents of The Contemporary, though
differing widely from each other in many respects, had the same
immediate object in view, and accordingly worked together. With
great ingenuity they contended that the Communal system of land
tenure had much greater advantages, and was attended with much
fewer inconveniences, than people generally supposed. But they did
not confine themselves to these immediate practical advantages,
which had very little interest for the general reader. The writers
in The Contemporary explained that the importance of the rural
Commune lies, not in its actual condition, but in its capabilities
of development, and they drew, with prophetic eye, most attractive
pictures of the happy rural Commune of the future. Let me give
here, as an illustration, one of these prophetic descriptions:
"Thanks to the spread of primary and technical education the
peasants have become well acquainted with the science of
agriculture, and are always ready to undertake in common the
necessary improvements. They no longer exhaust the soil by
exporting the grain, but sell merely certain technical products
containing no mineral ingredients. For this purpose the Communes
possess distilleries, starch-works, and the like, and the soil
thereby retains its original fertility. The scarcity induced by
the natural increase of the population is counteracted by improved
methods of cultivation. If the Chinese, who know nothing of
natural science, have succeeded by purely empirical methods in
perfecting agriculture to such an extent that a whole family can
support itself on a few square yards of land, what may not the
European do with the help of chemistry, botanical physiology, and
the other natural sciences?"
Coming back from the possibilities of the future to the actualities
of the present, these ingenious and eloquent writers pointed out
that in the rural Commune, Russia possessed a sure preventive
against the greatest evil of West-European social organisation, the
Proletariat. Here the Slavophils could strike in with their
favourite refrain about the rotten social condition of Western
Europe; and their temporary allies, though they habitually scoffed
at the Slavophil jeremiads, had no reason for the moment to
contradict them. Very soon the Proletariat became, for the
educated classes, a species of bugbear, and the reading public were
converted to the doctrine that the Communal institutions should be
preserved as a means of excluding the monster from Russia.
This fear of what is vaguely termed the Proletariat is still
frequently to be met with in Russia, and I have often taken pains
to discover precisely what is meant by the term. I cannot,
however, say that my efforts have been completely successful. The
monster seems to be as vague and shadowy as the awful forms which
Milton placed at the gate of the infernal regions. At one moment
he seems to be simply our old enemy Pauperism, but when we approach
a little nearer we find that he expands to colossal dimensions, so
as to include all who do not possess inalienable landed property.
In short, he turns out to be, on examination, as vague and
undefinable as a good bugbear ought to be; and this vagueness
contributed probably not a little to his success.
The influence which the idea of the Proletariat exercised on the
public mind and on the legislation at the time of the Emancipation
is a very notable fact, and well worthy of attention, because it
helps to illustrate a point of difference between Russians and
Englishmen.
Englishmen are, as a rule, too much occupied with the multifarious
concerns of the present to look much ahead into the distant future.
We profess, indeed, to regard with horror the maxim, Apres nous le
deluge! and we should probably annihilate with our virtuous
indignation any one who should boldly profess the principle. And
yet we often act almost as if we were really partisans of that
heartless creed. When called upon to consider the interests of the
future generations, we declared that "sufficient unto the day is
the evil thereof," and stigmatise as visionaries and dreamers all
who seek to withdraw our attention from the present. A modern
Cassandra who confidently predicts the near exhaustion of our coal-
fields, or graphically describes a crushing national disaster that
must some day overtake us, may attract some public attention; but
when we learn that the misfortune is not to take place in our time,
we placidly remark that future generations must take care of
themselves, and that we cannot reasonably be expected to bear their
burdens. When we are obliged to legislate, we proceed in a
cautious, tentative way, and are quite satisfied with any homely,
simple remedies that common sense and experience may suggest,
without taking the trouble to inquire whether the remedy adopted is
in accordance with scientific theories. In short, there is a
certain truth in those "famous prophetick pictures" spoken of by
Stillingfleet, which "represent the fate of England by a mole, a
creature blind and busy, continually working under ground."
In Russia we find the opposite extreme. There reformers have been
trained, not in the arena of practical politics, but in the school
of political speculation. As soon, therefore, as they begin to
examine any simple matter with a view to legislation, it at once
becomes a "question," and flies up into the region of political and
social science. Whilst we have been groping along an unexplored
path, the Russians have--at least in recent times--been constantly
mapping out, with the help of foreign experience, the country that
lay before them, and advancing with gigantic strides according to
the newest political theories. Men trained in this way cannot rest
satisfied with homely remedies which merely alleviate the evils of
the moment. They wish to "tear up evil by the roots," and to
legislate for future generations as well as for themselves.
This tendency was peculiarly strong at the time of the
Emancipation. The educated classes were profoundly convinced that
the system of Nicholas I. had been a mistake, and that a new and
brighter era was about to dawn upon the country. Everything had to
be reformed. The whole social and political edifice had to be
reconstructed on entirely new principles.
Let us imagine the position of a man who, having no practical
acquaintance with building, suddenly finds himself called upon to
construct a large house, containing all the newest appliances for
convenience and comfort. What will his first step be? Probably he
will proceed at once to study the latest authorities on
architecture and construction, and when he has mastered the general
principles he will come down gradually to the details. This is
precisely what the Russians did when they found themselves called
upon to reconstruct the political and social edifice. They eagerly
consulted the most recent English, French, and German writers on
social and political science, and here it was that they made the
acquaintance of the Proletariat.
People who read books of travel without ever leaving their own
country are very apt to acquire exaggerated notions regarding the
hardships and dangers of uncivilised life. They read about savage
tribes, daring robbers, ferocious wild beasts, poisonous snakes,
deadly fevers, and the like; and they cannot but wonder how a human
being can exist for a week among such dangers. But if they happen
thereafter to visit the countries described, they discover to their
surprise that, though the descriptions may not have been
exaggerated, life under such conditions is much easier than they
supposed. Now the Russians who read about the Proletariat were
very much like the people who remain at home and devour books of
travel. They gained exaggerated notions, and learned to fear the
Proletariat much more than we do, who habitually live in the midst
of it. Of course it is quite possible that their view of the
subject is truer than ours, and that we may some day, like the
people who live tranquilly on the slopes of a volcano, be rudely
awakened from our fancied security. But this is an entirely
different question. I am at present not endeavouring to justify
our habitual callousness with regard to social dangers, but simply
seeking to explain why the Russians, who have little or no
practical acquaintance with pauperism, should have taken such
elaborate precautions against it.
But how can the preservation of the Communal institutions lead to
this "consummation devoutly to be wished," and how far are the
precautions likely to be successful?
Those who have studied the mysteries of social science have
generally come to the conclusion that the Proletariat has been
formed chiefly by the expropriation of the peasantry or small land-
holders, and that its formation might be prevented, or at least
retarded, by any system of legislation which would secure the
possession of land for the peasants and prevent them from being
uprooted from the soil. Now it must be admitted that the Russian
Communal system is admirably adapted for this purpose. About one-
half of the arable land has been reserved for the peasantry, and
cannot be encroached on by the great landowners or the capitalists,
and every adult peasant, roughly speaking, has a right to a share
of this land. When I have said that the peasantry compose about
five-sixths of the population, and that it is extremely difficult
for a peasant to sever his connection with the rural Commune, it
will be at once evident that, if the theories of social
philosophers are correct, and if the sanguine expectations
entertained in many quarters regarding the permanence of the
present Communal institutions are destined to be realised, there is
little or no danger of a numerous Proletariat being formed, and the
Russians are justified in maintaining, as they often do, that they
have successfully solved one of the most important and most
difficult of social problems.
But is there any reasonable chance of these sanguine expectations
being realised?
This is, doubtless, a most complicated and difficult question, but
it cannot be shirked. However sceptical we may be with regard to
social panaceas of all sorts, we cannot dismiss with a few
hackneyed phrases a gigantic experiment in social science involving
the material and moral welfare of many millions of human beings.
On the other hand, I do not wish to exhaust the reader's patience
by a long series of multifarious details and conflicting arguments.
What I propose to do, therefore, is to state in a few words the
conclusions at which I have arrived, after a careful study of the
question in all its bearings, and to indicate in a general way how
I have arrived at these conclusions.
If Russia were content to remain a purely agricultural country of
the Sleepy Hollow type, and if her Government were to devote all
its energies to maintaining economic and social stagnation, the
rural Commune might perhaps prevent the formation of a large
Proletariat in the future, as it has tended to prevent it for
centuries in the past. The periodical redistributions of the
Communal land would secure to every family a portion of the soil,
and when the population became too dense, the evils arising from
inordinate subdivision of the land might be obviated by a carefully
regulated system of emigration to the outlying, thinly populated
provinces. All this sounds very well in theory, but experience is
proving that it cannot be carried out in practice. In Russia, as
in Western Europe, the struggle for life, even among the
conservative agricultural classes, is becoming yearly more and more
intense, and is producing both the desire and the necessity for
greater freedom of individual character and effort, so that each
man may make his way in the world according to the amount of his
intelligence, energy, spirit of enterprise, and tenacity of
purpose. Whatever institutions tend to fetter the individual and
maintain a dead level of mediocrity have little chance of
subsisting for any great length of time, and it must be admitted
that among such institutions the rural Commune in its present form
occupies a prominent place. All its members must possess, in
principle if not always in practice, an equal share of the soil and
must practice the same methods of agriculture, and when a certain
inequality has been created by individual effort it is in great
measure wiped out by a redistribution of the Communal land.
Now, I am well aware that in practice the injustice and
inconveniences of the system, being always tempered and corrected
by ingenious compromises suggested by long experience, are not
nearly so great as the mere theorist might naturally suppose; but
they are, I believe, quite great enough to prevent the permanent
maintenance of the institution, and already there are ominous
indications of the coming change, as I shall explain more fully
when I come to deal with the consequences of serf-emancipation. On
the other hand there is no danger of a sudden, general abolition of
the old system. Though the law now permits the transition from
Communal to personal hereditary tenure, even the progressive
enterprising peasants are slow to avail themselves of the
permission; and the reason I once heard given for this conservative
tendency is worth recording. A well-to-do peasant who had been in
the habit of manuring his land better than his neighbours, and who
was, consequently, a loser by the existing system, said to me: "Of
course I want to keep the allotment I have got. But if the land is
never again to be divided my grandchildren may be beggars. We must
not sin against those who are to come after us." This unexpected
reply gave me food for reflection. Surely those muzhiks who are so
often accused of being brutally indifferent to moral obligations
must have peculiar deep-rooted moral conceptions of their own which
exercise a great influence on their daily life. A man who
hesitates to sin against his grandchildren still unborn, though his
conceptions of the meum and the tuum in the present may be
occasionally a little confused, must possess somewhere deep down in
his nature a secret fund of moral feeling of a very respectable
kind. Even among the educated classes in Russia the way of looking
at these matters is very different from ours. We should naturally
feel inclined to applaud, encourage, and assist the peasants who
show energy and initiative, and who try to rise above their
fellows. To the Russian this seems at once inexpedient and
immoral. The success of the few, he explains, is always obtained
at the expense of the many, and generally by means which the severe
moralist cannot approve of. The rich peasants, for example, have
gained their fortune and influence by demoralising and exploiting
their weaker brethren, by committing all manner of illegalities,
and by bribing the local authorities. Hence they are styled
Miroyedy (Commune-devourers) or Kulaki (fists), or something
equally uncomplimentary. Once this view is adopted, it follows
logically that the Communal institutions, in so far as they form a
barrier to the activity of such persons, ought to be carefully
preserved. This idea underlies nearly all the arguments in favour
of the Commune, and explains why they are so popular. Russians of
all classes have, in fact, a leaning towards socialistic notions,
and very little sympathy with our belief in individual initiative
and unrestricted competition.
Even if it be admitted that the Commune may effectually prevent the
formation of an agricultural Proletariat, the question is thereby
only half answered. Russia aspires to become a great industrial
and commercial country, and accordingly her town population is
rapidly augmenting. We have still to consider, then, how the
Commune affects the Proletariat of the towns. In Western Europe
the great centres of industry have uprooted from the soil and
collected in the towns a great part of the rural population. Those
who yielded to this attractive influence severed all connection
with their native villages, became unfit for field labour, and were
transformed into artisans or factory-workers. In Russia this
transformation could not easily take place. The peasant might work
during the greater part of his life in the towns, but he did not
thereby sever his connection with his native village. He remained,
whether he desired it or not, a member of the Commune, possessing a
share of the Communal land, and liable for a share of the Communal
burdens. During his residence in the town his wife and family
remained at home, and thither he himself sooner or later returned.
In this way a class of hybrids--half-peasants, half-artisans--has
been created, and the formation of a town Proletariat has been
greatly retarded.
The existence of this hybrid class is commonly cited as a
beneficent result of the Communal institutions. The artisans and
factory labourers, it is said, have thus always a home to which
they can retire when thrown out of work or overtaken by old age,
and their children are brought up in the country, instead of being
reared among the debilitating influences of overcrowded cities.
Every common labourer has, in short, by this ingenious contrivance,
some small capital and a country residence.
In the present transitional state of Russian society this peculiar
arrangement is at once natural and convenient, but amidst its
advantages it has many serious defects. The unnatural separation
of the artisan from his wife and family leads to very undesirable
results, well known to all who are familiar with the details of
peasant life in the northern provinces. And whatever its
advantages and defects may be, it cannot be permanently retained.
At the present time native industry is still in its infancy.
Protected by the tariff from foreign competition, and too few in
number to produce a strong competition among themselves, the
existing factories can give to their owners a large revenue without
any strenuous exertion. Manufacturers can therefore allow
themselves many little liberties, which would be quite inadmissible
if the price of manufactured goods were lowered by brisk
competition. Ask a Lancashire manufacturer if he could allow a
large portion of his workers to go yearly to Cornwall or Caithness
to mow a field of hay or reap a few acres of wheat or oats! And if
Russia is to make great industrial progress, the manufacturers of
Moscow, Lodz, Ivanovo, and Shui will some day be as hard pressed as
are those of Bradford and Manchester. The invariable tendency of
modern industry, and the secret of its progress, is the ever-
increasing division of labour; and how can this principle be
applied if the artisans insist on remaining agriculturists?
The interests of agriculture, too, are opposed to the old system.
Agriculture cannot be expected to make progress, or even to be
tolerably productive, if it is left in great measure to women and
children. At present it is not desirable that the link which binds
the factory-worker or artisan with the village should be at once
severed, for in the neighbourhood of the large factories there is
often no proper accommodation for the families of the workers, and
agriculture, as at present practised, can be carried on
successfully though the Head of the Household happens to be absent.
But the system must be regarded as simply temporary, and the
disruption of large families--a phenomenon of which I have already
spoken--renders its application more and more difficult.
CHAPTER X
FINNISH AND TARTAR VILLAGES
A Finnish Tribe--Finnish Villages--Various Stages of Russification--
Finnish Women--Finnish Religions--Method of "Laying" Ghosts--
Curious Mixture of Christianity and Paganism--Conversion of the
Finns--A Tartar Village--A Russian Peasant's Conception of
Mahometanism--A Mahometan's View of Christianity--Propaganda--The
Russian Colonist--Migrations of Peoples During the Dark Ages.
When talking one day with a landed proprietor who lived near
Ivanofka, I accidentally discovered that in a district at some
distance to the northeast there were certain villages the
inhabitants of which did not understand Russian, and habitually
used a peculiar language of their own. With an illogical hastiness
worthy of a genuine ethnologist, I at once assumed that these must
be the remnants of some aboriginal race.
"Des aborigenes!" I exclaimed, unable to recall the Russian
equivalent for the term, and knowing that my friend understood
French. "Doubtless the remains of some ancient race who formerly
held the country, and are now rapidly disappearing. Have you any
Aborigines Protection Society in this part of the world?"
My friend had evidently great difficulty in imagining what an
Aborigines Protection Society could be, and promptly assured me
that there was nothing of the kind in Russia. On being told that
such a society might render valuable services by protecting the
weaker against the stronger race, and collecting important
materials for the new science of Social Embryology, he looked
thoroughly mystified. As to the new science, he had never heard of
it, and as to protection, he thought that the inhabitants of the
villages in question were quite capable of protecting themselves.
"I could invent," he added, with a malicious smile, "a society for
the protection of ALL peasants, but I am quite sure that the
authorities would not allow me to carry out my idea."
My ethnological curiosity was thoroughly aroused, and I endeavoured
to awaken a similar feeling in my friend by hinting that we had at
hand a promising field for discoveries which might immortalise the
fortunate explorers; but my efforts were in vain. The old
gentleman was a portly, indolent man, of phlegmatic temperament,
who thought more of comfort than of immortality in the terrestrial
sense of the term. To my proposal that we should start at once on
an exploring expedition, he replied calmly that the distance was
considerable, that the roads were muddy, and that there was nothing
to be learned. The villages in question were very like other
villages, and their inhabitants lived, to all intents and purposes,
in the same way as their Russian neighbours. If they had any
secret peculiarities they would certainly not divulge them to a
stranger, for they were notoriously silent, gloomy, morose, and
uncommunicative. Everything that was known about them, my friend
assured me, might be communicated in a few words. They belonged to
a Finnish tribe called Korelli, and had been transported to their
present settlements in comparatively recent times. In answer to my
questions as to how, when, and by whom they had been transported
thither my informant replied that it had been the work of Ivan the
Terrible.
Though I knew at that time little of Russian history, I suspected
that the last assertion was invented on the spur of the moment, in
order to satisfy my troublesome curiosity, and accordingly I
determined not to accept it without verification. The result
showed how careful the traveller should be in accepting the
testimony of "intelligent, well-informed natives." On further
investigation I discovered, not only that the story about Ivan the
Terrible was a pure invention--whether of my friend or of the
popular imagination, which always uses heroic names as pegs on
which to hang traditions, I know not--but also that my first theory
was correct. These Finnish peasants turned out to be a remnant of
the aborigines, or at least of the oldest known inhabitants of the
district. Men of the same race, but bearing different tribal
names, such as Finns, Korelli, Tcheremiss, Tchuvash, Mordva,
Votyaks, Permyaks, Zyryanye, Voguls, are to be found in
considerable numbers all over the northern provinces, from the Gulf
of Bothnia to Western Siberia, as well as in the provinces
bordering the Middle Volga as far south as Penza, Simbirsk, and
Tamboff.* The Russian peasants, who now compose the great mass of
the population, are the intruders.
* The semi-official "Statesman's Handbook for Russia," published in
1896, enumerates fourteen different tribes, with an aggregate of
about 4,650,000 souls, but these numbers must not be regarded as
having any pretensions to accuracy. The best authorities differ
widely in their estimates.
I had long taken a deep interest in what learned Germans call the
Volkerwanderung--that is to say, the migrations of peoples during
the gradual dissolution of the Roman Empire, and it had often
occurred to me that the most approved authorities, who had expended
an infinite amount of learning on the subject, had not always taken
the trouble to investigate the nature of the process. It is not
enough to know that a race or tribe extended its dominions or
changed its geographical position. We ought at the same time to
inquire whether it expelled, exterminated, or absorbed the former
inhabitants, and how the expulsion, extermination, or absorption
was effected. Now of these three processes, absorption may have
been more frequent than is commonly supposed, and it seemed to me
that in Northern Russia this process might be conveniently studied.
A thousand years ago the whole of Northern Russia was peopled by
Finnish pagan tribes, and at the present day the greater part of it
is occupied by peasants who speak the language of Moscow, profess
the Orthodox faith, present in their physiognomy no striking
peculiarities, and appear to the superficial observer pure
Russians. And we have no reason to suppose that the former
inhabitants were expelled or exterminated, or that they gradually
died out from contact with the civilisation and vices of a higher
race. History records no wholesale Finnish migrations like that of
the Kalmyks, and no war of extermination; and statistics prove that
among the remnants of those primitive races the population
increases as rapidly as among the Russian peasantry.* From these
facts I concluded that the Finnish aborigines had been simply
absorbed, or rather, were being absorbed, by the Slavonic
intruders.
* This latter statement is made on the authority of Popoff
("Zyryanye i zyryanski krai," Moscow, 1874) and Tcheremshanski
("Opisanie Orenburgskoi Gubernii," Ufa, 1859).
This conclusion has since been confirmed by observation. During my
wanderings in these northern provinces I have found villages in
every stage of Russification. In one, everything seemed thoroughly
Finnish: the inhabitants had a reddish-olive skin, very high cheek-
bones, obliquely set eyes, and a peculiar costume; none of the
women, and very few of the men, could understand Russian, and any
Russian who visited the place was regarded as a foreigner. In a
second, there were already some Russian inhabitants; the others had
lost something of their pure Finnish type, many of the men had
discarded the old costume and spoke Russian fluently, and a Russian
visitor was no longer shunned. In a third, the Finnish type was
still further weakened: all the men spoke Russian, and nearly all
the women understood it; the old male costume had entirely
disappeared, and the old female costume was rapidly following it;
while intermarriage with the Russian population was no longer rare.
In a fourth, intermarriage had almost completely done its work, and
the old Finnish element could be detected merely in certain
peculiarities of physiognomy and pronunciation.*
* One of the most common peculiarities of pronunciation is the
substitution of the sound of ts for that of tch, which I found
almost universal over a large area.
The process of Russification may be likewise observed in the manner
of building the houses and in the methods of farming, which show
plainly that the Finnish races did not obtain rudimentary
civilisation from the Slavs. Whence, then, was it derived? Was it
obtained from some other race, or is it indigenous? These are
questions which I have no means of answering.
A Positivist poet--or if that be a contradiction in terms, let us
say a Positivist who wrote verses--once composed an appeal to the
fair sex, beginning with the words:
"Pourquoi, O femmes, restez-vous en arriere?"
The question might have been addressed to the women in these
Finnish villages. Like their sisters in France, they are much more
conservative than the men, and oppose much more stubbornly the
Russian influence. On the other hand, like women in general, when
they do begin to change, they change more rapidly. This is seen
especially in the matter of costume. The men adopt the Russian
costume very gradually; the women adopt it at once. As soon as a
single woman gets a gaudy Russian dress, every other woman in the
village feels envious and impatient till she has done likewise. I
remember once visiting a Mordva village when this critical point
had been reached, and a very characteristic incident occurred. In
the preceding villages through which I had passed I had tried in
vain to buy a female costume, and I again made the attempt. This
time the result was very different. A few minutes after I had
expressed my wish to purchase a costume, the house in which I was
sitting was besieged by a great crowd of women, holding in their
hands articles of wearing apparel. In order to make a selection I
went out into the crowd, but the desire to find a purchaser was so
general and so ardent that I was regularly mobbed. The women,
shouting "Kupi! kupi!" ("Buy! buy!"), and struggling with each
other to get near me, were so importunate that I had at last to
take refuge in the house, to prevent my own costume from being torn
to shreds. But even there I was not safe, for the women followed
at my heels, and a considerable amount of good-natured violence had
to be employed to expel the intruders.
It is especially interesting to observe the transformation of
nationality in the sphere of religious conceptions. The Finns
remained pagans long after the Russians had become Christians, but
at the present time the whole population, from the eastern boundary
of Finland proper to the Ural Mountains, are officially described
as members of the Greek Orthodox Church. The manner in which this
change of religion was effected is well worthy of attention.
The old religion of the Finnish tribes, if we may judge from the
fragments which still remain, had, like the people themselves, a
thoroughly practical, prosaic character. Their theology consisted
not of abstract dogmas, but merely of simple prescriptions for the
ensuring of material welfare. Even at the present day, in the
districts not completely Russified, their prayers are plain,
unadorned requests for a good harvest, plenty of cattle, and the
like, and are expressed in a tone of childlike familiarity that
sounds strange in our ears. They make no attempt to veil their
desires with mystic solemnity, but ask, in simple, straightforward
fashion, that God should make the barley ripen and the cow calve
successfully, that He should prevent their horses from being
stolen, and that he should help them to gain money to pay their
taxes.
Their religious ceremonies have, so far as I have been able to
discover, no hidden mystical signification, and are for the most
part rather magical rites for averting the influence of malicious
spirits, or freeing themselves from the unwelcome visits of their
departed relatives. For this latter purpose many even of those who
are officially Christians proceed at stated seasons to the
graveyards and place an abundant supply of cooked food on the
graves of their relations who have recently died, requesting the
departed to accept this meal, and not to return to their old homes,
where their presence is no longer desired. Though more of the food
is eaten at night by the village dogs than by the famished spirits,
the custom is believed to have a powerful influence in preventing
the dead from wandering about at night and frightening the living.
If it be true, as I am inclined to believe, that tombstones were
originally used for keeping the dead in their graves, then it must
be admitted that in the matter of "laying" ghosts the Finns have
shown themselves much more humane than other races. It may,
however, be suggested that in the original home of the Finns--"le
berceau de la race," as French ethnologists say--stones could not
easily be procured, and that the custom of feeding the dead was
adopted as a pis aller. The decision of the question must be left
to those who know where the original home of the Finns was.
As the Russian peasantry, knowing little or nothing of theology,
and placing implicit confidence in rites and ceremonies, did not
differ very widely from the pagan Finns in the matter of religious
conceptions, the friendly contact of the two races naturally led to
a curious blending of the two religions. The Russians adopted many
customs from the Finns, and the Finns adopted still more from the
Russians. When Yumala and the other Finnish deities did not do as
they were desired, their worshippers naturally applied for
protection or assistance to the Madonna and the "Russian God." If
their own traditional magic rites did not suffice to ward off evil
influences, they naturally tried the effect of crossing themselves,
as the Russians do in moments of danger. All this may seem strange
to us who have been taught from our earliest years that religion is
something quite different from spells, charms, and incantations,
and that of all the various religions in the world one alone is
true, all the others being false. But we must remember that the
Finns have had a very different education. They do not distinguish
religion from magic rites, and they have never been taught that
other religions are less true than their own. For them the best
religion is the one which contains the most potent spells, and they
see no reason why less powerful religions should not be blended
therewith. Their deities are not jealous gods, and do not insist
on having a monopoly of devotion; and in any case they cannot do
much injury to those who have placed themselves under the
protection of a more powerful divinity.
This simple-minded eclecticism often produces a singular mixture of
Christianity and paganism. Thus, for instance, at the harvest
festivals, Tchuvash peasants have been known to pray first to their
own deities, and then to St. Nicholas, the miracle-worker, who is
the favourite saint of the Russian peasantry. Such dual worship is
sometimes even recommended by the Yomzi--a class of men who
correspond to the medicine-men among the Red Indians--and the
prayers are on these occasions couched in the most familiar terms.
Here is a specimen given by a Russian who has specially studied the
language and customs of this interesting people:* "Look here, O
Nicholas-god! Perhaps my neighbour, little Michael, has been
slandering me to you, or perhaps he will do so. If he does, don't
believe him. I have done him no ill, and wish him none. He is a
worthless boaster and a babbler. He does not really honour you,
and merely plays the hypocrite. But I honour you from my heart;
and, behold, I place a taper before you!" Sometimes incidents
occur which display a still more curious blending of the two
religions. Thus a Tcheremiss, on one occasion, in consequence of a
serious illness, sacrificed a young foal to our Lady of Kazan!
* Mr. Zolotnitski, "Tchuvasko-russki slovar," p. 167.
Though the Finnish beliefs affected to some extent the Russian
peasantry, the Russian faith ultimately prevailed. This can be
explained without taking into consideration the inherent
superiority of Christianity over all forms of paganism. The Finns
had no organised priesthood, and consequently never offered a
systematic opposition to the new faith; the Russians, on the
contrary, had a regular hierarchy in close alliance with the civil
administration. In the principal villages Christian churches were
built, and some of the police-officers vied with the ecclesiastical
officials in the work of making converts. At the same time there
were other influences tending in the same direction. If a Russian
practised Finnish superstitions he exposed himself to disagreeable
consequences of a temporal kind; if, on the contrary, a Finn
adopted the Christian religion, the temporal consequences that
could result were all advantageous to him.
Many of the Finns gradually became Christians almost unconsciously.
The ecclesiastical authorities were extremely moderate in their
demands. They insisted on no religious knowledge, and merely
demanded that the converts should be baptised. The converts,
failing to understand the spiritual significance of the ceremony,
commonly offered no resistance, so long as the immersion was
performed in summer. So little repugnance, indeed, did they feel,
that on some occasions, when a small reward was given to those who
consented, some of the new converts wished the ceremony to be
repeated several times. The chief objection to receiving the
Christian faith lay in the long and severe fasts imposed by the
Greek Orthodox Church; but this difficulty was overcome by assuming
that they need not be strictly observed. At first, in some
districts, it was popularly believed that the Icons informed the
Russian priests against those who did not fast as the Church
prescribed; but experience gradually exploded this theory. Some of
the more prudent converts, however, to prevent all possible tale-
telling, took the precaution of turning the face of the Icon to the
wall when prohibited meats were about to be eaten!
This gradual conversion of the Finnish tribes, effected without any
intellectual revolution in the minds of the converts, had very
important temporal consequences. Community of faith led to
intermarriage, and intermarriage led rapidly to the blending of the
two races.
If we compare a Finnish village in any stage of Russification with
a Tartar village, of which the inhabitants are Mahometans, we
cannot fail to be struck by the contrast. In the latter, though
there may be many Russians, there is no blending of the two races.
Between them religion has raised an impassable barrier. There are
many villages in the eastern and north-eastern provinces of
European Russia which have been for generations half Tartar and
half Russian, and the amalgamation of the two nationalities has not
yet begun. Near the one end stands the Christian church, and near
the other stands the little metchet, or Mahometan house of prayer.
The whole village forms one Commune, with one Village Assembly and
one Village Elder; but, socially, it is composed of two distinct
communities, each possessing its peculiar customs and peculiar mode
of life. The Tartar may learn Russian, but he does not on that
account become Russianised.
It must not, however, be supposed that the two races are imbued
with fanatical hatred towards each other. On the contrary, they
live in perfect good-fellowship, elect as Village Elder sometimes a
Russian and sometimes a Tartar, and discuss the Communal affairs in
the Village Assembly without reference to religious matters. I
know one village where the good-fellowship went even a step
farther: the Christians determined to repair their church, and the
Mahometans helped them to transport wood for the purpose! All this
tends to show that under a tolerably good Government, which does
not favour one race at the expense of the other, Mahometan Tartars
and Christian Slavs can live peaceably together.
The absence of fanaticism and of that proselytising zeal which is
one of the most prolific sources of religious hatred, is to be
explained by the peculiar religious conceptions of these peasants.
In their minds religion and nationality are so closely allied as to
be almost identical. The Russian is, as it were, by nature a
Christian, and the Tartar a Mahometan; and it never occurs to any
one in these villages to disturb the appointed order of nature. On
this subject I had once an interesting conversation with a Russian
peasant who had been for some time living among Tartars. In reply
to my question as to what kind of people the Tartars were, he
replied laconically, "Nitchevo"--that is to say, "nothing in
particular"; and on being pressed for a more definite expression of
opinion, he admitted that they were very good people indeed.
"And what kind of faith have they?" I continued.
"A good enough faith," was the prompt reply.
"Is it better than the faith of the Molokanye?" The Molokanye are
Russian sectarians--closely resembling Scotch Presbyterians--of
whom I shall have more to say in the sequel.
"Of course it is better than the Molokan faith."
"Indeed!" I exclaimed, endeavouring to conceal my astonishment at
this strange judgment. "Are the Molokanye, then, very bad people?"
"Not at all. The Molokanye are good and honest."
"Why, then, do you think their faith is so much worse than that of
the Mahometans?"
"How shall I tell you?" The peasant here paused as if to collect
his thoughts, and then proceeded slowly, "The Tartars, you see,
received their faith from God as they received the colour of their
skins, but the Molokanye are Russians who have invented a faith out
of their own heads!"
This singular answer scarcely requires a commentary. As it would
be absurd to try to make Tartars change the colour of their skins,
so it would be absurd to try to make them change their religion.
Besides this, such an attempt would be an unjustifiable
interference with the designs of Providence, for, in the peasant's
opinion, God gave Mahometanism to the Tartars just as he gave the
Orthodox faith to the Russians.
The ecclesiastical authorities do not formally adopt this strange
theory, but they generally act in accordance with it. There is
little official propaganda among the Mahometan subjects of the
Tsar, and it is well that it is so, for an energetic propaganda
would lead merely to the stirring up of any latent hostility which
may exist deep down in the nature of the two races, and it would
not make any real converts. The Tartars cannot unconsciously
imbibe Christianity as the Finns have done. Their religion is not
a rude, simple paganism without theology in the scholastic sense of
the term, but a monotheism as exclusive as Christianity itself.
Enter into conversation with an intelligent man who has no higher
religious belief than a rude sort of paganism, and you may, if you
know him well and make a judicious use of your knowledge, easily
interest him in the touching story of Christ's life and teaching.
And in these unsophisticated natures there is but one step from
interest and sympathy to conversion.
Try the same method with a Mussulman, and you will soon find that
all your efforts are fruitless. He has already a theology and a
prophet of his own, and sees no reason why he should exchange them
for those which you have to offer. Perhaps he will show you more
or less openly that he pities your ignorance and wonders that you
have not been able to ADVANCE from Christianity to Mahometanism.
In his opinion--I am supposing that he is a man of education--Moses
and Christ were great prophets in their day, and consequently he is
accustomed to respect their memory; but he is profoundly convinced
that however appropriate they were for their own times, they have
been entirely superseded by Mahomet, precisely as we believe that
Judaism was superseded by Christianity. Proud of his superior
knowledge, he regards you as a benighted polytheist, and may
perhaps tell you that the Orthodox Christians with whom he comes in
contact have three Gods and a host of lesser deities called saints,
that they pray to idols called Icons, and that they keep their holy
days by getting drunk. In vain you endeavour to explain to him
that saints and Icons are not essential parts of Christianity, and
that habits of intoxication have no religious significance. On
these points he may make concessions to you, but the doctrine of
the Trinity remains for him a fatal stumbling-block. "You
Christians," he will say, "once had a great prophet called Jisous,
who is mentioned with respect in the Koran, but you falsified your
sacred writings and took to worshipping him, and now you declare
that he is the equal of Allah. Far from us be such blasphemy!
There is but one God, and Mahomet is His prophet."
A worthy Christian missionary, who had laboured long and zealously
among a Mussulman population, once called me sharply to account for
having expressed the opinion that Mahometans are very rarely
converted to Christianity. When I brought him down from the region
of vague general statements and insisted on knowing how many cases
he had met with in his own personal experience during sixteen years
of missionary work, he was constrained to admit that he had know
only one: and when I pressed him farther as to the disinterested
sincerity of the convert in question his reply was not altogether
satisfactory.
The policy of religious non-intervention has not always been
practised by the Government. Soon after the conquest of the
Khanate of Kazan in the sixteenth century, the Tsars of Muscovy
attempted to convert their new subjects from Mahometanism to
Christianity. The means employed were partly spiritual and partly
administrative, but the police-officers seem to have played a more
important part than the clergy. In this way a certain number of
Tartars were baptised; but the authorities were obliged to admit
that the new converts "shamelessly retain many horrid Tartar
customs, and neither hold nor know the Christian faith." When
spiritual exhortations failed, the Government ordered its officials
to "pacify, imprison, put in irons, and thereby UNTEACH and
frighten from the Tartar faith those who, though baptised, do not
obey the admonitions of the Metropolitan." These energetic
measures proved as ineffectual as the spiritual exhortations; and
Catherine II. adopted a new method, highly characteristic of her
system of administration. The new converts--who, be it remembered,
were unable to read and write--were ordered by Imperial ukaz to
sign a written promise to the effect that "they would completely
forsake their infidel errors, and, avoiding all intercourse with
unbelievers, would hold firmly and unwaveringly the Christian faith
and its dogmas"*--of which latter, we may add, they had not the
slightest knowledge. The childlike faith in the magical efficacy
of stamped paper here displayed was not justified. The so-called
"baptised Tartars" are at the present time as far from being
Christians as they were in the sixteenth century. They cannot
openly profess Mahometanism, because men who have been once
formally admitted into the National Church cannot leave it without
exposing themselves to the severe pains and penalties of the
criminal code, but they strongly object to be Christianised.
* "Ukaz Kazanskoi dukhovnoi Konsistorii." Anno 1778.
On this subject I have found a remarkable admission in a
semiofficial article, published as recently as 1872.* "It is a
fact worthy of attention," says the writer, "that a long series of
evident apostasies coincides with the beginning of measures to
confirm the converts in the Christian faith. There must be,
therefore, some collateral cause producing those cases of apostasy
precisely at the moment when the contrary might be expected."
There is a delightful naivete in this way of stating the fact. The
mysterious cause vaguely indicated is not difficult to find. So
long as the Government demanded merely that the supposed converts
should be inscribed as Christians in the official registers, there
was no official apostasy; but as soon as active measures began to
be taken "to confirm the converts," a spirit of hostility and
fanaticism appeared among the Mussulman population, and made those
who were inscribed as Christians resist the propaganda.
* "Zhurnal Ministerstva Narodnago Prosveshtcheniya." June, 1872.
It may safely be said that Christians are impervious to Islam, and
genuine Mussulmans impervious to Christianity; but between the two
there are certain tribes, or fractions of tribes, which present a
promising field for missionary enterprise. In this field the
Tartars show much more zeal than the Russians, and possess certain
advantages over their rivals. The tribes of Northeastern Russia
learn Tartar much more easily than Russian, and their geographical
position and modes of life bring them in contact with Russians much
less than with Tartars. The consequence is that whole villages of
Tcheremiss and Votiaks, officially inscribed as belonging to the
Greek Orthodox Church, have openly declared themselves Mahometans;
and some of the more remarkable conversions have been commemorated
by popular songs, which are sung by young and old. Against this
propaganda the Orthodox ecclesiastical authorities do little or
nothing. Though the criminal code contains severe enactments
against those who fall away from the Orthodox Church, and still
more against those who produce apostasy,* the enactments are rarely
put in force. Both clergy and laity in the Russian Church are, as
a rule, very tolerant where no political questions are involved.
The parish priest pays attention to apostasy only when it
diminishes his annual revenues, and this can be easily avoided by
the apostate's paying a small yearly sum. If this precaution be
taken, whole villages may be converted to Islam without the higher
ecclesiastical authorities knowing anything of the matter.
* A person convicted of converting a Christian to Islamism is
sentenced, according to the criminal code ( 184), to the loss of?
all civil rights, and to imprisonment with hard labour for a term
varying from eight to ten years.
Whether the barrier that separates Christians and Mussulmans in
Russia, as elsewhere, will ever be broken down by education, I do
not know; but I may remark that hitherto the spread of education
among the Tartars has tended rather to imbue them with fanaticism.
If we remember that theological education always produces
intolerance, and that Tartar education is almost exclusively
theological, we shall not be surprised to find that a Tartar's
religious fanaticism is generally in direct proportion to the
amount of his intellectual culture. The unlettered Tartar,
unspoiled by learning falsely so called, and knowing merely enough
of his religion to perform the customary ordinances prescribed by
the Prophet, is peaceable, kindly, and hospitable towards all men;
but the learned Tartar, who has been taught that the Christian is a
kiafir (infidel) and a mushrik (polytheist), odious in the sight of
Allah, and already condemned to eternal punishment, is as
intolerant and fanatical as the most bigoted Roman Catholic or
Calvinist. Such fanatics are occasionally to be met with in the
eastern provinces, but they are few in number, and have little
influence on the masses. From my own experience I can testify that
during the whole course of my wanderings I have nowhere received
more kindness and hospitality than among the uneducated Mussulman
Bashkirs. Even here, however, Islam opposes a strong barrier to
Russification.
Though no such barrier existed among the pagan Finnish tribes, the
work of Russification among them is still, as I have already
indicated, far from complete. Not only whole villages, but even
many entire districts, are still very little affected by Russian
influence. This is to be explained partly by geographical
conditions. In regions which have a poor soil, and are intersected
by no navigable river, there are few or no Russian settlers, and
consequently the Finns have there preserved intact their language
and customs; whilst in those districts which present more
inducements to colonisation, the Russian population is more
numerous, and the Finns less conservative. It must, however, be
admitted that geographical conditions do not completely explain the
facts. The various tribes, even when placed in the same
conditions, are not equally susceptible to foreign influence. The
Mordva, for instance, are infinitely less conservative than the
Tchuvash. This I have often noticed, and my impression has been
confirmed by men who have had more opportunities of observation.
For the present we must attribute this to some occult ethnological
peculiarity, but future investigations may some day supply a more
satisfactory explanation. Already I have obtained some facts which
appear to throw light on the subject. The Tchuvash have certain
customs which seem to indicate that they were formerly, if not
avowed Mahometans, at least under the influence of Islam, whilst we
have no reason to suppose that the Mordva ever passed through that
school.
The absence of religious fanaticism greatly facilitated Russian
colonisation in these northern regions, and the essentially
peaceful disposition of the Russian peasantry tended in the same
direction. The Russian peasant is admirably fitted for the work of
peaceful agricultural colonisation. Among uncivilised tribes he is
good-natured, long-suffering, conciliatory, capable of bearing
extreme hardships, and endowed with a marvellous power of adapting
himself to circumstances. The haughty consciousness of personal
and national superiority habitually displayed by Englishmen of all
ranks when they are brought in contact with races which they look
upon as lower in the scale of humanity than themselves, is entirely
foreign to his character. He has no desire to rule, and no wish to
make the natives hewers of wood and drawers of water. All he
desires is a few acres of land which he and his family can
cultivate; and so long as he is allowed to enjoy these he is not
likely to molest his neighbours. Had the colonists of the Finnish
country been men of Anglo-Saxon race, they would in all probability
have taken possession of the land and reduced the natives to the
condition of agricultural labourers. The Russian colonists have
contented themselves with a humbler and less aggressive mode of
action; they have settled peaceably among the native population,
and are rapidly becoming blended with it. In many districts the
so-called Russians have perhaps more Finnish than Slavonic blood in
their veins.
But what has all this to do, it may be asked, with the
aforementioned Volkerwanderung, or migration of peoples, during the
Dark Ages? More than may at first sight appear. Some of the so-
called migrations were, I suspect, not at all migrations in the
ordinary sense of the term, but rather gradual changes, such as
those which have taken place, and are still taking place, in
Northern Russia. A thousand years ago what is now known as the
province of Yaroslavl was inhabited by Finns, and now it is
occupied by men who are commonly regarded as pure Slays. But it
would be an utter mistake to suppose that the Finns of this
district migrated to those more distant regions where they are now
to be found. In reality they formerly occupied, as I have said,
the whole of Northern Russia, and in the province of Yaroslavl they
have been transformed by Slav infiltration. In Central Europe the
Slavs may be said in a certain sense to have retreated, for in
former times they occupied the whole of Northern Germany as far as
the Elbe. But what does the word "retreat" mean in this case? It
means probably that the Slays were gradually Teutonised, and then
absorbed by the Teutonic race. Some tribes, it is true, swept over
a part of Europe in genuine nomadic fashion, and endeavoured
perhaps to expel or exterminate the actual possessors of the soil.
This kind of migration may likewise be studied in Russia. But I
must leave the subject till I come to speak of the southern
provinces.
CHAPTER XI
LORD NOVGOROD THE GREAT
Departure from Ivanofka and Arrival at Novgorod--The Eastern Half
of the Town--The Kremlin--An Old Legend--The Armed Men of Rus--The
Northmen--Popular Liberty in Novgorod--The Prince and the Popular
Assembly--Civil Dissensions and Faction-fights-- The Commercial
Republic Conquered by the Muscovite Tsars--Ivan the Terrible--
Present Condition of the Town--Provincial Society--Card-playing--
Periodicals--"Eternal Stillness."
Country life in Russia is pleasant enough in summer or in winter,
but between summer and winter there is an intermediate period of
several weeks when the rain and mud transform a country-house into
something very like a prison. To escape this durance vile I
determined in the month of October to leave Ivanofka, and chose as
my headquarters for the next few months the town of Novgorod--the
old town of that name, not to be confounded with Nizhni Novgorod--
i.e., Lower Novgorod, on the Volga--where the great annual fair is
held.
For this choice there were several reasons. I did not wish to go
to St. Petersburg or Moscow, because I foresaw that in either of
those cities my studies would certainly be interrupted. In a
quiet, sleepy provincial town I should have much more chance of
coming in contact with people who could not speak fluently any
West-European languages, and much better opportunities for studying
native life and local administration. Of the provincial capitals,
Novgorod was the nearest, and more interesting than most of its
rivals; for it has had a curious history, much older than that of
St. Petersburg or even of Moscow, and some traces of its former
greatness are still visible. Though now a town of third-rate
importance--a mere shadow of its former self--it still contains
about 21,000 inhabitants, and is the administrative centre of the
large province in which it is situated.
About eighty miles before reaching St. Petersburg the Moscow
railway crosses the Volkhof, a rapid, muddy river which connects
Lake Ilmen with Lake Ladoga. At the point of intersection I got on
board a small steamer and sailed up stream towards Lake Ilmen for
about fifty miles.* The journey was tedious, for the country was
flat and monotonous, and the steamer, though it puffed and snorted
inordinately, did not make more than nine knots. Towards sunset
Novgorod appeared on the horizon. Seen thus at a distance in the
soft twilight, it seemed decidedly picturesque. On the east bank
lay the greater part of the town, the sky line of which was
agreeably broken by the green roofs and pear-shaped cupolas of many
churches. On the opposite bank rose the Kremlin. Spanning the
river was a long, venerable stone bridge, half hidden by a
temporary wooden one, which was doing duty for the older structure
while the latter was being repaired. A cynical fellow-passenger
assured me that the temporary structure was destined to become
permanent, because it yielded a comfortable revenue to certain
officials, but this sinister prediction has not been verified.
* The journey would now be made by rail, but the branch line which
runs near the bank of the river had not been constructed at that
time.
That part of Novgorod which lies on the eastern bank of the river,
and in which I took up my abode for several months, contains
nothing that is worthy of special mention. As is the case in most
Russian towns, the streets are straight, wide, and ill-paved, and
all run parallel or at right angles to each other. At the end of
the bridge is a spacious market-place, flanked on one side by the
Town-house. Near the other side stand the houses of the Governor
and of the chief military authority of the district. The only
other buildings of note are the numerous churches, which are mostly
small, and offer nothing that is likely to interest the student of
architecture. Altogether this part of the town is unquestionably
commonplace. The learned archaeologist may detect in it some
traces of the distant past, but the ordinary traveller will find
little to arrest his attention.
If now we cross over to the other side of the river, we are at once
confronted by something which very few Russian towns possess--a
kremlin, or citadel. This is a large and slightly-elevated
enclosure, surrounded by high brick walls, and in part by the
remains of a moat. Before the days of heavy artillery these walls
must have presented a formidable barrier to any besieging force,
but they have long ceased to have any military significance, and
are now nothing more than an historical monument. Passing through
the gateway which faces the bridge, we find ourselves in a large
open space. To the right stands the cathedral--a small, much-
venerated church, which can make no pretensions to architectural
beauty--and an irregular group of buildings containing the
consistory and the residence of the Archbishop. To the left is a
long symmetrical range of buildings containing the Government
offices and the law courts. Midway between this and the cathedral,
in the centre of the great open space, stands a colossal monument,
composed of a massive circular stone pedestal and an enormous
globe, on and around which cluster a number of emblematic and
historical figures. This curious monument, which has at least the
merit of being original in design, was erected in 1862, in
commemoration of Russia's thousandth birthday, and is supposed to
represent the history of Russia in general and of Novgorod in
particular during the last thousand years. It was placed here
because Novgorod is the oldest of Russian towns, and because
somewhere in the surrounding country occurred the incident which is
commonly recognised as the foundation of the Russian Empire. The
incident in question is thus described in the oldest chronicle:
"At that time, as the southern Slavonians paid tribute to the
Kozars, so the Novgorodian Slavonians suffered from the attacks of
the Variags. For some time the Variags exacted tribute from the
Novgorodian Slavonians and the neighbouring Finns; then the
conquered tribes, by uniting their forces, drove out the
foreigners. But among the Slavonians arose strong internal
dissensions; the clans rose against each other. Then, for the
creation of order and safety, they resolved to call in princes from
a foreign land. In the year 862 Slavonic legates went away beyond
the sea to the Variag tribe called Rus, and said, 'Our land is
great and fruitful, but there is no order in it; come and reign and
rule over us.' Three brothers accepted the invitation, and
appeared with their armed followers. The eldest of these, Rurik,
settled in Novgorod; the second, Sineus, at Byelo-ozero; and the
third, Truvor, in Isborsk. From them our land is called Rus.
After two years the brothers of Rurik died. He alone began to rule
over the Novgorod district, and confided to his men the
administration of the principal towns."
This simple legend has given rise to a vast amount of learned
controversy, and historical investigators have fought valiantly
with each other over the important question, Who were those armed
men of Rus? For a long time the commonly received opinion was that
they were Normans from Scandinavia. The Slavophils accepted the
legend literally in this sense, and constructed upon it an
ingenious theory of Russian history. The nations of the West, they
said, were conquered by invaders, who seized the country and
created the feudal system for their own benefit; hence the history
of Western Europe is a long tale of bloody struggles between
conquerors and conquered, and at the present day the old enmity
still lives in the political rivalry of the different social
classes. The Russo-Slavonians, on the contrary, were not
conquered, but voluntarily invited a foreign prince to come and
rule over them! Hence the whole social and political development
of Russia has been essentially peaceful, and the Russian people
know nothing of social castes or feudalism. Though this theory
afforded some nourishment for patriotic self-satisfaction, it
displeased extreme patriots, who did not like the idea that order
was first established in their country by men of Teutonic race.
These preferred to adopt the theory that Rurik and his companions
were Slavonians from the shores of the Baltic.
Though I devoted to the study of this question more time and labour
than perhaps the subject deserved, I have no intention of inviting
the reader to follow me through the tedious controversy. Suffice
it to say that, after careful consideration, and with all due
deference to recent historians, I am inclined to adopt the old
theory, and to regard the Normans of Scandinavia as in a certain
sense the founders of the Russian Empire. We know from other
sources that during the ninth century there was a great exodus from
Scandinavia. Greedy of booty, and fired with the spirit of
adventure, the Northmen, in their light, open boats, swept along
the coasts of Germany, France, Spain, Greece, and Asia Minor,
pillaging the towns and villages near the sea, and entering into
the heart of the country by means of the rivers. At first they
were mere marauders, and showed everywhere such ferocity and
cruelty that they came to be regarded as something akin to plagues
and famines, and the faithful added a new petition to the Litany,
"From the wrath and malice of the Normans, O Lord, deliver us!"
But towards the middle of the century the movement changed its
character. The raids became military invasions, and the invaders
sought to conquer the lands which they had formerly plundered, "ut
acquirant sibi spoliando regna quibus possent vivere pace
perpetua." The chiefs embraced Christianity, married the daughters
or sisters of the reigning princes, and obtained the conquered
territories as feudal grants. Thus arose Norman principalities in
the Low Countries, in France, in Italy, and in Sicily; and the
Northmen, rapidly blending with the native population, soon showed
as much political talent as they had formerly shown reckless and
destructive valour.
It would have been strange indeed if these adventurers, who
succeeded in reaching Asia Minor and the coasts of North America,
should have overlooked Russia, which lay, as it were, at their very
doors. The Volkhof, flowing through Novgorod, formed part of a
great waterway which afforded almost uninterrupted water-
communication between the Baltic and the Black Sea; and we know
that some time afterwards the Scandinavians used this route in
their journeys to Constantinople. The change which the
Scandinavian movement underwent elsewhere is clearly indicated by
the Russian chronicles: first, the Variags came as collectors of
tribute, and raised so much popular opposition that they were
expelled, and then they came as rulers, and settled in the country.
Whether they really came on invitation may be doubted, but that
they adopted the language, religion, and customs of the native
population does not militate against the assertion that they were
Normans. On the contrary, we have here rather an additional
confirmation, for elsewhere the Normans did likewise. In the North
of France they adopted almost at once the French language and
religion, and the son and successor of the famous Rollo was
sometimes reproached with being more French than Norman.*
*Strinnholm, "Die Vikingerzuge" (Hamburg, 1839), I., p. 135.
Though it is difficult to decide how far the legend is literally
true, there can be no possible doubt that the event which it more
or less accurately describes had an important influence on Russian
history. From that time dates the rapid expansion of the Russo-
Slavonians--a movement that is still going on at the present day.
To the north, the east, and the south new principalities were
formed and governed by men who all claimed to be descendants of
Rurik, and down to the end of the sixteenth century no Russian
outside of this great family ever attempted to establish
independent sovereignty.
For six centuries after the so-called invitation of Rurik the city
on the Volkhof had a strange, checkered history. Rapidly it
conquered the neighbouring Finnish tribes, and grew into a powerful
independent state, with a territory extending to the Gulf of
Finland, and northwards to the White Sea. At the same time its
commercial importance increased, and it became an outpost of the
Hanseatic League. In this work the descendants of Rurik played an
important part, but they were always kept in strict subordination
to the popular will. Political freedom kept pace with commercial
prosperity. What means Rurik employed for establishing and
preserving order we know not, but the chronicles show that his
successors in Novgorod possessed merely such authority as was
freely granted them by the people. The supreme power resided, not
in the prince, but in the assembly of the citizens called together
in the market-place by the sound of the great bell. This assembly
made laws for the prince as well as for the people, entered into
alliances with foreign powers, declared war, and concluded peace,
imposed taxes, raised troops, and not only elected the magistrates,
but also judged and deposed them when it thought fit. The prince
was little more than the hired commander of the troops and the
president of the judicial administration. When entering on his
functions he had to take a solemn oath that he would faithfully
observe the ancient laws and usages, and if he failed to fulfil his
promise he was sure to be summarily deposed and expelled. The
people had an old rhymed proverb, "Koli khud knyaz, tak v gryaz!"
"If the prince is bad, into the mud with him!"), and they
habitually acted according to it. So unpleasant, indeed, was the
task of ruling those sturdy, stiff-necked burghers, that some
princes refused to undertake it, and others, having tried it for a
time, voluntarily laid down their authority and departed. But
these frequent depositions and abdications--as many as thirty took
place in the course of a single century--did not permanently
disturb the existing order of things. The descendants of Rurik
were numerous, and there were always plenty of candidates for the
vacant post. The municipal republic continued to grow in strength
and in riches, and during the thirteenth and fourteenth centuries
it proudly styled itself "Lord Novgorod the Great" (Gospodin
Velilki Novgorod).
"Then came a change, as all things human change." To the east
arose the principality of Moscow--not an old, rich municipal
republic, but a young, vigorous State, ruled by a line of crafty,
energetic, ambitious, and unscrupulous princes of the Rurik stock,
who were freeing the country from the Tartar yoke and gradually
annexing by fair means and foul the neighbouring principalities to
their own dominions. At the same time, and in a similar manner,
the Lithuanian Princes to the westward united various small
principalities and formed a large independent State. Thus Novgorod
found itself in a critical position. Under a strong Government it
might have held its own against these rivals and successfully
maintained its independence, but its strength was already
undermined by internal dissensions. Political liberty had led to
anarchy. Again and again on that great open space where the
national monument now stands, and in the market-place on the other
side of the river, scenes of disorder and bloodshed took place, and
more than once on the bridge battles were fought by contending
factions. Sometimes it was a contest between rival families, and
sometimes a struggle between the municipal aristocracy, who sought
to monopolise the political power, and the common people, who
wished to have a large share in the administration. A State thus
divided against itself could not long resist the aggressive
tendencies of powerful neighbours. Artful diplomacy could but
postpone the evil day, and it required no great political foresight
to predict that sooner or later Novgorod must become Lithuanian or
Muscovite. The great families inclined to Lithuania, but the
popular party and the clergy, disliking Roman Catholicism, looked
to Moscow for assistance, and the Grand Princes of Muscovy
ultimately won the prize.
The barbarous way in which the Grand Princes effected the
annexation shows how thoroughly they had imbibed the spirit of
Tartar statesmanship. Thousands of families were transported to
Moscow, and Muscovite families put in their places; and when, in
spite of this, the old spirit revived, Ivan the Terrible determined
to apply the method of physical extermination which he had found so
effectual in breaking the power of his own nobles. Advancing with
a large army, which met with no resistance, he devastated the
country with fire and sword, and during a residence of five weeks
in the town he put the inhabitants to death with a ruthless
ferocity which has perhaps never been surpassed even by Oriental
despots. If those old walls could speak they would have many a
horrible tale to tell. Enough has been preserved in the chronicles
to give us some idea of this awful time. Monks and priests were
subjected to the Tartar punishment called pravezh, which consisted
in tying the victim to a stake, and flogging him daily until a
certain sum of money was paid for his release. The merchants and
officials were tortured with fire, and then thrown from the bridge
with their wives and children into the river. Lest any of them
should escape by swimming, boatfuls of soldiers despatched those
who were not killed by the fall. At the present day there is a
curious bubbling immediately below the bridge, which prevents the
water from freezing in winter, and according to popular belief this
is caused by the spirits of the terrible Tsar's victims. Of those
who were murdered in the villages there is no record, but in the
town alone no less than 60,000 human beings are said to have been
butchered--an awful hecatomb on the altar of national unity and
autocratic power!
This tragic scene, which occurred in 1570, closes the history of
Novgorod as an independent State. Its real independence had long
since ceased to exist, and now the last spark of the old spirit was
extinguished. The Tsars could not suffer even a shadow of
political independence to exist within their dominions.
In the old days, when many Hanseatic merchants annually visited the
city, and when the market-place, the bridge, and the Kremlin were
often the scene of violent political struggles, Novgorod must have
been an interesting place to live in; but now its glory has
departed, and in respect of social resources it is not even a
first-rate provincial town. Kief, Kharkof, and other towns which
are situated at a greater distance from the capital, in districts
fertile enough to induce the nobles to farm their own land, are in
their way little semi-independent centres of civilisation. They
contain a theatre, a library, two or three clubs, and large houses
belonging to rich landed proprietors, who spend the summer on their
estates and come into town for the winter months. These
proprietors, together with the resident officials, form a numerous
society, and during the winter, dinner-parties, balls, and other
social gatherings are by no means infrequent. In Novgorod the
society is much more limited. It does not, like Kief, Kharkof, and
Kazan, possess a university, and it contains no houses belonging to
wealthy nobles. The few proprietors of the province who live on
their estates, and are rich enough to spend part of the year in
town, prefer St. Petersburg for their winter residence. The
society, therefore, is composed exclusively of the officials and of
the officers who happen to be quartered in the town or the
immediate vicinity.
Of all the people whose acquaintance I made at Novgorod, I can
recall only two men who did not occupy some official position,
civil or military. One of these was a retired doctor, who was
attempting to farm on scientific principles, and who, I believe,
soon afterwards gave up the attempt and migrated elsewhere. The
other was a Polish bishop who had been compromised in the
insurrection of 1863, and was condemned to live here under police
supervision. This latter could scarcely be said to belong to the
society of the place; though he sometimes appeared at the
unceremonious weekly receptions given by the Governor, and was
invariably treated by all present with marked respect, he could not
but feel that he was in a false position, and he was rarely or
never seen in other houses.
The official circle of a town like Novgorod is sure to contain a
good many people of average education and agreeable manners, but it
is sure to be neither brilliant nor interesting. Though it is
constantly undergoing a gradual renovation by the received system
of frequently transferring officials from one town to another, it
preserves faithfully, in spite of the new blood which it thus
receives, its essentially languid character. When a new official
arrives he exchanges visits with all the notables, and for a few
days he produces quite a sensation in the little community. If he
appears at social gatherings he is much talked to, and if he does
not appear he is much talked about. His former history is
repeatedly narrated, and his various merits and defects assiduously
discussed.
If he is married, and has brought his wife with him, the field of
comment and discussion is very much enlarged. The first time that
Madame appears in society she is the "cynosure of neighbouring
eyes." Her features, her complexion, her hair, her dress, and her
jewellery are carefully noted and criticised. Perhaps she has
brought with her, from the capital or from abroad, some dresses of
the newest fashion. As soon as this is discovered she at once
becomes an object of special curiosity to the ladies, and of
envious jealousy to those who regard as a personal grievance the
presence of a toilette finer or more fashionable than their own.
Her demeanour, too, is very carefully observed. If she is friendly
and affable in manner, she is patronised; if she is distant and
reserved, she is condemned as proud and pretentious. In either
case she is pretty sure to form a close intimacy with some one of
the older female residents, and for a few weeks the two ladies are
inseparable, till some incautious word or act disturbs the new-born
friendship, and the devoted friends become bitter enemies.
Voluntarily or involuntarily the husbands get mixed up in the
quarrel. Highly undesirable qualities are discovered in the
characters of all parties concerned, and are made the subject of
unfriendly comment. Then the feud subsides, and some new feud of a
similar kind comes to occupy the public attention. Mrs. A. wonders
how her friends Mr. and Mrs. B. can afford to lose considerable
sums every evening at cards, and suspects that they are getting
into debt or starving themselves and their children; in her humble
opinion they would do well to give fewer supper-parties, and to
refrain from poisoning their guests. The bosom friend to whom this
is related retails it directly or indirectly to Mrs. B., and Mrs.
B. naturally retaliates. Here is a new quarrel, which for some
time affords material for conversation.
When there is no quarrel, there is sure to be a bit of scandal
afloat. Though Russian provincial society is not at all prudish,
and leans rather to the side of extreme leniency, it cannot
entirely overlook les convenances. Madame C. has always a large
number of male admirers, and to this there can be no reasonable
objection so long as her husband does not complain, but she really
parades her preference for Mr. X. at balls and parties a little too
conspicuously. Then there is Madame D., with the big dreamy eyes.
How can she remain in the place after her husband was killed in a
duel by a brother officer? Ostensibly the cause of the quarrel was
a trifling incident at the card-table, but every one knows that in
reality she was the cause of the deadly encounter. And so on, and
so on. In the absence of graver interests society naturally
bestows inordinate attention on the private affairs of its members;
and quarrelling, backbiting, and scandal-mongery help indolent
people to kill the time that hangs heavily on their hands.
Potent as these instruments are, they are not sufficient to kill
all the leisure hours. In the forenoons the gentlemen are occupied
with their official duties, whilst the ladies go out shopping or
pay visits, and devote any time that remains to their household
duties and their children; but the day's work is over about four
o'clock, and the long evening remains to be filled up. The siesta
may dispose of an hour or an hour and a half, but about seven
o'clock some definite occupation has to be found. As it is
impossible to devote the whole evening to discussing the ordinary
news of the day, recourse is almost invariably had to card-playing,
which is indulged in to an extent that we had no conception of in
England until Bridge was imported. Hour after hour the Russians of
both sexes will sit in a hot room, filled with a constantly-renewed
cloud of tobacco-smoke--in the production of which most of the
ladies take part--and silently play "Preference," "Yarolash," or
Bridge. Those who for some reason are obliged to be alone can
amuse themselves with "Patience," in which no partner is required.
In the other games the stakes are commonly very small, but the
sittings are often continued so long that a player may win or lose
two or three pounds sterling. It is no unusual thing for gentlemen
to play for eight or nine hours at a time. At the weekly club
dinners, before coffee had been served, nearly all present used to
rush off impatiently to the card-room, and sit there placidly from
five o'clock in the afternoon till one or two o'clock in the
morning! When I asked my friends why they devoted so much time to
this unprofitable occupation, they always gave me pretty much the
same answer: "What are we to do? We have been reading or writing
official papers all day, and in the evening we like to have a
little relaxation. When we come together we have very little to
talk about, for we have all read the daily papers and nothing more.
The best thing we can do is to sit down at the card-table, where we
can spend our time pleasantly, without the necessity of talking."
In addition to the daily papers, some people read the monthly
periodicals--big, thick volumes, containing several serious
articles on historical and social subjects, sections of one or two
novels, satirical sketches, and a long review of home and foreign
politics on the model of those in the Revue des Deux Mondes.
Several of these periodicals are very ably conducted, and offer to
their readers a large amount of valuable information; but I have
noticed that the leaves of the more serious part often remain
uncut. The translation of a sensation novel by the latest French
or English favourite finds many more readers than an article by an
historian or a political economist. As to books, they seem to be
very little read, for during all the time I lived in Novgorod I
never discovered a bookseller's shop, and when I required books I
had to get them sent from St. Petersburg. The local
administration, it is true, conceived the idea of forming a museum
and circulating library, but in my time the project was never
realised. Of all the magnificent projects that are formed in
Russia, only a very small percentage come into existence, and these
are too often very short-lived. The Russians have learned
theoretically what are the wants of the most advanced civilisation,
and are ever ready to rush into the grand schemes which their
theoretical knowledge suggests; but very few of them really and
permanently feel these wants, and consequently the institutions
artificially formed to satisfy them very soon languish and die. In
the provincial towns the shops for the sale of gastronomic
delicacies spring up and flourish, whilst shops for the sale of
intellectual food are rarely to be met with.
About the beginning of December the ordinary monotony of Novgorod
life is a little relieved by the annual Provincial Assembly, which
sits daily for two or three weeks and discusses the economic wants
of the province.* During this time a good many lauded proprietors,
who habitually live on their estates or in St. Petersburg, collect
in the town, and enliven a little the ordinary society. But as
Christmas approaches the deputies disperse, and again the town
becomes enshrouded in that "eternal stillness" (vetchnaya tishina)
which a native poet has declared to be the essential characteristic
of Russian provincial life.
* Of these Assemblies I shall have more to say when I come to
describe the local self-government.
CHAPTER XII
THE TOWNS AND THE MERCANTILE CLASSES
General Character of Russian Towns--Scarcity of Towns in Russia--
Why the Urban Element in the Population is so Small--History of
Russian Municipal Institutions--Unsuccessful Efforts to Create a
Tiers-etat--Merchants, Burghers, and Artisans--Town Council--A Rich
Merchant--His House--His Love of Ostentation--His Conception of
Aristocracy--Official Decorations--Ignorance and Dishonesty of the
Commercial Classes--Symptoms of Change.
Those who wish to enjoy the illusions produced by scene painting
and stage decorations should never go behind the scenes. In like
manner he who wishes to preserve the delusion that Russian
provincial towns are picturesque should never enter them, but
content himself with viewing them from a distance.
However imposing they may look when seen from the outside, they
will be found on closer inspection, with very few exceptions, to be
little more than villages in disguise. If they have not a
positively rustic, they have at least a suburban, appearance. The
streets are straight and wide, and are either miserably paved or
not paved at all. Trottoirs are not considered indispensable. The
houses are built of wood or brick, generally one-storied, and
separated from each other by spacious yards. Many of them do not
condescend to turn their facades to the street. The general
impression produced is that the majority of the burghers have come
from the country, and have brought their country-houses with them.
There are few or no shops with merchandise tastefully arranged in
the window to tempt the passer-by. If you wish to make purchases
you must go to the Gostinny Dvor,* or Bazaar, which consists of
long, symmetrical rows of low-roofed, dimly-lighted stores, with a
colonnade in front. This is the place where merchants most do
congregate, but it presents nothing of that bustle and activity
which we are accustomed to associate with commercial life. The
shopkeepers stand at their doors or loiter about in the immediate
vicinity waiting for customers. From the scarcity of these latter
I should say that when sales are effected the profits must be
enormous.
* These words mean literally the Guests' Court or Yard. The
Ghosti--a word which is etymologically the same as our "host" and
"guest"--were originally the merchants who traded with other towns
or other countries.
In the other parts of the town the air of solitude and languor is
still more conspicuous. In the great square, or by the side of the
promenade--if the town is fortunate enough to have one--cows or
horses may be seen grazing tranquilly, without being at all
conscious of the incongruity of their position. And, indeed, it
would be strange if they had any such consciousness, for it does
not exist in the minds either of the police or of the inhabitants.
At night the streets may be lighted merely with a few oil-lamps,
which do little more than render the darkness visible, so that
cautious citizens returning home late often provide themselves with
lanterns. As late as the sixties the learned historian, Pogodin,
then a town-councillor of Moscow, opposed the lighting of the city
with gas on the ground that those who chose to go out at night
should carry their lamps with them. The objection was overruled,
and Moscow is now fairly well lit, but the provincial towns are
still far from being on the same level. Some retain their old
primitive arrangements, while others enjoy the luxury of electric
lighting.
The scarcity of large towns in Russia is not less remarkable than
their rustic appearance. According to the last census (1897) the
number of towns, officially so-called, is 1,321, but about three-
fifths of them have under 5,000 inhabitants; only 104 have over
25,000, and only 19 over 100,000. These figures indicate plainly
that the urban element of the population is relatively small, and
it is declared by the official statisticians to be only 14 per
cent., as against 72 per cent. in Great Britain, but it is now
increasing rapidly. When the first edition of this work was
published, in 1877, European Russia in the narrower sense of the
term--excluding Finland, the Baltic Provinces, Lithuania, Poland,
and the Caucasus--had only 11 towns with a population of over
50,000, and now there are 34; that is to say, the number of such
towns has more than trebled. In the other portions of the country
a similar increase has taken place. The towns which have become
important industrial and commercial centres have naturally grown
most rapidly. For example, in a period of twelve years (1885-97)
the populations of Lodz, of Ekaterinoslaf, of Baku, of Yaroslavl,
and of Libau, have more than doubled. In the five largest towns of
the Empire--St. Petersburg, Moscow, Warsaw, Odessa and Lodz--the
aggregate population rose during the same twelve years from
2,423,000 to 3,590,000, or nearly 50 per cent. In ten other towns,
with populations varying from 50,000 to 282,000, the aggregate rose
from 780,000 to 1,382,000, or about 77 per cent.
That Russia should have taken so long to assimilate herself in this
respect to Western Europe is to be explained by the geographical
and political conditions. Her population was not hemmed in by
natural or artificial frontiers strong enough to restrain their
expansive tendencies. To the north, the east, and the southeast
there was a boundless expanse of fertile, uncultivated land,
offering a tempting field for emigration; and the peasantry have
ever shown themselves ready to take advantage of their
opportunities. Instead of improving their primitive system of
agriculture, which requires an enormous area and rapidly exhausts
the soil, they have always found it easier and more profitable to
emigrate and take possession of the virgin land beyond. Thus the
territory--sometimes with the aid of, and sometimes in spite of,
the Government--has constantly expanded, and has already reached
the Polar Ocean, the Pacific, and the northern offshoots of the
Himalayas. The little district around the sources of the Dnieper
has grown into a mighty empire, comprising one-seventh of the land
surface of the globe. Prolific as the Russian race is, its power
of reproduction could not keep pace with its territorial expansion,
and consequently the country is still very thinly peopled.
According to the latest census (1897) in the whole empire there are
under 130 millions of inhabitants, and the average density of
population is only about fifteen to the English square mile. Even
the most densely populated provinces, including Moscow with its
988,610 inhabitants, cannot show more than 189 to the English
square mile, whereas England has about 400. A people that has such
an abundance of land, and can support itself by agriculture, is not
naturally disposed to devote itself to industry, or to congregate
in large cities.
For many generations there were other powerful influences working
in the same direction. Of these the most important was serfage,
which was not abolished till 1861. That institution, and the
administrative system of which it formed an essential part, tended
to prevent the growth of the towns by hemming the natural movements
of the population. Peasants, for example, who learned trades, and
who ought to have drifted naturally into the burgher class, were
mostly retained by the master on his estate, where artisans of all
sorts were daily wanted, and the few who were sent to seek work in
the towns were not allowed to settle there permanently.
Thus the insignificance of the Russian towns is to be attributed
mainly to two causes. The abundance of land tended to prevent the
development of industry, and the little industry which did exist
was prevented by serfage from collecting in the towns. But this
explanation is evidently incomplete. The same causes existed
during the Middle Ages in Central Europe, and yet, in spite of
them, flourishing cities grew up and played an important part in
the social and political history of Germany. In these cities
collected traders and artisans, forming a distinct social class,
distinguished from the nobles on the one hand, and the surrounding
peasantry on the other, by peculiar occupations, peculiar aims,
peculiar intellectual physiognomy, and peculiar moral conceptions.
Why did these important towns and this burgher class not likewise
come into existence in Russia, in spite of the two preventive
causes above mentioned?
To discuss this question fully it would be necessary to enter into
certain debated points of mediaeval history. All I can do here is
to indicate what seems to me the true explanation.
In Central Europe, all through the Middle Ages, a perpetual
struggle went on between the various political factors of which
society was composed, and the important towns were in a certain
sense the products of this struggle. They were preserved and
fostered by the mutual rivalry of the Sovereign, the Feudal
Nobility, and the Church; and those who desired to live by trade or
industry settled in them in order to enjoy the protection and
immunities which they afforded. In Russia there was never any
political struggle of this kind. As soon as the Grand Princes of
Moscow, in the sixteenth century, threw off the yoke of the
Tartars, and made themselves Tsars of all Russia, their power was
irresistible and uncontested. Complete masters of the situation,
they organised the country as they thought fit. At first their
policy was favourable to the development of the towns. Perceiving
that the mercantile and industrial classes might be made a rich
source of revenue, they separated them from the peasantry, gave
them the exclusive right of trading, prevented the other classes
from competing with them, and freed them from the authority of the
landed proprietors. Had they carried out this policy in a
cautious, rational way, they might have created a rich burgher
class; but they acted with true Oriental short-sightedness, and
defeated their own purpose by imposing inordinately heavy taxes,
and treating the urban population as their serfs. The richer
merchants were forced to serve as custom-house officers--often at a
great distance from their domiciles*--and artisans were yearly
summoned to Moscow to do work for the Tsars without remuneration.
* Merchants from Yaroslavl, for instance, were sent to Astrakhan to
collect the custom-dues.
Besides this, the system of taxation was radically defective, and
the members of the local administration, who received no pay and
were practically free from control, were merciless in their
exactions. In a word, the Tsars used their power so stupidly and
so recklessly that the industrial and trading population, instead
of fleeing to the towns to secure protection, fled from them to
escape oppression. At length this emigration from the towns
assumed such dimensions that it was found necessary to prevent it
by administrative and legislative measures; and the urban
population was legally fixed in the towns as the rural population
was fixed to the soil. Those who fled were brought back as
runaways, and those who attempted flight a second time were ordered
to be flogged and transported to Siberia.*
* See the "Ulozhenie" (i.e. the laws of Alexis, father of Peter the
Great), chap. xix. 13.
With the eighteenth century began a new era in the history of the
towns and of the urban population. Peter the Great observed,
during his travels in Western Europe, that national wealth and
prosperity reposed chiefly on the enterprising, educated middle
classes, and he attributed the poverty of his own country to the
absence of this burgher element. Might not such a class be created
in Russia? Peter unhesitatingly assumed that it might, and set
himself at once to create it in a simple, straightforward way.
Foreign artisans were imported into his dominions and foreign
merchants were invited to trade with his subjects; young Russians
were sent abroad to learn the useful arts; efforts were made to
disseminate practical knowledge by the translation of foreign books
and the foundation of schools; all kinds of trade were encouraged,
and various industrial enterprises were organised. At the same
time the administration of the towns was thoroughly reorganised
after the model of the ancient free-towns of Germany. In place of
the old organisation, which was a slightly modified form of the
rural Commune, they received German municipal institutions, with
burgomasters, town councils, courts of justice, guilds for the
merchants, trade corporations (tsekhi) for the artisans, and an
endless list of instructions regarding the development of trade and
industry, the building of hospitals, sanitary precautions, the
founding of schools, the dispensation of justice, the organisation
of the police, and similar matters.
Catherine II. followed in the same track. If she did less for
trade and industry, she did more in the way of legislating and
writing grandiloquent manifestoes. In the course of her historical
studies she had learned, as she proclaims in one of her
manifestoes, that "from remotest antiquity we everywhere find the
memory of town-builders elevated to the same level as the memory of
legislators, and we see that heroes, famous for their victories,
hoped by town-building to give immortality to their names." As the
securing of immortality for her own name was her chief aim in life,
she acted in accordance with historical precedent, and created 216
towns in the short space of twenty-three years. This seems a great
work, but it did not satisfy her ambition. She was not only a
student of history, but was at the same time a warm admirer of the
fashionable political philosophy of her time. That philosophy paid
much attention to the tiers-etat, which was then acquiring in
France great political importance, and Catherine thought that as
she had created a Noblesse on the French model, she might also
create a bourgeoisie. For this purpose she modified the municipal
organisation created by her great predecessor, and granted to all
the towns an Imperial Charter. This charter remained without
essential modification until the publication of the new
Municipality Law in 1870.
The efforts of the Government to create a rich, intelligent tiers-
etat were not attended with much success. Their influence was
always more apparent in official documents than in real life. The
great mass of the population remained serfs, fixed to the soil,
whilst the nobles--that is to say, all who possessed a little
education--were required for the military and civil services.
Those who were sent abroad to learn the useful arts learned little,
and made little use of the knowledge which they acquired. On their
return to their native country they very soon fell victims to the
soporific influence of the surrounding social atmosphere. The
"town-building" had as little practical result. It was an easy
matter to create any number of towns in the official sense of the
term. To transform a village into a town, it was necessary merely
to prepare an izba, or log-house, for the district court, another
for the police-office, a third for the prison, and so on. On an
appointed day the Governor of the province arrived in the village,
collected the officials appointed to serve in the newly-constructed
or newly-arranged log-houses, ordered a simple religious ceremony
to be performed by the priest, caused a formal act to be drawn up,
and then declared the town to be "opened." All this required very
little creative effort; to create a spirit of commercial and
industrial enterprise among the population was a more difficult
matter and could not be effected by Imperial ukaz.
To animate the newly-imported municipal institutions, which had no
root in the traditions and habits of the people, was a task of
equal difficulty. In the West these institutions had been slowly
devised in the course of centuries to meet real, keenly-felt,
practical wants. In Russia they were adopted for the purpose of
creating those wants which were not yet felt. Let the reader
imagine our Board of Trade supplying the masters of fishing-smacks
with accurate charts, learned treatises on navigation, and detailed
instructions for the proper ventilation of ships' cabins, and he
will have some idea of the effect which Peter's legislation had
upon the towns. The office-bearers, elected against their will,
were hopelessly bewildered by the complicated procedure, and were
incapable of understanding the numerous ukazes which prescribed to
them their multifarious duties and threatened the most merciless
punishments for sins of omission and commission. Soon, however, it
was discovered that the threats were not nearly so dreadful as they
seemed; and accordingly those municipal authorities who were to
protect and enlighten the burghers, "forgot the fear of God and the
Tsar," and extorted so unblushingly that it was found necessary to
place them under the control of Government officials.
The chief practical result of the efforts made by Peter and
Catherine to create a bourgeoisie was that the inhabitants of the
towns were more systematically arranged in categories for the
purpose of taxation, and that the taxes were increased. All those
parts of the new administration which had no direct relation to the
fiscal interests of the Government had very little vitality in
them. The whole system had been arbitrarily imposed on the people,
and had as motive only the Imperial will. Had that motive power
been withdrawn and the burghers left to regulate their own
municipal affairs, the system would immediately have collapsed.
Rathhaus, burgomasters, guilds, aldermen, and all the other
lifeless shadows which had been called into existence by Imperial
ukaz would instantly have vanished into space. In this fact we
have one of the characteristic traits of Russian historical
development compared with that of Western Europe. In the West
monarchy had to struggle with municipal institutions to prevent
them from becoming too powerful; in Russia, it had to struggle with
them to prevent them from committing suicide or dying of inanition.
According to Catherine's legislation, which remained in force until
1870, and still exists in some of its main features, the towns were
divided into three categories: (1) Government towns (gubernskiye
goroda)--that is to say, the chief towns of provinces, or
governments (gubernii)--in which are concentrated the various
organs of provincial administration; (2) district towns (uyezdniye
goroda), in which resides the administration of the districts
(uyezdi) into which the provinces are divided; and (3)
supernumerary towns (zashtatniye goroda), which have no particular
significance in the territorial administration.
In all these the municipal organisation is the same. Leaving out
of consideration those persons who happen to reside in the towns,
but in reality belong to the Noblesse, the clergy, or the lower
ranks of officials, we may say that the town population is composed
of three groups: the merchants (kuptsi), the burghers in the
narrower sense of the term (meshtchanye), and the artisans
(tsekhoviye). These categories are not hereditary castes, like the
nobles, the clergy, and the peasantry. A noble may become a
merchant, or a man may be one year a burgher, the next year an
artisan, and the third year a merchant, if he changes his
occupation and pays the necessary dues. But the categories form,
for the time being, distinct corporations, each possessing a
peculiar organisation and peculiar privileges and obligations.
Of these three groups the first in the scale of dignity is that of
the merchants. It is chiefly recruited from the burghers and the
peasantry. Any one who wishes to engage in commerce inscribes
himself in one of the three guilds, according to the amount of his
capital and the nature of the operations in which he wishes to
embark, and as soon as he has paid the required dues he becomes
officially a merchant. As soon as he ceases to pay these dues he
ceases to be a merchant in the legal sense of the term, and returns
to the class to which he formerly belonged. There are some
families whose members have belonged to the merchant class for
several generations, and the law speaks about a certain "velvet-
book" (barkhatnaya kniga) in which their names should be inscribed,
but in reality they do not form a distinct category, and they
descend at once from their privileged position as soon as they
cease to pay the annual guild dues.
The artisans form the connecting link between the town population
and the peasantry, for peasants often enrol themselves in the
trades-corporations, or tsekhi, without severing their connection
with the rural Communes to which they belong. Each trade or
handicraft constitutes a tsekh, at the head of which stands an
elder and two assistants, elected by the members; and all the
tsekhi together form a corporation under an elected head
(remeslenny golova) assisted by a council composed of the elders of
the various tsekhi. It is the duty of this council and its
president to regulate all matters connected with the tsekhi, and to
see that the multifarious regulations regarding masters,
journeymen, and apprentices are duly observed.
The nondescript class, composed of those who are inscribed as
permanent inhabitants of the towns, but who do not belong to any
guild or tsekh, constitutes what is called the burghers in the
narrower sense of the term. Like the other two categories, they
form a separate corporation, with an elder and an administrative
bureau.
Some idea of the relative numerical strength of these three
categories may be obtained from the following figures. Thirty
years ago in European Russia the merchant class (including wives
and children) numbered about 466,000, the burghers about 4,033,000,
and the artisans about 260,000. The numbers according to the last
census are not yet available.
In 1870 the entire municipal administration was reorganised on
modern West-European principles, and the Town Council (gorodskaya
duma), which formed under the previous system the connecting link
between the old-fashioned corporations, and was composed
exclusively of members of these bodies, became a genuine
representative body composed of householders, irrespective of the
social class to which they might belong. A noble, provided he was
a house-proprietor, could become Town Councillor or Mayor, and in
this way a certain amount of vitality and a progressive spirit were
infused into the municipal administration. As a consequence of
this change the schools, hospitals, and other benevolent
institutions were much improved, the streets were kept cleaner and
somewhat better paved, and for a time it seemed as if the towns in
Russia might gradually rise to the level of those of Western
Europe. But the charm of novelty, which so often works wonders in
Russia, soon wore off. After a few years of strenuous effort the
best citizens no longer came forward as candidates, and the office-
bearers selected no longer displayed zeal and intelligence in the
discharge of their duties. In these circumstances the Government
felt called upon again to intervene. By a decree dated June 11,
1892, it introduced a new series of reforms, by which the municipal
self-government was placed more under the direction and control of
the centralised bureaucracy, and the attendance of the Town
Councillors at the periodical meetings was declared to be
obligatory, recalcitrant members being threatened with reprimands
and fines.
This last fact speaks volumes for the low vitality of the
institutions and the prevalent popular apathy with regard to
municipal affairs. Nor was the unsatisfactory state of things much
improved by the new reforms; on the contrary, the increased
interference of the regular officials tended rather to weaken the
vitality of the urban self government, and the so-called reform was
pretty generally condemned as a needlessly reactionary measure. We
have here, in fact, a case of what has often occurred in the
administrative history of the Russian Empire since the time of
Peter the Great, and to which I shall again have occasion to refer.
The central authority, finding itself incompetent to do all that is
required of it, and wishing to make a display of liberalism,
accords large concessions in the direction of local autonomy; and
when it discovers that the new institutions do not accomplish all
that was expected of them, and are not quite so subservient and
obsequious as is considered desirable, it returns in a certain
measure to the old principles of centralised bureaucracy.
The great development of trade and industry in recent years has of
course enriched the mercantile classes, and has introduced into
them a more highly educated element, drawn chiefly from the
Noblesse, which formerly eschewed such occupations; but it has not
yet affected very deeply the mode of life of those who have sprung
from the old merchant families and the peasantry. When a merchant,
contractor, or manufacturer of the old type becomes wealthy, he
builds for himself a fine house, or buys and thoroughly repairs the
house of some ruined noble, and spends money freely on parquetry
floors, large mirrors, malachite tables, grand pianos by the best
makers, and other articles of furniture made of the most costly
materials. Occasionally--especially on the occasion of a marriage
or a death in the family--he will give magnificent banquets, and
expend enormous sums on gigantic sterlets, choice sturgeons,
foreign fruits, champagne, and all manner of costly delicacies.
But this lavish, ostentatious expenditure does not affect the
ordinary current of his daily life. As you enter those gaudily
furnished rooms you can perceive at a glance that they are not for
ordinary use. You notice a rigid symmetry and an indescribable
bareness which inevitably suggest that the original arrangements of
the upholsterer have never been modified or supplemented. The
truth is that by far the greater part of the house is used only on
state occasions. The host and his family live down-stairs in
small, dirty rooms, furnished in a very different, and for them
more comfortable, style. At ordinary times the fine rooms are
closed, and the fine furniture carefully covered.
If you make a visite de politesse after an entertainment, you will
probably have some difficulty in gaining admission by the front
door. When you have knocked or rung several times, some one will
come round from the back regions and ask you what you want. Then
follows another long pause, and at last footsteps are heard
approaching from within. The bolts are drawn, the door is opened,
and you are led up to a spacious drawing-room. At the wall
opposite the windows there is sure to be a sofa, and before it an
oval table. At each end of the table, and at right angles to the
sofa, there will be a row of three arm-chairs. The other chairs
will be symmetrically arranged round the room. In a few minutes
the host will appear, in his long double-breasted black coat and
well-polished long boots. His hair is parted in the middle, and
his beard shows no trace of scissors or razor.
After the customary greetings have been exchanged, glasses of tea,
with slices of lemon and preserves, or perhaps a bottle of
champagne, are brought in by way of refreshments. The female
members of the family you must not expect to see, unless you are an
intimate friend; for the merchants still retain something of that
female seclusion which was in vogue among the upper classes before
the time of Peter the Great. The host himself will probably be an
intelligent, but totally uneducated and decidedly taciturn, man.
About the weather and the crops he may talk fluently enough, but he
will not show much inclination to go beyond these topics. You may,
perhaps, desire to converse with him on the subject with which he
is best acquainted--the trade in which he is himself engaged; but
if you make the attempt, you will certainly not gain much
information, and you may possibly meet with such an incident as
once happened to my travelling companion, a Russian gentleman who
had been commissioned by two learned societies to collect
information regarding the grain trade. When he called on a
merchant who had promised to assist him in his investigation, he
was hospitably received; but when he began to speak about the grain
trade of the district the merchant suddenly interrupted him, and
proposed to tell him a story. The story was as follows:
Once on a time a rich landed proprietor had a son, who was a
thoroughly spoilt child; and one day the boy said to his father
that he wished all the young serfs to come and sing before the door
of the house. After some attempts at dissuasion the request was
granted, and the young people assembled; but as soon as they began
to sing, the boy rushed out and drove them away.
When the merchant had told this apparently pointless story at great
length, and with much circumstantial detail, he paused a little,
poured some tea into his saucer, drank it off, and then inquired,
"Now what do you think was the reason of this strange conduct?"
My friend replied that the riddle surpassed his powers of
divination.
"Well," said the merchant, looking hard at him, with a knowing
grin, "there was no reason; and all the boy could say was, 'Go
away, go away! I've changed my mind; I've changed my mind'"
(poshli von; otkhotyel).
There was no possibility of mistaking the point of the story. My
friend took the hint and departed.
The Russian merchant's love of ostentation is of a peculiar kind--
something entirely different from English snobbery. He may delight
in gaudy reception-rooms, magnificent dinners, fast trotters,
costly furs; or he may display his riches by princely donations to
churches, monasteries, or benevolent institutions: but in all this
he never affects to be other than he really is. He habitually
wears a costume which designates plainly his social position; he
makes no attempt to adopt fine manners or elegant tastes; and he
never seeks to gain admission to what is called in Russia la
societe. Having no desire to seem what he is not, he has a plain,
unaffected manner, and sometimes a quiet dignity which contrasts
favourably with the affected manner of those nobles of the lower
ranks who make pretensions to being highly educated and strive to
adopt the outward forms of French culture. At his great dinners,
it is true, the merchant likes to see among his guests as many
"generals"--that is to say, official personages--as possible, and
especially those who happen to have a grand cordon; but he never
dreams of thereby establishing an intimacy with these personages,
or of being invited by them in return. It is perfectly understood
by both parties that nothing of the kind is meant. The invitation
is given and accepted from quite different motives. The merchant
has the satisfaction of seeing at his table men of high official
rank, and feels that the consideration which he enjoys among people
of his own class is thereby augmented. If he succeeds in obtaining
the presence of three generals, he obtains a victory over a rival
who cannot obtain more than two. The general, on his side, gets a
first-rate dinner, a la russe, and acquires an undefined right to
request subscriptions for public objects or benevolent
institutions.
Of course this undefined right is commonly nothing more than a mere
tacit understanding, but in certain cases the subject is expressly
mentioned. I know of one case in which a regular bargain was made.
A Moscow magnate was invited by a merchant to a dinner, and
consented to go in full uniform, with all his decorations, on
condition that the merchant should subscribe a certain sum to a
benevolent institution in which he was particularly interested. It
is whispered that such bargains are sometimes made, not on behalf
of benevolent institutions, but simply in the interest of the
gentleman who accepts the invitation. I cannot believe that there
are many official personages who would consent to let themselves
out as table decorations, but that it may happen is proved by the
following incident, which accidentally came to my knowledge. A
rich merchant of the town of T---- once requested the Governor of
the Province to honour a family festivity with his presence, and
added that he would consider it a special favour if the
"Governoress" would enter an appearance. To this latter request
his Excellency made many objections, and at last let the petitioner
understand that her Excellency could not possibly be present,
because she had no velvet dress that could bear comparison with
those of several merchants' wives in the town. Two days after the
interview a piece of the finest velvet that could be procured in
Moscow was received by the Governor from an unknown donor, and his
wife was thus enabled to be present at the festivity, to the
complete satisfaction of all parties concerned.
It is worthy of remark that the merchants recognise no aristocracy
but that of official rank. Many merchants would willingly give
twenty pounds for the presence of an "actual State Councillor" who
perhaps never heard of his grandfather, but who can show a grand
cordon; whilst they would not give twenty pence for the presence of
an undecorated Prince without official rank, though he might be
able to trace his pedigree up to the half-mythical Rurik. Of the
latter they would probably say, "Kto ikh znact?" (Who knows what
sort of a fellow he is?) The former, on the contrary, whoever his
father and grandfather may have been, possesses unmistakable marks
of the Tsar's favour, which, in the merchant's opinion, is
infinitely more important than any rights or pretensions founded on
hereditary titles or long pedigrees.
Some marks of Imperial favour the old-fashioned merchants strive to
obtain for themselves. They do not dream of grand cordons--that is
far beyond their most sanguine expectations--but they do all in
their power to obtain those lesser decorations which are granted to
the mercantile class. For this purpose the most common expedient
is a liberal subscription to some benevolent institution, and
occasionally a regular bargain is made. I know of at least one
instance where the kind of decoration was expressly stipulated.
The affair illustrates so well the commercial character of these
transactions that I venture to state the facts as related to me by
the official chiefly concerned. A merchant subscribed to a society
which enjoyed the patronage of a Grand Duchess a considerable sum
of money, under the express condition that he should receive in
return a St. Vladimir Cross. Instead of the desired decoration,
which was considered too much for the sum subscribed, a cross of
St. Stanislas was granted; but the donor was dissatisfied with the
latter and demanded that his money should be returned to him. The
demand had to be complied with, and, as an Imperial gift cannot be
retracted, the merchant had his Stanislas Cross for nothing.
This traffic in decorations has had its natural result. Like paper
money issued in too large quantities, the decorations have fallen
in value. The gold medals which were formerly much coveted and
worn with pride by the rich merchants--suspended by a ribbon round
the neck--are now little sought after. In like manner the
inordinate respect for official personages has considerably
diminished. Fifty years ago the provincial merchants vied with
each other in their desire to entertain any great dignitary who
honoured their town with a visit, but now they seek rather to avoid
this expensive and barren honour. When they do accept the honour,
they fulfil the duties of hospitality in a most liberal spirit. I
have sometimes, when living as an honoured guest in a rich
merchant's house, found it difficult to obtain anything simpler
than sterlet, sturgeon, and champagne.
The two great blemishes on the character of the Russian merchants
as a class are, according to general opinion, their ignorance and
their dishonesty. As to the former of these there cannot possibly
be any difference of opinion. Many of them can neither read nor
write, and are forced to keep their accounts in their memory, or by
means of ingenious hieroglyphics, intelligible only to the
inventor. Others can decipher the calendar and the lives of the
saints, can sign their names with tolerable facility, and can make
the simpler arithmetical calculations with the help of the stchety,
a little calculating instrument, composed of wooden balls strung on
brass wires, which resembles the "abaca" of the old Romans, and is
universally used in Russia. It is only the minority who understand
the mysteries of regular book-keeping, and of these very few can
make any pretensions to being educated men.
All this, however, is rapidly undergoing a radical change.
Children are now much better educated than their parents, and the
next generation will doubtless make further progress, so that the
old-fashioned type above described is destined to disappear.
Already there are not a few of the younger generation--especially
among the wealthy manufacturers of Moscow--who have been educated
abroad, who may be described as tout a fait civilises, and whose
mode of life differs little from that of the richer nobles; but
they remain outside fashionable society, and constitute a "set" of
their own.
As to the dishonesty which is said to be so common among the
Russian commercial classes, it is difficult to form an accurate
judgment. That an enormous amount of unfair dealing does exist
there can be no possible doubt, but in this matter a foreigner is
likely to be unduly severe. We are apt to apply unflinchingly our
own standard of commercial morality, and to forget that trade in
Russia is only emerging from that primitive condition in which
fixed prices and moderate profits are entirely unknown. And when
we happen to detect positive dishonesty, it seems to us especially
heinous, because the trickery employed is more primitive and
awkward than that to which we are accustomed. Trickery in weighing
and measuring, for instance, which is by no means uncommon in
Russia, is likely to make us more indignant than those ingenious
methods of adulteration which are practised nearer home, and are
regarded by many as almost legitimate. Besides this, foreigners
who go to Russia and embark in speculations without possessing any
adequate knowledge of the character, customs, and language of the
people positively invite spoliation, and ought to blame themselves
rather than the people who profit by their ignorance.
All this, and much more of the same kind, may be fairly urged in
mitigation of the severe judgments which foreign merchants commonly
pass on Russian commercial morality, but these judgments cannot be
reversed by such argumentation. The dishonesty and rascality which
exist among the merchants are fully recognised by the Russians
themselves. In all moral affairs the lower classes in Russia are
very lenient in their judgments, and are strongly disposed, like
the Americans, to admire what is called in Transatlantic
phraseology "a smart man," though the smartness is known to contain
a large admixture of dishonesty; and yet the vox populi in Russia
emphatically declares that the merchants as a class are
unscrupulous and dishonest. There is a rude popular play in which
the Devil, as principal dramatis persona, succeeds in cheating all
manner and conditions of men, but is finally overreached by a
genuine Russian merchant. When this play is acted in the Carnival
Theatre in St. Petersburg the audience invariably agrees with the
moral of the plot.
If this play were acted in the southern towns near the coast of the
Black Sea it would be necessary to modify it considerably, for
here, in company with Jews, Greeks, and Armenians, the Russian
merchants seem honest by comparison. As to Greeks and Armenians, I
know not which of the two nationalities deserves the palm, but it
seems that both are surpassed by the Children of Israel. "How
these Jews do business," I have heard a Russian merchant of this
region exclaim, "I cannot understand. They buy up wheat in the
villages at eleven roubles per tchetvert, transport it to the coast
at their own expense, and sell it to the exporters at ten roubles!
And yet they contrive to make a profit! It is said that the
Russian trader is cunning, but here 'our brother' [i.e., the
Russian] can do nothing." The truth of this statement I have had
abundant opportunities of confirming by personal investigations on
the spot.
If I might express a general opinion regarding Russian commercial
morality, I should say that trade in Russia is carried on very much
on the same principle as horse-dealing in England. A man who
wishes to buy or sell must trust to his own knowledge and
acuteness, and if he gets the worst of a bargain or lets himself be
deceived, he has himself to blame. Commercial Englishmen on
arriving in Russia rarely understand this, and when they know it
theoretically they are too often unable, from their ignorance of
the language, the laws, and the customs of the people, to turn
their theoretical knowledge to account. They indulge, therefore,
at first in endless invectives against the prevailing dishonesty;
but gradually, when they have paid what Germans call Lehrgeld, they
accommodate themselves to circumstances, take large profits to
counterbalance bad debts, and generally succeed--if they have
sufficient energy, mother-wit, and capital--in making a very
handsome income.
The old race of British merchants, however, is rapidly dying out,
and I greatly fear that the rising generation will not be equally
successful. Times have changed. It is no longer possible to amass
large fortunes in the old easy-going fashion. Every year the
conditions alter, and the competition increases. In order to
foresee, understand, and take advantage of the changes, one must
have far more knowledge of the country than the men of the old
school possessed, and it seems to me that the young generation have
still less of that knowledge than their predecessors. Unless some
change takes place in this respect, the German merchants, who have
generally a much better commercial education and are much better
acquainted with their adopted country, will ultimately, I believe,
expel their British rivals. Already many branches of commerce
formerly carried on by Englishmen have passed into their hands.
It must not be supposed that the unsatisfactory organisation of the
Russian commercial world is the result of any radical peculiarity
of the Russian character. All new countries have to pass through a
similar state of things, and in Russia there are already
premonitory symptoms of a change for the better. For the present,
it is true, the extensive construction of railways and the rapid
development of banks and limited liability companies have opened up
a new and wide field for all kinds of commercial swindling; but, on
the other hand, there are now in every large town a certain number
of merchants who carry on business in the West-European manner, and
have learnt by experience that honesty is the best policy. The
success which many of these have obtained will doubtless cause
their example to be followed. The old spirit of caste and routine
which has long animated the merchant class is rapidly disappearing,
and not a few nobles are now exchanging country life and the
service of the State for industrial and commercial enterprises. In
this way is being formed the nucleus of that wealthy, enlightened
bourgeoisie which Catherine endeavoured to create by legislation;
but many years must elapse before this class acquires sufficient
social and political significance to deserve the title of a tiers-
etat.
CHAPTER XIII
THE PASTORAL TRIBES OF THE STEPPE
A Journey to the Steppe Region of the Southeast--The Volga--Town
and Province of Samara--Farther Eastward--Appearance of the
Villages--Characteristic Incident--Peasant Mendacity--Explanation
of the Phenomenon--I Awake in Asia--A Bashkir Aoul--Diner la
Tartare--Kumyss--A Bashkir Troubadour--Honest Mehemet Zian--Actual
Economic Condition of the Bashkirs Throws Light on a Well-known
Philosophical Theory--Why a Pastoral Race Adopts Agriculture--The
Genuine Steppe--The Kirghiz--Letter from Genghis Khan--The Kalmyks--
Nogai Tartars--Struggle between Nomadic Hordes and Agricultural
Colonists.
When I had spent a couple of years or more in the Northern and
North-Central provinces--the land of forests and of agriculture
conducted on the three-field system, with here and there a town of
respectable antiquity--I determined to visit for purposes of
comparison and contrast the Southeastern region, which possesses no
forests nor ancient towns, and corresponds to the Far West of the
United States of America. My point of departure was Yaroslavl, a
town on the right bank of the Volga to the northeast of Moscow--and
thence I sailed down the river during three days on a large
comfortable steamer to Samara, the chief town of the province or
"government" of the name. Here I left the steamer and prepared to
make a journey into the eastern hinterland.
Samara is a new town, a child of the last century. At the time of
my first visit, now thirty years ago, it recalled by its unfinished
appearance the new towns of America. Many of the houses were of
wood. The streets were still in such a primitive condition that
after rain they were almost impassable from mud, and in dry, gusty
weather they generated thick clouds of blinding, suffocating dust.
Before I had been many days in the place I witnessed a dust-
hurricane, during which it was impossible at certain moments to see
from my window the houses on the other side of the street. Amidst
such primitive surroundings the colossal new church seemed a little
out of keeping, and it occurred to my practical British mind that
some of the money expended on its construction might have been more
profitably employed. But the Russians have their own ideas of the
fitness of things. Religious after their own fashion, they
subscribe money liberally for ecclesiastical purposes--especially
for the building and decoration of their churches. Besides this,
the Government considers that every chief town of a province should
possess a cathedral.
In its early days Samara was one of the outposts of Russian
colonisation, and had often to take precautions against the raids
of the nomadic tribes living in the vicinity; but the agricultural
frontier has since been pushed far forward to the east and south,
and the province was until lately, despite occasional droughts, one
of the most productive in the Empire. The town is the chief market
of this region, and therein lies its importance. The grain is
brought by the peasants from great distances, and stored in large
granaries by the merchants, who send it to Moscow or St.
Petersburg. In former days this was a very tedious operation. The
boats containing the grain were towed by horses or stout peasants
up the rivers and through the canals for hundreds of miles. Then
came the period of "cabestans"--unwieldly machines propelled by
means of anchors and windlasses. Now these primitive methods of
transport have disappeared. The grain is either despatched by rail
or put into gigantic barges, which are towed up the river by
powerful tug-steamers to some point connected with the great
network of railways.
When the traveller has visited the Cathedral and the granaries he
has seen all the lions--not very formidable lions, truly--of the
place. He may then inspect the kumyss establishments, pleasantly
situated near the town. He will find there a considerable number
of patients--mostly consumptive--who drink enormous quantities of
fermented mare's-milk, and who declare that they receive great
benefit from this modern health-restorer.
What interested me more than the lions of the town or the suburban
kumyss establishments were the offices of the local administration,
where I found in the archives much statistical and other
information of the kind I was in search of, regarding the economic
condition of the province generally, and of the emancipated
peasantry in particular. Having filled my note-book with material
of this sort, I proceeded to verify and complete it by visiting
some characteristic villages and questioning the inhabitants. For
the student of Russian affairs who wishes to arrive at real, as
distinguished from official, truth, this is not an altogether
superfluous operation.
When I had thus made the acquaintance of the sedentary agricultural
population in several districts I journeyed eastwards with the
intention of visiting the Bashkirs, a Tartar tribe which still
preserved--so at least I was assured--its old nomadic habits. My
reasons for undertaking this journey were twofold. In the first
place I was desirous of seeing with my own eyes some remnants of
those terrible nomadic tribes which had at one time conquered
Russia and long threatened to overrun Europe--those Tartar hordes
which gained, by their irresistible force and relentless cruelty,
the reputation of being "the scourge of God." Besides this, I had
long wished to study the conditions of pastoral life, and
congratulated myself on having found a convenient opportunity of
doing so.
As I proceeded eastwards I noticed a change in the appearance of
the villages. The ordinary wooden houses, with their high sloping
roofs, gradually gave place to flat-roofed huts, built of a
peculiar kind of unburnt bricks, composed of mud and straw. I
noticed, too, that the population became less and less dense, and
the amount of fallow land proportionately greater. The peasants
were evidently richer than those near the Volga, but they
complained--as the Russian peasant always does--that they had not
land enough. In answer to my inquiries why they did not use the
thousands of acres that were lying fallow around them, they
explained that they had already raised crops on that land for
several successive years, and that consequently they must now allow
it to "rest."
In one of the villages through which I passed I met with a very
characteristic little incident. The village was called Samovolnaya
Ivanofka--that is to say, "Ivanofka the Self-willed" or "the Non-
authorised." Whilst our horses were being changed my travelling
companion, in the course of conversation with a group of peasants,
inquired about the origin of this extraordinary name, and
discovered a curious bit of local history. The founders of the
village had settled on the land without the permission of the
absentee owner, and obstinately resisted all attempts at eviction.
Again and again troops had been sent to drive them away, but as
soon as the troops retired these "self-willed" people returned and
resumed possession, till at last the proprietor, who lived in St.
Petersburg or some other distant place, became weary of the contest
and allowed them to remain. The various incidents were related
with much circumstantial detail, so that the narration lasted
perhaps half an hour. All this time I listened attentively, and
when the story was finished I took out my note-book in order to jot
down the facts, and asked in what year the affair had happened. No
answer was given to my question. The peasants merely looked at
each other in a significant way and kept silence. Thinking that my
question had not been understood, I asked it a second time,
repeating a part of what had been related. To my astonishment and
utter discomfiture they all declared that they had never related
anything of the sort! In despair I appealed to my friend, and
asked him whether my ears had deceived me--whether I was labouring
under some strange hallucination. Without giving me any reply he
simply smiled and turned away.
When we had left the village and were driving along in our
tarantass the mystery was satisfactorily cleared up. My friend
explained to me that I had not at all misunderstood what had been
related, but that my abrupt question and the sight of my note-book
had suddenly aroused the peasants' suspicions. "They evidently
suspected," he continued, "that you were a tchinovnik, and that you
wished to use to their detriment the knowledge you had acquired.
They thought it safer, therefore, at once to deny it all. You
don't yet understand the Russian muzhik!"
In this last remark I was obliged to concur, but since that time I
have come to know the muzhik better, and an incident of the kind
would now no longer surprise me. From a long series of
observations I have come to the conclusion that the great majority
of the Russian peasants, when dealing with the authorities,
consider the most patent and barefaced falsehoods as a fair means
of self-defence. Thus, for example, when a muzhik is implicated in
a criminal affair, and a preliminary investigation is being made,
he probably begins by constructing an elaborate story to explain
the facts and exculpate himself. The story may be a tissue of
self-evident falsehoods from beginning to end, but he defends it
valiantly as long as possible. When he perceives that the position
which he has taken up is utterly untenable, he declares openly that
all he has said is false, and that he wishes to make a new
declaration. This second declaration may have the same fate as the
former one, and then he proposes a third. Thus groping his way, he
tries various stories till he finds one that seems proof against
all objections. In the fact of his thus telling lies there is of
course nothing remarkable, for criminals in all parts of the world
have a tendency to deviate from the truth when they fall into the
hands of justice. The peculiarity is that he retracts his
statements with the composed air of a chess-player who requests his
opponent to let him take back an inadvertent move. Under the old
system of procedure, which was abolished in the sixties, clever
criminals often contrived by means of this simple device to have
their trial postponed for many years.
Such incidents naturally astonish a foreigner, and he is apt, in
consequence, to pass a very severe judgment on the Russian
peasantry in general. The reader may remember Karl Karl'itch's
remarks on the subject. These remarks I have heard repeated in
various forms by Germans in all parts of the country, and there
must be a certain amount of truth in them, for even an eminent
Slavophil once publicly admitted that the peasant is prone to
perjury.* It is necessary, however, as it seems to me, to draw a
distinction. In the ordinary intercourse of peasants among
themselves, or with people in whom they have confidence, I do not
believe that the habit of lying is abnormally developed. It is
only when the muzhik comes in contact with authorities that he
shows himself an expert fabricator of falsehoods. In this there is
nothing that need surprise us. For ages the peasantry were exposed
to the arbitrary power and ruthless exactions of those who were
placed over them; and as the law gave them no means of legally
protecting themselves, their only means of self-defence lay in
cunning and deceit.
* Kireyefski, in the Russakaya Beseda.
We have here, I believe, the true explanation of that "Oriental
mendacity" about which Eastern travellers have written so much. It
is simply the result of a lawless state of society. Suppose a
truth-loving Englishman falls into the hands of brigands or
savages. Will he not, if he have merely an ordinary moral
character, consider himself justified in inventing a few falsehoods
in order to effect his escape? If so, we have no right to condemn
very severely the hereditary mendacity of those races which have
lived for many generations in a position analogous to that of the
supposed Englishman among brigands. When legitimate interests
cannot be protected by truthfulness and honesty, prudent people
always learn to employ means which experience has proved to be more
effectual. In a country where the law does not afford protection,
the strong man defends himself by his strength, the weak by cunning
and duplicity. This fully explains the fact that in Turkey the
Christians are less truthful than the Mahometans.
But we have wandered a long way from the road to Bashkiria. Let us
therefore return at once.
Of all the journeys which I made in Russia this was one of the most
agreeable. The weather was bright and warm, without being
unpleasantly hot; the roads were tolerably smooth; the tarantass,
which had been hired for the whole journey, was nearly as
comfortable as a tarantass can be; good milk, eggs, and white bread
could be obtained in abundance; there was not much difficulty in
procuring horses in the villages through which we passed, and the
owners of them were not very extortionate in their demands. But
what most contributed to my comfort was that I was accompanied by
an agreeable, intelligent young Russian, who kindly undertook to
make all the necessary arrangements, and I was thereby freed from
those annoyances and worries which are always encountered in
primitive countries where travelling is not yet a recognised
institution. To him I left the entire control of our movements,
passively acquiescing in everything, and asking no questions as to
what was coming. Taking advantage of my passivity, he prepared for
me one evening a pleasant little surprise.
About sunset we had left a village called Morsha, and shortly
afterwards, feeling drowsy, and being warned by my companion that
we should have a long, uninteresting drive, I had lain down in the
tarantass and gone to sleep. On awaking I found that the tarantass
had stopped, and that the stars were shining brightly overhead. A
big dog was barking furiously close at hand, and I heard the voice
of the yamstchik informing us that we had arrived. I at once sat
up and looked about me, expecting to see a village of some kind,
but instead of that I perceived a wide open space, and at a short
distance a group of haystacks. Close to the tarantass stood two
figures in long cloaks, armed with big sticks, and speaking to each
other in an unknown tongue. My first idea was that we had been
somehow led into a trap, so I drew my revolver in order to be ready
for all emergencies. My companion was still snoring loudly by my
side, and stoutly resisted all my efforts to awaken him.
"What's this?" I said, in a gruff, angry voice, to the yamstchik.
"Where have you taken us to?"
"To where I was ordered, master!"
For the purpose of getting a more satisfactory explanation I took
to shaking my sleepy companion, but before he had returned to
consciousness the moon shone out brightly from behind a thick bank
of clouds, and cleared up the mystery. The supposed haystacks
turned out to be tents. The two figures with long sticks, whom I
had suspected of being brigands, were peaceable shepherds, dressed
in the ordinary Oriental khalat, and tending their sheep, which
were grazing close by. Instead of being in an empty hay-field, as
I had imagined, we had before us a regular Tartar aoul, such as I
had often read about. For a moment I felt astonished and
bewildered. It seemed to me that I had fallen asleep in Europe and
woke up in Asia!
In a few minutes we were comfortably installed in one of the tents,
a circular, cupola-shaped erection, of about twelve feet in
diameter, composed of a frame-work of light wooden rods covered
with thick felt. It contained no furniture, except a goodly
quantity of carpets and pillows, which had been formed into a bed
for our accommodation. Our amiable host, who was evidently
somewhat astonished at our unexpected visit, but refrained from
asking questions, soon bade us good-night and retired. We were
not, however, left alone. A large number of black beetles remained
and gave us a welcome in their own peculiar fashion. Whether they
were provided with wings, or made up for the want of flying
appliances by crawling up the sides of the tent and dropping down
on any object they wished to reach, I did not discover, but certain
it is that they somehow reached our heads--even when we were
standing upright--and clung to our hair with wonderful tenacity.
Why they should show such a marked preference for human hair we
could not conjecture, till it occurred to us that the natives
habitually shaved their heads, and that these beetles must
naturally consider a hair-covered cranium a curious novelty
deserving of careful examination. Like all children of nature they
were decidedly indiscreet and troublesome in their curiosity, but
when the light was extinguished they took the hint and departed.
When we awoke next morning it was broad daylight, and we found a
crowd of natives in front of the tent. Our arrival was evidently
regarded as an important event, and all the inhabitants of the aoul
were anxious to make our acquaintance. First our host came
forward. He was a short, slimly-built man, of middle age, with a
grave, severe expression, indicating an unsociable disposition. We
afterwards learned that he was an akhun*--that is to say, a minor
officer of the Mahometan ecclesiastical administration, and at the
same time a small trader in silken and woollen stuffs. With him
came the mullah, or priest, a portly old gentleman with an open,
honest face of the European type, and a fine grey beard. The other
important members of the little community followed. They were all
swarthy in colour, and had the small eyes and prominent cheek-bones
which are characteristic of the Tartar races, but they had little
of that flatness of countenance and peculiar ugliness which
distinguish the pure Mongol. All of them, with the exception of
the mullah, spoke a little Russian, and used it to assure us that
we were welcome. The children remained respectfully in the
background, and the women, with laces veiled, eyed us furtively
from the doors of the tents.
* I presume this is the same word as akhund, well known on the
Northwest frontier of India, where it was applied specially to the
late ruler of Svat.
The aoul consisted of about twenty tents, all constructed on the
same model, and scattered about in sporadic fashion, without the
least regard to symmetry. Close by was a watercourse, which
appears on some maps as a river, under the name of Karalyk, but
which was at that time merely a succession of pools containing a
dark-coloured liquid. As we more than suspected that these pools
supplied the inhabitants with water for culinary purposes, the
sight was not calculated to whet our appetites. We turned away
therefore hurriedly, and for want of something better to do we
watched the preparations for dinner. These were decidedly
primitive. A sheep was brought near the door of our tent, and
there killed, skinned, cut up into pieces, and put into an immense
pot, under which a fire had been kindled.
The dinner itself was not less primitive than the manner of
preparing it. The table consisted of a large napkin spread in the
middle of the tent, and the chairs were represented by cushions, on
which we sat cross-legged. There were no plates, knives, forks,
spoons, or chopsticks. Guests were expected all to eat out of a
common wooden bowl, and to use the instruments with which Nature
had provided them. The service was performed by the host and his
son. The fare was copious, but not varied--consisting entirely of
boiled mutton, without bread or other substitute, and a little
salted horse-flesh thrown in as an entree.
To eat out of the same dish with half-a-dozen Mahometans who accept
their Prophet's injunction about ablutions in a highly figurative
sense, and who are totally unacquainted with the use of forks and
spoons, is not an agreeable operation, even if one is not much
troubled with religious prejudices; but with these Bashkirs
something worse than this has to be encountered, for their
favourite method of expressing their esteem and affection for one
with whom they are eating consists in putting bits of mutton, and
sometimes even handfuls of hashed meat, into his month! When I
discovered this unexpected peculiarity in Bashkir manners and
customs, I almost regretted that I had made a favourable impression
upon my new acquaintances.
When the sheep had been devoured, partly by the company in the tent
and partly by a nondescript company outside--for the whole aoul
took part in the festivities--kumyss was served in unlimited
quantities. This beverage, as I have already explained, is mare's
milk fermented; but what here passed under the name was very
different from the kumyss I had tasted in the establissements of
Samara. There it was a pleasant effervescing drink, with only the
slightest tinge of acidity; here it was a "still" liquid, strongly
resembling very thin and very sour butter-milk. My Russian friend
made a wry face on first tasting it, and I felt inclined at first
to do likewise, but noticing that his grimaces made an unfavourable
impression on the audience, I restrained my facial muscles, and
looked as if I liked it. Very soon I really came to like it, and
learned to "drink fair" with those who had been accustomed to it
from their childhood. By this feat I rose considerably in the
estimation of the natives; for if one does not drink kumyss one
cannot be sociable in the Bashkir sense of the term, and by
acquiring the habit one adopts an essential principle of Bashkir
nationality. I should certainly have preferred having a cup of it
to myself, but I thought it well to conform to the habits of the
country, and to accept the big wooden bowl when it was passed
round. In return my friends made an important concession in my
favour: they allowed me to smoke as I pleased, though they
considered that, as the Prophet had refrained from tobacco,
ordinary mortals should do the same.
Whilst the "loving-cup" was going round I distributed some small
presents which I had brought for the purpose, and then proceeded to
explain the object of my visit. In the distant country from which
I came--far away to the westward--I had heard of the Bashkirs as a
people possessing many strange customs, but very kind and
hospitable to strangers. Of their kindness and hospitality I had
already learned something by experience, and I hoped they would
allow me to learn something of their mode of life, their customs,
their songs, their history, and their religion, in all of which I
assured them my distant countrymen took a lively interest.
This little after-dinner speech was perhaps not quite in accordance
with Bashkir etiquette, but it made a favourable impression. There
was a decided murmur of approbation, and those who understood
Russian translated my words to their less accomplished brethren. A
short consultation ensued, and then there was a general shout of
"Abdullah! Abdullah!" which was taken up and repeated by those
standing outside.
In a few minutes Abdullah appeared, with a big, half-picked bone in
his hand, and the lower part of his face besmeared with grease. He
was a short, thin man, with a dark, sallow complexion, and a look
of premature old age; but the suppressed smile that played about
his mouth and a tremulous movement of his right eye-lid showed
plainly that he had not yet forgotten the fun and frolic of youth.
His dress was of richer and more gaudy material, but at the same
time more tawdry and tattered, than that of the others. Altogether
he looked like an artiste in distressed circumstances, and such he
really was. At a word and a sign from the host he laid aside his
bone and drew from under his green silk khalat a small wind-
instrument resembling a flute or flageolet. On this he played a
number of native airs. The first melodies which he played reminded
me of a Highland pibroch--at one moment low, solemn, and plaintive,
then gradually rising into a soul-stirring, martial strain, and
again descending to a plaintive wail. The amount of expression
which he put into his simple instrument was truly marvellous.
Then, passing suddenly from grave to gay, he played a series of
light, merry airs, and some of the younger onlookers got up and
performed a dance as boisterous and ungraceful as an Irish jig.
This Abdullah turned out to be for me a most valuable acquaintance.
He was a kind of Bashkir troubadour, well acquainted not only with
the music, but also with the traditions, the history, the
superstitions, and the folk-lore of his people. By the akhun and
the mullah he was regarded as a frivolous, worthless fellow, who
had no regular, respectable means of gaining a livelihood, but
among the men of less rigid principles he was a general favourite.
As he spoke Russian fluently I could converse with him freely
without the aid of an interpreter, and he willingly placed his
store of knowledge at my disposal. When in the company of the
akhun he was always solemn and taciturn, but as soon as he was
relieved of that dignitary's presence he became lively and
communicative.
Another of my new acquaintances was equally useful to me in another
way. This was Mehemet Zian, who was not so intelligent as
Abdullah, but much more sympathetic. In his open, honest face, and
kindly, unaffected manner there was something so irresistibly
attractive that before I had known him twenty-four hours a sort of
friendship had sprung up between us. He was a tall, muscular,
broad-shouldered man, with features that suggested a mixture of
European blood. Though already past middle age, he was still wiry
and active--so active that he could, when on horseback, pick a
stone off the ground without dismounting. He could, however, no
longer perform this feat at full gallop, as he had been wont to do
in his youth. His geographical knowledge was extremely limited and
inaccurate--his mind being in this respect like those old Russian
maps in which the nations of the earth and a good many peoples who
had never more than a mythical existence are jumbled together in
hopeless confusion--but his geographical curiosity was insatiable.
My travelling-map--the first thing of the kind he had ever seen--
interested him deeply. When he found that by simply examining it
and glancing at my compass I could tell him the direction and
distance of places he knew, his face was like that of a child who
sees for the first time a conjuror's performance; and when I
explained the trick to him, and taught him to calculate the
distance to Bokhara--the sacred city of the Mussulmans of that
region--his delight was unbounded. Gradually I perceived that to
possess such a map had become the great object of his ambition.
Unfortunately I could not at once gratify him as I should have
wished, because I had a long journey before me and I had no other
map of the region, but I promised to find ways and means of sending
him one, and I kept my word by means of a native of the Karalyk
district whom I discovered in Samara. I did not add a compass
because I could not find one in the town, and it would have been of
little use to him: like a true child of nature he always knew the
cardinal points by the sun or the stars. Some years later I had
the satisfaction of learning that the map had reached its
destination safely, through no less a personage than Count Tolstoy.
One evening at the home of a friend in Moscow I was presented to
the great novelist, and as soon as he heard my name he said: "Oh! I
know you already, and I know your friend Mehemet Zian. When I
passed a night this summer in his aoul he showed me a map with your
signature on the margin, and taught me how to calculate the
distance to Bokhara!"
If Mehemet knew little of foreign countries he was thoroughly well
acquainted with his own, and repaid me most liberally for my
elementary lessons in geography. With him I visited the
neighbouring aouls. In all of them he had numerous acquaintances,
and everywhere we were received with the greatest hospitality,
except on one occasion when we paid a visit of ceremony to a famous
robber who was the terror of the whole neighbourhood. Certainly he
was one of the most brutalised specimens of humanity I have ever
encountered. He made no attempt to be amiable, and I felt inclined
to leave his tent at once; but I saw that my friend wanted to
conciliate him, so I restrained my feelings and eventually
established tolerably good relations with him. As a rule I avoided
festivities, partly because I knew that my hosts were mostly poor
and would not accept payment for the slaughtered sheep, and partly
because I had reason to apprehend that they would express to me
their esteem and affection more Bashkirico; but in kumyss-drinking,
the ordinary occupation of these people when they have nothing to
do, I had to indulge to a most inordinate extent. On these
expeditions Abdullah generally accompanied us, and rendered
valuable service as interpreter and troubadour. Mehemet could
express himself in Russian, but his vocabulary failed him as soon
as the conversation ran above very ordinary topics; Abdullah, on
the contrary, was a first-rate interpreter, and under the influence
of his musical pipe and lively talkativeness new acquaintances
became sociable and communicative. Poor Abdullah! He was a kind
of universal genius; but his faded, tattered khalat showed only too
plainly that in Bashkiria, as in more civilised countries,
universal genius and the artistic temperament lead to poverty
rather than to wealth.
I have no intention of troubling the reader with the miscellaneous
facts which, with the assistance of these two friends, I succeeded
in collecting--indeed, I could not if I would, for the notes I then
made were afterwards lost--but I wish to say a few words about the
actual economic condition of the Bashkirs. They are at present
passing from pastoral to agricultural life; and it is not a little
interesting to note the causes which induce them to make this
change, and the way in which it is made.
Philosophers have long held a theory of social development
according to which men were at first hunters, then shepherds, and
lastly agriculturists. How far this theory is in accordance with
reality we need not for the present inquire, but we may examine an
important part of it and ask ourselves the question, Why did
pastoral tribes adopt agriculture? The common explanation is that
they changed their mode of life in consequence of some ill-defined,
fortuitous circumstances. A great legislator arose amongst them
and taught them to till the soil, or they came in contact with an
agricultural race and adopted the customs of their neighbours.
Such explanations must appear unsatisfactory to any one who has
lived with a pastoral people. Pastoral life is so incomparably
more agreeable than the hard lot of the agriculturist, and so much
more in accordance with the natural indolence of human nature, that
no great legislator, though he had the wisdom of a Solon and the
eloquence of a Demosthenes, could possibly induce his fellow-
countrymen to pass voluntarily from the one to the other. Of all
the ordinary means of gaining a livelihood--with the exception
perhaps of mining--agriculture is the most laborious, and is never
voluntarily adopted by men who have not been accustomed to it from
their childhood. The life of a pastoral race, on the contrary, is
a perennial holiday, and I can imagine nothing except the prospect
of starvation which could induce men who live by their flocks and
herds to make the transition to agricultural life.
The prospect of starvation is, in fact, the cause of the
transition--probably in all cases, and certainly in the case of the
Bashkirs. So long as they had abundance of pasturage they never
thought of tilling the soil. Their flocks and herds supplied them
with all that they required, and enabled them to lead a tranquil,
indolent existence. No great legislator arose among them to teach
them the use of the plough and the sickle, and when they saw the
Russian peasants on their borders laboriously ploughing and
reaping, they looked on them with compassion, and never thought of
following their example. But an impersonal legislator came to
them--a very severe and tyrannical legislator, who would not brook
disobedience--I mean Economic Necessity. By the encroachments of
the Ural Cossacks on the east, and by the ever-advancing wave of
Russian colonisation from the north and west, their territory had
been greatly diminished. With diminution of the pasturage came
diminution of the live stock, their sole means of subsistence. In
spite of their passively conservative spirit they had to look about
for some new means of obtaining food and clothing--some new mode of
life requiring less extensive territorial possessions. It was only
then that they began to think of imitating their neighbours. They
saw that the neighbouring Russian peasant lived comfortably on
thirty or forty acres of land, whilst they possessed a hundred and
fifty acres per male, and were in danger of starvation.
The conclusion to be drawn from this was self-evident--they ought
at once to begin ploughing and sowing. But there was a very
serious obstacle to the putting of this principle in practice.
Agriculture certainly requires less land than sheep-farming, but it
requires very much more labour, and to hard work the Bashkirs were
not accustomed. They could bear hardships and fatigues in the
shape of long journeys on horseback, but the severe, monotonous
labour of the plough and the sickle was not to their taste. At
first, therefore, they adopted a compromise. They had a portion of
their land tilled by Russian peasants, and ceded to these a part of
the produce in return for the labour expended; in other words, they
assumed the position of landed proprietors, and farmed part of
their land on the metayage system.
The process of transition had reached this point in several aouls
which I visited. My friend Mehemet Zian showed me at some distance
from the tents his plot of arable land, and introduced me to the
peasant who tilled it--a Little-Russian, who assured me that the
arrangement satisfied all parties. The process of transition
cannot, however, stop here. The compromise is merely a temporary
expedient. Virgin soil gives very abundant harvests, sufficient to
support both the labourer and the indolent proprietor, but after a
few years the soil becomes exhausted and gives only a very moderate
revenue. A proprietor, therefore, must sooner or later dispense
with the labourers who take half of the produce as their
recompense, and must himself put his hand to the plough.
Thus we see the Bashkirs are, properly speaking, no longer a purely
pastoral, nomadic people. The discovery of this fact caused me
some little disappointment, and in the hope of finding a tribe in a
more primitive condition I visited the Kirghiz of the Inner Horde,
who occupy the country to the southward, in the direction of the
Caspian. Here for the first time I saw the genuine Steppe in the
full sense of the term--a country level as the sea, with not a
hillock or even a gentle undulation to break the straight line of
the horizon, and not a patch of cultivation, a tree, a bush, or
even a stone, to diversify the monotonous expanse.
Traversing such a region is, I need scarcely say, very weary work--
all the more as there are no milestones or other landmarks to show
the progress you are making. Still, it is not so overwhelmingly
wearisome as might be supposed. In the morning you may watch the
vast lakes, with their rugged promontories and well-wooded banks,
which the mirage creates for your amusement. Then during the
course of the day there are always one or two trifling incidents
which arouse you for a little from your somnolence. Now you descry
a couple of horsemen on the distant horizon, and watch them as they
approach; and when they come alongside you may have a talk with
them if you know the language or have an interpreter; or you may
amuse yourself with a little pantomime, if articulate speech is
impossible. Now you encounter a long train of camels marching
along with solemn, stately step, and speculate as to the contents
of the big packages with which they are laden. Now you encounter
the carcass of a horse that has fallen by the wayside, and watch
the dogs and the steppe eagles fighting over their prey; and if you
are murderously inclined you may take a shot with your revolver at
these great birds, for they are ignorantly brave, and will
sometimes allow you to approach within twenty or thirty yards. At
last you perceive--most pleasant sight of all--a group of haystack-
shaped tents in the distance; and you hurry on to enjoy the
grateful shade, and quench your thirst with "deep, deep draughts"
of refreshing kumyss.
During my journey through the Kirghiz country I was accompanied by
a Russian gentleman, who had provided himself with a circular
letter from the hereditary chieftain of the Horde, a personage who
rejoiced in the imposing name of Genghis Khan,* and claimed to be a
descendant of the great Mongol conqueror. This document assured us
a good reception in the aouls through which we passed. Every
Kirghis who saw it treated it with profound respect, and professed
to put all his goods and chattels at our service. But in spite of
this powerful recommendation we met with none of the friendly
cordiality and communicativeness which I had found among the
Bashkirs. A tent with an unlimited quantity of cushions was always
set apart for our accommodation; the sheep were killed and boiled
for our dinner, and the pails of kumyss were regularly brought for
our refreshment; but all this was evidently done as a matter of
duty and not as a spontaneous expression of hospitality. When we
determined once or twice to prolong our visit beyond the term
originally announced, I could perceive that our host was not at all
delighted by the change of our plans. The only consolation we had
was that those who entertained us made no scruples about accepting
payment for the food and shelter supplied.
* I have adopted the ordinary English spelling of this name. The
Kirghiz and the Russians pronounce it "Tchinghiz."
From all this I have no intention of drawing the conclusion that
the Kirghiz are, as a people, inhospitable or unfriendly to
strangers. My experience of them is too limited to warrant any
such inference. The letter of Genghis Khan insured us all the
accommodation we required, but it at the same time gave us a
certain official character not at all favourable to the
establishment of friendly relations. Those with whom we came in
contact regarded us as Russian officials, and suspected us of
having some secret designs. As I endeavoured to discover the
number of their cattle, and to form an approximate estimate of
their annual revenue, they naturally feared--having no conception
of disinterested scientific curiosity--that these data were being
collected for the purpose of increasing the taxes, or with some
similar intention of a sinister kind. Very soon I perceived
clearly that any information we might here collect regarding the
economic conditions of pastoral life would not be of much value,
and I postponed my proposed studies to a more convenient season.
The Kirghiz are, ethnographically speaking, closely allied to the
Bashkirs, but differ from them both in physiognomy and language.
Their features approach much nearer the pure Mongol type, and their
language is a distinct dialect, which a Bashkir or a Tartar of
Kazan has some difficulty in understanding. They are professedly
Mahometans, but their Mahometanism is not of a rigid kind, as may
be seen by the fact that their women do not veil their faces even
in the presence of Ghiaours--a laxness of which the Ghiaour will
certainly not approve if he happen to be sensitive to female beauty
and ugliness. Their mode of life differs from that of the
Bashkirs, but they have proportionately more land and are
consequently still able to lead a purely pastoral life. Near their
western frontier, it is true, they annually let patches of land to
the Russian peasants for the purpose of raising crops; but these
encroachments can never advance very far, for the greater part of
their territory is unsuited to agriculture, on account of a large
admixture of salt in the soil. This fact will have an important
influence on their future. Unlike the Bashkirs, who possess good
arable land, and are consequently on the road to become
agriculturists, they will in all probability continue to live
exclusively by their flocks and herds.
To the southwest of the Lower Volga, in the flat region lying to
the north of the Caucasus, we find another pastoral tribe, the
Kalmyks, differing widely from the two former in language, in
physiognomy, and in religion. Their language, a dialect of the
Mongolian, has no close affinity with any other language in this
part of the world. In respect of religion they are likewise
isolated, for they are Buddhists, and have consequently no co-
religionists nearer than Mongolia or Thibet. But it is their
physiognomy that most strikingly distinguishes them from the
surrounding peoples, and stamps them as Mongols of the purest
water. There is something almost infra-human in their ugliness.
They show in an exaggerated degree all those repulsive traits which
we see toned down and refined in the face of an average Chinaman;
and it is difficult, when we meet them for the first time, to
believe that a human soul lurks behind their expressionless,
flattened faces and small, dull, obliquely set eyes. If the Tartar
and Turkish races are really descended from ancestors of that type,
then we must assume that they have received in the course of time a
large admixture of Aryan or Semitic blood.
But we must not be too hard on the poor Kalmyks, or judge of their
character by their unprepossessing appearance. They are by no
means so unhuman as they look. Men who have lived among them have
assured me that they are decidedly intelligent, especially in all
matters relating to cattle, and that they are--though somewhat
addicted to cattle-lifting and other primitive customs not
tolerated in the more advanced stages of civilisation--by no means
wanting in some of the better qualities of human nature.
Formerly there was a fourth pastoral tribe in this region--the
Nogai Tartars. They occupied the plains to the north of the Sea of
Azof, but they are no longer to be found there. Shortly after the
Crimean war they emigrated to Turkey, and their lands are now
occupied by Russian, German, Bulgarian, and Montenegrin colonists.
Among the pastoral tribes of this region the Kalmyks are recent
intruders. They first appeared in the seventeenth century, and
were long formidable on account of their great numbers and compact
organisation; but in 1771 the majority of them suddenly struck
their tents and retreated to their old home in the north of the
Celestial Empire. Those who remained were easily pacified, and
have long since lost, under the influence of unbroken peace and a
strong Russian administration, their old warlike spirit. Their
latest military exploits were performed during the last years of
the Napoleonic wars, and were not of a very serious kind; a troop
of them accompanied the Russian army, and astonished Western Europe
by their uncouth features, their strange costume, and their
primitive accoutrements, among which their curious bows and arrows
figured conspicuously.
The other pastoral tribes which I have mentioned--Bashkirs,
Kirghiz, and Nogai Tartars--are the last remnants of the famous
marauders who from time immemorial down to a comparatively recent
period held the vast plains of Southern Russia. The long struggle
between them and the agricultural colonists from the northwest,
closely resembling the long struggle between the Red-skins and the
white settlers on the prairies of North America, forms an important
page of Russian history.
For centuries the warlike nomads stoutly resisted all encroachments
on their pasture-grounds, and considered cattle-lifting,
kidnapping, and pillage as a legitimate and honorable occupation.
"Their raids," says an old Byzantine writer, "are as flashes of
lightning, and their retreat is at once heavy and light--heavy from
booty and light from the swiftness of their movements. For them a
peaceful life is a misfortune, and a convenient opportunity for war
is the height of felicity. Worst of all, they are more numerous
than bees in spring, their numbers are uncountable." "Having no
fixed place of abode," says another Byzantine authority, "they seek
to conquer all lands and colonise none. They are flying people,
and therefore cannot be caught. As they have neither towns nor
villages, they must be hunted like wild beasts, and can be fitly
compared only to griffins, which beneficent Nature has banished to
uninhabited regions." As a Persian distich, quoted by Vambery, has
it--
"They came, conquered, burned,
pillaged, murdered, and went."
Their raids are thus described by an old Russian chronicler: "They
burn the villages, the farmyards, and the churches. The land is
turned by them into a desert, and the overgrown fields become the
lair of wild beasts. Many people are led away into slavery; others
are tortured and killed, or die from hunger and thirst. Sad,
weary, stiff from cold, with faces wan from woe, barefoot or naked,
and torn by the thistles, the Russian prisoners trudge along
through an unknown country, and, weeping, say to one another, 'I am
from such a town, and I from such a village.'" And in harmony with
the monastic chroniclers we hear the nameless Slavonic Ossian
wailing for the fallen sons of Rus: "In the Russian land is rarely
heard the voice of the husbandman, but often the cry of the
vultures, fighting with each other over the bodies of the slain;
and the ravens scream as they fly to the spoil."
In spite of the stubborn resistance of the nomads the wave of
colonisation moved steadily onwards until the first years of the
thirteenth century, when it was suddenly checked and thrown back.
A great Mongolian horde from Eastern Asia, far more numerous and
better organized than the local nomadic tribes, overran the whole
country, and for more than two centuries Russia was in a certain
sense ruled by Mongol Khans. As I wish to speak at some length of
this Mongol domination, I shall devote to it a separate chapter.
CHAPTER XIV
THE MONGOL DOMINATION
The Conquest--Genghis Khan and his People--Creation and Rapid
Disintegration of the Mongol Empire--The Golden Horde--The Real
Character of the Mongol Domination--Religious Toleration--Mongol
System of Government--Grand Princes--The Princes of Moscow--
Influence of the Mongol Domination--Practical Importance of the
Subject.
The Tartar invasion, with its direct and indirect consequences, is
a subject which has more than a mere antiquarian interest. To the
influence of the Mongols are commonly attributed many peculiarities
in the actual condition and national character of the Russians of
the present day, and some writers would even have us believe that
the men whom we call Russians are simply Tartars half disguised by
a thin varnish of European civilisation. It may be well,
therefore, to inquire what the Tartar or Mongol domination really
was, and how far it affected the historical development and
national character of the Russian people.
The story of the conquest may be briefly told. In 1224 the
chieftains of the Poloftsi--one of those pastoral tribes which
roamed on the Steppe and habitually carried on a predatory warfare
with the Russians of the south--sent deputies to Mistislaf the
Brave, Prince of Galicia, to inform him that their country had been
invaded from the southeast by strong, cruel enemies called
Tartars*--strange-looking men with brown faces, eyes small and wide
apart, thick lips, broad shoulders, and black hair. "Today," said
the deputies, "they have seized our country, and tomorrow they will
seize yours if you do not help us."
* The word is properly "Tatar," and the Russians write and
pronounce it in this way, but I have preferred to retain the better
known form.
Mistislaf had probably no objection to the Poloftsi being
annihilated by some tribe stronger and fiercer than themselves, for
they gave him a great deal of trouble by their frequent raids; but
he perceived the force of the argument about his own turn coming
next, and thought it wise to assist his usually hostile neighbours.
For the purpose of warding off the danger he called together the
neighbouring Princes, and urged them to join him in an expedition
against the new enemy. The expedition was undertaken, and ended in
disaster. On the Kalka, a small river falling into the Sea of
Azof, the Russian host met the invaders, and was completely routed.
The country was thereby opened to the victors, but they did not
follow up their advantage. After advancing for some distance they
suddenly wheeled round and disappeared.
Thus ended unexpectedly the first visit of these unwelcome
strangers. Thirteen years afterwards they returned, and were not
so easily got rid of. An enormous horde crossed the River Ural and
advanced into the heart of the country, pillaging, burning,
devastating, and murdering. Nowhere did they meet with serious
resistance. The Princes made no attempt to combine against the
common enemy. Nearly all the principal towns were laid in ashes,
and the inhabitants were killed or carried off as slaves. Having
conquered Russia, they advanced westward, and threw all Europe into
alarm. The panic reached even England, and interrupted, it is
said, for a time the herring fishing on the coast. Western Europe,
however, escaped their ravages. After visiting Poland, Hungary,
Bulgaria, Servia, and Dalmatia, they retreated to the Lower Volga,
and the Russian Princes were summoned thither to do homage to the
victorious Khan.
At first the Russians had only very vague notions as to who this
terrible enemy was. The old chronicler remarks briefly: "For our
sins unknown peoples have appeared. No one knows who they are or
whence they have come, or to what race and faith they belong. They
are commonly called Tartars, but some call them Tauermen, and
others Petchenegs. Who they really are is known only to God, and
perhaps to wise men deeply read in books." Some of these "wise men
deeply read in books" supposed them to be the idolatrous Moabites
who had in Old Testament times harassed God's chosen people, whilst
others thought that they must be the descendants of the men whom
Gideon had driven out, of whom a revered saint had prophesied that
they would come in the latter days and conquer the whole earth,
from the East even unto the Euphrates, and from the Tigris even
unto the Black Sea.
We are now happily in a position to dispense with such vague
ethnographical speculations. From the accounts of several European
travellers who visited Tartary about that time, and from the
writings of various Oriental historians, we know a great deal about
these barbarians who conquered Russia and frightened the Western
nations.
The vast region lying to the east of Russia, from the basin of the
Volga to the shores of the Pacific Ocean, was inhabited then, as it
is still, by numerous Tartar and Mongol tribes. These two terms
are often regarded as identical and interchangeable, but they
ought, I think, to be distinguished. From the ethnographic, the
linguistic, and the religious point of view they differ widely from
each other. The Kazan Tartars, the Bashkirs, the Kirghiz, in a
word, all the tribes in the country stretching latitudinally from
the Volga to Kashgar, and longitudinally from the Persian frontier,
the Hindu Kush and the Northern Himalaya, to a line drawn east and
west through the middle of Siberia, belong to the Tartar group;
whereas those further eastward, occupying Mongolia and Manchuria,
are Mongol in the stricter sense of the term.
A very little experience enables the traveller to distinguish
between the two. Both of them have the well-known characteristics
of the Northern Asiatic--the broad flat face, yellow skin, small,
obliquely set eyes, high cheekbones, thin, straggling beard; but
these traits are more strongly marked, more exaggerated, if we may
use such an expression, in the Mongol than in the Tartar. Thus the
Mongol is, according to our conceptions, by far the uglier of the
two, and the man of Tartar race, when seen beside him, appears
almost European by comparison. The distinction is confirmed by a
study of their languages. All the Tartar languages are closely
allied, so that a person of average linguistic talent who has
mastered one of them, whether it be the rude Turki of Central Asia
or the highly polished Turkish of Stambul, can easily acquire any
of the others; whereas even an extensive acquaintance with the
Tartar dialects will be of no practical use to him in learning a
language of the Mongol group. In their religions likewise the two
races differ. The Mongols are as a rule Shamanists or Buddhists,
while the Tartars are Mahometans. Some of the Mongol invaders, it
is true, adopted Mahometanism from the conquered Tartar tribes, and
by this change of religion, which led naturally to intermarriage,
their descendants became gradually blended with the older
population; but the broad line of distinction was not permanently
effaced.
It is often supposed, even by people who profess to be acquainted
with Russian history, that Mongols and Tartars alike first came
westward to the frontiers of Europe with Genghis Khan. This is
true of the Mongols, but so far as the Tartars are concerned it is
an entire mistake. From time immemorial the Tartar tribes roamed
over these territories. Like the Russians, they were conquered by
the Mongol invaders and had long to pay tribute, and when the
Mongol empire crumbled to pieces by internal dissensions and
finally disappeared before the victorious advance of the Russians,
the Tartars reappeared from the confusion without having lost,
notwithstanding an intermixture doubtless of Mongol blood, their
old racial characteristics, their old dialects, and their old
tribal organisation.
The germ of the vast horde which swept over Asia and advanced into
the centre of Europe was a small pastoral tribe of Mongols living
in the hilly country to the north of China, near the sources of the
Amur. This tribe was neither more warlike nor more formidable than
its neighbours till near the close of the twelfth century, when
there appeared in it a man who is described as "a mighty hunter
before the Lord." Of him and his people we have a brief
description by a Chinese author of the time: "A man of gigantic
stature, with broad forehead and long beard, and remarkable for his
bravery. As to his people, their faces are broad, flat, and four-
cornered, with prominent cheek-bones; their eyes have no upper
eyelashes; they have very little hair in their beards and
moustaches; their exterior is very repulsive." This man of
gigantic stature was no other than Genghis Khan. He began by
subduing and incorporating into his army the surrounding tribes,
conquered with their assistance a great part of Northern China, and
then, leaving one of his generals to complete the conquest of the
Celestial Empire, he led his army westward with the ambitious
design of conquering the whole world. "As there is but one God in
heaven," he was wont to say, "so there should be but one ruler on
earth"; and this one universal ruler he himself aspired to be.
A European army necessarily diminishes in force and its existence
becomes more and more imperilled as it advances from its base of
operations into a foreign and hostile country. Not so a horde like
that of Genghis Khan in a country such as that which it had to
traverse. It needed no base of operations, for it took with it its
flocks, its tents, and all its worldly goods. Properly speaking,
it was not an army at all, but rather a people in movement. The
grassy Steppes fed the flocks, and the flocks fed the warriors; and
with such a simple commissariat system there was no necessity for
keeping up communications with the point of departure. Instead of
diminishing in numbers, the horde constantly increased as it moved
forwards. The nomadic tribes which it encountered on its way,
composed of men who found a home wherever they found pasture and
drinking-water, required little persuasion to make them join the
onward movement. By means of this terrible instrument of conquest
Genghis succeeded in creating a colossal Empire, stretching from
the Carpathians to the eastern shores of Asia, and from the Arctic
Ocean to the Himalayas.
Genghis was no mere ruthless destroyer; he was at the same time one
of the greatest administrators the world has ever seen. But his
administrative genius could not work miracles. His vast Empire,
founded on conquest and composed of the most heterogeneous
elements, had no principle of organic life in it, and could not
possibly be long-lived. It had been created by him, and it
perished with him. For some time after his death the dignity of
Grand Khan was held by some one of his descendants, and the
centralised administration was nominally preserved; but the local
rulers rapidly emancipated themselves from the central authority,
and within half a century after the death of its founder the great
Mongol Empire was little more than "a geographical expression."
With the dismemberment of the short-lived Empire the danger for
Eastern Europe was by no means at an end. The independent hordes
were scarcely less formidable than the Empire itself. A grandson
of Genghis formed on the Russian frontier a new State, commonly
known as Kiptchak, or the Golden Horde, and built a capital called
Serai, on one of the arms of the Lower Volga. This capital, which
has since so completely disappeared that there is some doubt as to
its site, is described by Ibn Batuta, who visited it in the
fifteenth century, as a very great, populous, and beautiful city,
possessing many mosques, fine market-places, and broad streets, in
which were to be seen merchants from Babylon, Egypt, Syria, and
other countries. Here lived the Khans of the Golden Horde, who
kept Russia in subjection for two centuries.
In conquering Russia the Mongols had no wish to possess themselves
of the soil, or to take into their own hands the local
administration. What they wanted was not land, of which they had
enough and to spare, but movable property which they might enjoy
without giving up their pastoral, nomadic life. They applied,
therefore, to Russia the same method of extracting supplies as they
had used in other countries. As soon as their authority had been
formally acknowledged they sent officials into the country to
number the inhabitants and to collect an amount of tribute
proportionate to the population. This was a severe burden for the
people, not only on account of the sum demanded, but also on
account of the manner in which it was raised. The exactions and
cruelty of the tax-gatherers led to local insurrections, and the
insurrections were of course always severely punished. But there
was never any general military occupation of the country or any
wholesale confiscations of land, and the existing political
organisation was left undisturbed. The modern method of dealing
with annexed provinces was totally unknown to the Mongols. The
Khans never thought of attempting to denationalise their Russian
subjects. They demanded simply an oath of allegiance from the
Princes* and a certain sum of tribute from the people. The
vanquished were allowed to retain their land, their religion, their
language, their courts of justice, and all their other
institutions.
* During the Mongol domination Russia was composed of a large
number of independent principalities.
The nature of the Mongol domination is well illustrated by the
policy which the conquerors adopted towards the Russian Church.
For more than half a century after the conquest the religion of the
Tartars was a mixture of Buddhism and Paganism, with traces of
Sabaeism or fire-worship. During this period Christianity was more
than simply tolerated. The Grand Khan Kuyuk caused a Christian
chapel to be erected near his domicile, and one of his successors,
Khubilai, was in the habit of publicly taking part in the Easter
festivals. In 1261 the Khan of the Golden Horde allowed the
Russians to found a bishopric in his capital, and several members
of his family adopted Christianity. One of them even founded a
monastery, and became a saint of the Russian Church! The Orthodox
clergy were exempted from the poll-tax, and in the charters granted
to them it was expressly declared that if any one committed
blasphemy against the faith of the Russians he should be put to
death. Some time afterwards the Golden Horde was converted to
Islam, but the Khans did not on that account change their policy.
They continued to favour the clergy, and their protection was long
remembered. Many generations later, when the property of the
Church was threatened by the autocratic power, refractory
ecclesiastics contrasted the policy of the Orthodox Sovereign with
that of the "godless Tartars," much to the advantage of the latter.
At first there was and could be very little mutual confidence
between the conquerors and the conquered. The Princes anxiously
looked for an opportunity of throwing off the galling yoke, and the
people chafed under the exactions and cruelty of the tribute-
collectors, whilst the Khans took precautions to prevent
insurrection, and threatened to devastate the country if their
authority was not respected. But in the course of time this mutual
distrust and hostility greatly lessened. When the Princes found by
experience that all attempts at resistance were fruitless, they
became reconciled to their new position, and instead of seeking to
throw off the Khan's authority, they tried to gain his favour, in
the hope of forwarding their personal interests. For this purpose
they paid frequent visits to the Tartar Suzerain, made rich
presents to his wives and courtiers, received from him charters
confirming their authority, and sometimes even married members of
his family. Some of them used the favour thus acquired for
extending their possessions at the expense of neighbouring Princes
of their own race, and did not hesitate to call in Tartar hordes to
their assistance. The Khans, in their turn, placed greater
confidence in their vassals, entrusted them with the task of
collecting the tribute, recalled their own officials who were a
constant eyesore to the people, and abstained from all interference
in the internal affairs of the principalities so long as the
tribute was regularly paid. The Princes acted, in short, as the
Khan's lieutenants, and became to a certain extent Tartarised.
Some of them carried this policy so far that they were reproached
by the people with "loving beyond measure the Tartars and their
language, and with giving them too freely land, and gold, and goods
of every kind."
Had the Khans of the Golden Horde been prudent, far-seeing
statesmen, they might have long retained their supremacy over
Russia. In reality they showed themselves miserably deficient in
political talent. Seeking merely to extract from the country as
much tribute as possible, they overlooked all higher
considerations, and by this culpable shortsightedness prepared
their own political ruin. Instead of keeping all the Russian
Princes on the same level and thereby rendering them all equally
feeble, they were constantly bribed or cajoled into giving to one
or more of their vassals a pre-eminence over the others. At first
this pre-eminence consisted in little more than the empty title of
Grand Prince; but the vassals thus favoured soon transformed the
barren distinction into a genuine power by arrogating to themselves
the exclusive right of holding direct communications with the
Horde, and compelling the minor Princes to deliver to them the
Mongol tribute. If any of the lesser Princes refused to
acknowledge this intermediate authority, the Grand Prince could
easily crush them by representing them at the Horde as rebels.
Such an accusation would cause the accused to be summoned before
the Supreme Tribunal, where the procedure was extremely summary and
the Grand Prince had always the means of obtaining a decision in
his own favour.
Of the Princes who strove in this way to increase their influence,
the most successful were the Grand Princes of Moscow. They were
not a chivalrous race, or one with which the severe moralist can
sympathise, but they were largely endowed with cunning, tact, and
perseverance, and were little hampered by conscientious scruples.
Having early discovered that the liberal distribution of money at
the Tartar court was the surest means of gaining favour, they lived
parsimoniously at home and spent their savings at the Horde. To
secure the continuance of the favour thus acquired, they were ready
to form matrimonial alliances with the Khan's family, and to act
zealously as his lieutenants. When Novgorod, the haughty,
turbulent republic, refused to pay the yearly tribute, they quelled
the insurrection and punished the leaders; and when the inhabitants
of Tver rose against the Tartars and compelled their Prince to make
common cause with them, the wily Muscovite hastened to the Tartar
court and received from the Khan the revolted principality, with
50,000 Tartars to support his authority.
Thus those cunning Moscow Princes "loved the Tartars beyond
measure" so long as the Khan was irresistibly powerful, but as his
power waned they stood forth as his rivals. When the Golden Horde,
like the great Empire of which it had once formed a part, fell to
pieces in the fifteenth century, these ambitious Princes read the
signs of the times, and put themselves at the head of the
liberation movement, which was at first unsuccessful, but
ultimately freed the country from the hated yoke.
From this brief sketch of the Mongol domination the reader will
readily understand that it did not leave any deep, lasting
impression on the people. The invaders never settled in Russia
proper, and never amalgamated with the native population. So long
as they retained their semi-pagan, semi-Buddhistic religion, a
certain number of their notables became Christians and were
absorbed by the Russian Noblesse; but as soon as the Horde adopted
Islam this movement was arrested. There was no blending of the two
races such as has taken place--and is still taking place--between
the Russian peasantry and the Finnish tribes of the North. The
Russians remained Christians, and the Tartars remained Mahometans;
and this difference of religion raised an impassable barrier
between the two nationalities.
It must, however, be admitted that the Tartar domination, though it
had little influence on the life and habits of the people, had a
considerable influence on the political development of the nation.
At the time of the conquest Russia was composed of a large number
of independent principalities, all governed by descendants of
Rurik. As these principalities were not geographical or
ethnographical units, but mere artificial, arbitrarily defined
districts, which were regularly subdivided or combined according to
the hereditary rights of the Princes, it is highly probable that
they would in any case have been sooner or later united under one
sceptre; but it is quite certain that the policy of the Khans
helped to accelerate this unification and to create the autocratic
power which has since been wielded by the Tsars. If the
principalities had been united without foreign interference we
should probably have found in the united State some form of
political organisation corresponding to that which existed in the
component parts--some mixed form of government, in which the
political power would have been more or less equally divided
between the Tsar and the people. The Tartar rule interrupted this
normal development by extinguishing all free political life. The
first Tsars of Muscovy were the political descendants, not of the
old independent Princes, but of the Mongol Khans. It may be said,
therefore, that the autocratic power, which has been during the
last four centuries out of all comparison the most important factor
in Russian history, was in a certain sense created by the Mongol
domination.
CHAPTER XV
THE COSSACKS
Lawlessness on the Steppe--Slave-markets of the Crimea--The
Military Cordon and the Free Cossacks--The Zaporovian Commonwealth
Compared with Sparta and with the Mediaeval Military Orders--The
Cossacks of the Don, of the Volga, and of the Ural--Border Warfare--
The Modern Cossacks--Land Tenure among the Cossacks of the Don--
The Transition from Pastoral to Agriculture Life--"Universal Law"
of Social Development--Communal versus Private Property--Flogging
as a Means of Land-registration.
No sooner had the Grand Princes of Moscow thrown off the Mongol
yoke and become independent Tsars of Muscovy than they began that
eastward territorial expansion which has been going on steadily
ever since, and which culminated in the occupation of Talienwan and
Port Arthur. Ivan the Terrible conquered the Khanates of Kazan and
Astrakhan (1552-54) and reduced to nominal subjection the Bashkir
and Kirghiz tribes in the vicinity of the Volga, but he did not
thereby establish law and order on the Steppe. The lawless tribes
retained their old pastoral mode of life and predatory habits, and
harassed the Russian agricultural population of the outlying
provinces in the same way as the Red Indians in America used to
harass the white colonists of the Far West. A large section of the
Horde, inhabiting the Crimea and the Steppe to the north of the
Black Sea, escaped annexation by submitting to the Ottoman Turks
and becoming tributaries of the Sultan.
The Turks were at that time a formidable power, with which the
Tsars of Muscovy were too weak to cope successfully, and the Khan
of the Crimea could always, when hard pressed by his northern
neighbours, obtain assistance from Constantinople. This potentate
exercised a nominal authority over the pastoral tribes which roamed
on the Steppe between the Crimea and the Russian frontier, but he
had neither the power nor the desire to control their aggressive
tendencies. Their raids in Russian and Polish territory ensured,
among other advantages, a regular and plentiful supply of slaves,
which formed the chief article of export from Kaffa--the modern
Theodosia--and from the other seaports of the coast.
Of this slave trade, which flourished down to 1783, when the Crimea
was finally conquered and annexed by Russia, we have a graphic
account by an eye-witness, a Lithuanian traveller of the sixteenth
century. "Ships from Asia," he says, "bring arms, clothes, and
horses to the Crimean Tartars, and start on the homeward voyage
laden with slaves. It is for this kind of merchandise alone that
the Crimean markets are remarkable. Slaves may be always had for
sale as a pledge or as a present, and every one rich enough to have
a horse deals in them. If a man wishes to buy clothes, arms, or
horses, and does not happen to have at the moment any slaves, he
takes on credit the articles required, and makes a formal promise
to deliver at a certain time a certain number of people of our
blood--being convinced that he can get by that time the requisite
number. And these promises are always accurately fulfilled, as if
those who made them had always a supply of our people in their
courtyards. A Jewish money-changer, sitting at the gate of Tauris
and seeing constantly the countless multitude of our countrymen led
in as captives, asked us whether there still remained any people in
our land, and whence came such a multitude of them. The stronger
of these captives, branded on the forehead and cheeks and manacled
or fettered, are tortured by severe labour all day, and are shut up
in dark cells at night. They are kept alive by small quantities of
food, composed chiefly of the flesh of animals that have died--
putrid, covered with maggots, disgusting even to dogs. Women, who
are more tender, are treated in a different fashion; some of them
who can sing and play are employed to amuse the guests at
festivals.
"When the slaves are led out for sale they walk to the marketplace
in single file, like storks on the wing, in whole dozens, chained
together by the neck, and are there sold by auction. The
auctioneer shouts loudly that they are 'the newest arrivals,
simple, and not cunning, lately captured from the people of the
kingdom (Poland), and not from Muscovy'; for the Muscovite race,
being crafty and deceitful, does not bring a good price. This kind
of merchandise is appraised with great accuracy in the Crimea, and
is bought by foreign merchants at a high price, in order to be sold
at a still higher rate to blacker nations, such as Saracens,
Persians, Indians, Arabs, Syrians, and Assyrians. When a purchase
is made the teeth are examined, to see that they are neither few
nor discoloured. At the same time the more hidden parts of the
body are carefully inspected, and if a mole, excrescence, wound, or
other latent defect is discovered, the bargain is rescinded. But
notwithstanding these investigations the cunning slave-dealers and
brokers succeed in cheating the buyers; for when they have valuable
boys and girls, they do not at once produce them, but first fatten
them, clothe them in silk, and put powder and rouge on their
cheeks, so as to sell them at a better price. Sometimes beautiful
and perfect maidens of our nation bring their weight in gold. This
takes place in all the towns of the peninsula, but especially in
Kaffa."*
* Michalonis Litvani, "De moribus Tartarorum Fragmina," X.,
Basilliae, 1615.
To protect the agricultural population of the Steppe against the
raids of these thieving, cattle-lifting, kidnapping neighbours, the
Tsars of Muscovy and the Kings of Poland built forts, constructed
palisades, dug trenches, and kept up a regular military cordon.
The troops composing this cordon were called Cossacks; but these
were not the "Free Cossacks" best known to history and romance.
These latter lived beyond the frontier on the debatable land which
lay between the two hostile races, and there they formed self-
governing military communities. Each one of the rivers flowing
southwards--the Dnieper, the Don, the Volga, and the Yaik or Ural--
was held by a community of these Free Cossacks, and no one, whether
Christian or Tartar, was allowed to pass through their territory
without their permission.
Officially the Free Cossacks were Russians, for they professed to
be champions of Orthodox Christianity, and--with the exception of
those of the Dnieper--loyal subjects of the Tsar; but in reality
they were something different. Though they were Russian by origin,
language, and sympathy, the habit of kidnapping Tartar women
introduced among them a certain admixture of Tartar blood. Though
self-constituted champions of Christianity and haters of Islam,
they troubled themselves very little with religion, and did not
submit to the ecclesiastical authorities. As to their religious
status, it cannot be easily defined. Whilst professing allegiance
and devotion to the Tsar, they did not think it necessary to obey
him, except in so far as his orders suited their own convenience.
And the Tsar, it must be confessed, acted towards them in a similar
fashion. When he found it convenient he called them his faithful
subjects; and when complaints were made to him about their raids in
Turkish territory, he declared that they were not his subjects, but
runaways and brigands, and that the Sultan might punish them as he
saw fit. At the same time, the so-called runaways and brigands
regularly received supplies and ammunition from Moscow, as is amply
proved by recently-published documents. Down to the middle of the
seventeenth century the Cossacks of the Dnieper stood in a similar
relation to the Polish kings; but at that time they threw off their
allegiance to Poland, and became subjects of the Tsars of Muscovy.
Of these semi-independent military communities, which formed a
continuous barrier along the southern and southeastern frontier,
the most celebrated were the Zaporovians* of the Dnieper, and the
Cossacks of the Don.
* The name "Zaporovians," by which they are known in the West, is a
corruption of the Russian word Zaporozhtsi, which means "Those who
live beyond the rapids."
The Zaporovian Commonwealth has been compared sometimes to ancient
Sparta, and sometimes to the mediaeval Military Orders, but it had
in reality quite a different character. In Sparta the nobles kept
in subjection a large population of slaves, and were themselves
constantly under the severe discipline of the magistrates. These
Cossacks of the Dnieper, on the contrary, lived by fishing,
hunting, and marauding, and knew nothing of discipline, except in
time of war. Amongst all the inhabitants of the Setch--so the
fortified camp was called--there reigned the most perfect equality.
The common saying, "Bear patiently, Cossack; you will one day be
Ataman!" was often realised; for every year the office-bearers laid
down the insignia of office in presence of the general assembly,
and after thanking the brotherhood for the honour they had enjoyed,
retired to their former position of common Cossack. At the
election which followed this ceremony any member could be chosen
chief of his kuren, or company, and any chief of a kuren could be
chosen Ataman.
The comparison of these bold Borderers with the mediaeval Military
Orders is scarcely less forced. They call themselves, indeed,
Lytsars--a corruption of the Russian word Ritsar, which is in its
turn a corruption of the German Ritter--talked of knightly honour
(lytsarskaya tchest'), and sometimes proclaimed themselves the
champions of Greek Orthodoxy against the Roman Catholicism of the
Poles and the Mahometanism of the Tartars; but religion occupied in
their minds a very secondary place. Their great object in life was
the acquisition of booty. To attain this object they lived in
intermittent warfare with the Tartars, lifted their cattle,
pillaged their aouls, swept the Black Sea in flotillas of small
boats, and occasionally sacked important coast towns, such as Varna
and Sinope. When Tartar booty could not be easily obtained, they
turned their attention to the Slavonic populations; and when hard
pressed by Christian potentates, they did not hesitate to put
themselves under the protection of the Sultan.
The Cossacks of the Don, of the Volga, and of the Ural had a
somewhat different organisation. They had no fortified camp like
the Setch, but lived in villages, and assembled as necessity
demanded. As they were completely beyond the sphere of Polish
influence, they knew nothing about "knightly honour" and similar
conceptions of Western chivalry; they even adopted many Tartar
customs, and loved in time of peace to strut about in gorgeous
Tartar costumes. Besides this, they were nearly all emigrants from
Great Russia, and mostly Old Ritualists or Sectarians, whilst the
Zaporovians were Little Russians and Orthodox.
These military communities rendered valuable service to Russia.
The best means of protecting the southern frontier was to have as
allies a large body of men leading the same kind of life and
capable of carrying on the same kind of warfare as the nomadic
marauders; and such a body of men were the Free Cossacks. The
sentiment of self-preservation and the desire of booty kept them
constantly on the alert. By sending out small parties in all
directions, by "procuring tongues"--that is to say, by kidnapping
and torturing straggling Tartars with a view to extracting
information from them--and by keeping spies in the enemy's
territory, they were generally apprised beforehand of any intended
incursion. When danger threatened, the ordinary precautions were
redoubled. Day and night patrols kept watch at the points where
the enemy was expected, and as soon as sure signs of his approach
were discovered a pile of tarred barrels prepared for the purpose
was fired to give the alarm. Rapidly the signal was repeated at
one point of observation after another, and by this primitive
system of telegraphy in the course of a few hours the whole
district was up in arms. If the invaders were not too numerous,
they were at once attacked and driven back. If they could not be
successfully resisted, they were allowed to pass; but a troop of
Cossacks was sent to pillage their aouls in their absence, whilst
another and larger force was collected, in order to intercept them
when they were returning home laden with booty. Thus many a
nameless battle was fought on the trackless Steppe, and many brave
men fell unhonoured and unsung:
"Illacrymabiles
Urgentur ignotique longa
Nocte, carent quia vate sacro."
Notwithstanding these valuable services, the Cossack communities
were a constant source of diplomatic difficulties and political
dangers. As they paid very little attention to the orders of the
Government, they supplied the Sultan with any number of casi belli,
and were often ready to turn their arms against the power to which
they professed allegiance. During "the troublous times," for
example, when the national existence was endangered by civil strife
and foreign invasion, they overran the country, robbing, pillaging,
and burning as they were wont to do in the Tartar aouls. At a
later period the Don Cossacks twice raised formidable
insurrections--first under Stenka Razin (1670), and secondly under
Pugatchef (1773)--and during the war between Peter the Great and
Charles XII. of Sweden the Zaporovians took the side of the Swedish
king.
The Government naturally strove to put an end to this danger, and
ultimately succeeded. All the Cossacks were deprived of their
independence, but the fate of the various communities was
different. Those of the Volga were transfered to the Terek, where
they had abundant occupation in guarding the frontier against the
incursions of the Eastern Caucasian tribes. The Zaporovians held
tenaciously to their "Dnieper liberties," and resisted all
interference, till they were forcibly disbanded in the time of
Catherine II. The majority of them fled to Turkey, where some of
their descendants are still to be found, and the remainder were
settled on the Kuban, where they could lead their old life by
carrying on an irregular warfare with the tribes of the Western
Caucasus. Since the capture of Shamyl and the pacification of the
Caucasus, this Cossack population of the Kuban and the Terek,
extending in an unbroken line from the Sea of Azof to the Caspian,
have been able to turn their attention to peaceful pursuits, and
now raise large quantities of wheat for exportation; but they still
retain their martial bearing, and some of them regret the good old
times when a brush with the Circassians was an ordinary occurrence
and the work of tilling the soil was often diversified with a more
exciting kind of occupation.
The Cossacks of the Ural and the Don have been allowed to remain in
their old homes, but they have been deprived of their independence
and self-government, and their social organisation has been
completely changed. The boisterous popular assemblies which
formerly decided all public affairs have been abolished, and the
custom of choosing the Ataman and other office-bearers by popular
election has been replaced by a system of regular promotion,
according to rules elaborated in St. Petersburg. The officers and
their families now compose a kind of hereditary aristocracy which
has succeeded in appropriating, by means of Imperial grants, a
large portion of the land which was formerly common property. As
the Empire expanded in Asia the system of protecting the parties by
Cossack colonists was extended eastwards, so now there is a belt of
Cossack territory stretching almost without interruption from the
banks of the Don to the coast of the Pacific. It is divided into
eleven sections, in each of which is settled a Cossack corps with a
separate administration.
When universal military service was introduced, in 1873, the
Cossacks were brought under the new law, but in order to preserve
their military traditions and habits they were allowed to retain,
with certain modifications, their old organisation, rights, and
privileges. In return for a large amount of fertile land and
exemption from direct taxation, they have to equip themselves at
their own expense, and serve for twenty years, of which three are
spent in preparatory training, twelve in the active army, and five
in the reserve. This system gives to the army a contingent of
about 330,000 men--divided into 890 squadrons and 108 infantry
companies--with 236 guns.
The Cossacks in active service are to be met with in all parts of
the Empire, from the Prussian to the Chinese frontier. In the
Asiatic Provinces their services are invaluable. Capable of
enduring an incredible amount of fatigue and all manner of
privations, they can live and thrive in conditions which would soon
disable regular troops. The capacity of self-adaptation, which is
characteristic of the Russian people generally, is possessed by
them in the highest degree. When placed on some distant Asiatic
frontier they can at once transform themselves into squatters--
building their own houses, raising crops of grain, and living as
colonists without neglecting their military duties.
I have sometimes heard it asserted by military men that the Cossack
organisation is an antiquated institution, and that the soldiers
which it produces, however useful they may be in Central Asia,
would be of little service in regular European warfare. Whether
this view, which received some confirmation in the Russo-Turkish
War of 1877-78, is true or false I cannot pretend to say, for it is
a subject on which a civilian has no right to speak; but I may
remark that the Cossacks themselves are not by any means of that
opinion. They regard themselves as the most valuable troops which
the Tsar possesses, believing themselves capable of performing
anything within the bounds of human possibility, and a good deal
that lies beyond that limit. More than once Don Cossacks have
assured me that if the Tsar had allowed them to fit out a flotilla
of small boats during the Crimean War they would have captured the
British fleet, as their ancestors used to capture Turkish galleys
on the Black Sea!
In old times, throughout the whole territory of the Don Cossacks,
agriculture was prohibited on pain of death. It is generally
supposed that this measure was adopted with a view to preserve the
martial spirit of the inhabitants, but it may be explained
otherwise. The great majority of the Cossacks, averse to all
regular, laborious occupations, wished to live by fishing, hunting,
cattle-breeding, and marauding, but there was always amongst them a
considerable number of immigrants--runaway serfs from the interior--
who had been accustomed to live by agriculture. These latter
wished to raise crops on the fertile virgin soil, and if they had
been allowed to do so they would to some extent have spoiled the
pastures. We have here, I believe, the true reason for the above-
mentioned prohibition, and this view is strongly confirmed by
analogous facts which I have observed in another locality. In the
Kirghiz territory the poorer inhabitants of the aouls near the
frontier, having few or no cattle, wish to let part of the common
land to the neighbouring Russian peasantry for agricultural
purposes; but the richer inhabitants, who possess flocks and herds,
strenuously oppose this movement, and would doubtless prohibit it
under pain of death if they had the power, because all agricultural
encroachments diminish the pasture-land.
Whatever was the real reason of the prohibition, practical
necessity proved in the long run too strong for the anti-
agriculturists. As the population augmented and the opportunities
for marauding decreased, the majority had to overcome their
repugnance to husbandry; and soon large patches of ploughed land or
waving grain were to be seen in the vicinity of the stanitsas, as
the Cossack villages are termed. At first there was no attempt to
regulate this new use of the ager publicus. Each Cossack who
wished to raise a crop ploughed and sowed wherever he thought fit,
and retained as long as he chose the land thus appropriated; and
when the soil began to show signs of exhaustion he abandoned his
plot and ploughed elsewhere. But this unregulated use of the
Communal property could not long continue. As the number of
agriculturists increased, quarrels frequently arose, and sometimes
terminated in bloodshed. Still worse evils appeared when markets
were created in the vicinity, and it became possible to sell the
grain for exportation. In some stanitsas the richer families
appropriated enormous quantities of the common land by using
several teams of oxen, or by hiring peasants in the nearest
villages to come and plough for them; and instead of abandoning the
land after raising two or three crops they retained possession of
it, and came to regard it as their private property. Thus the
whole of the arable land, or at least the best part of it, became
actually, if not legally, the private property of a few families,
whilst the less energetic or less fortunate inhabitants of the
stanitsa had only parcels of comparatively barren soil, or had no
land whatever, and became mere agricultural labourers.
After a time this injustice was remedied. The landless members
justly complained that they had to bear the same burdens as those
who possessed the land, and that therefore they ought to enjoy the
same privileges. The old spirit of equality was still strong
amongst them, and they ultimately succeeded in asserting their
rights. In accordance with their demands the appropriated land was
confiscated by the Commune, and the system of periodical
redistributions was introduced. By this system each adult male
possesses a share of the land.
These facts tend to throw light on some of the dark questions of
social development in its early stages.
So long as a village community leads a purely pastoral life, and
possesses an abundance of land, there is no reason why the
individuals or the families of which it is composed should divide
the land into private lots, and there are very potent reasons why
they should not adopt such a course. To give the division of the
land any practical significance, it would be necessary to raise
fences of some kind, and these fences, requiring for their
construction a certain amount of labour, would prove merely a
useless encumbrance, for it is much more convenient that all the
sheep and cattle should graze together. If there is a scarcity of
pasture, and consequently a conflict of interest among the
families, the enjoyment of the common land will be regulated not by
raising fences, but by simply limiting the number of sheep and
cattle which each family is entitled to put upon the pasturage, as
is done in many Russian villages at the present day. When any one
desires to keep more sheep and cattle than the maximum to which he
is entitled, he pays to the others a certain compensation. Thus,
we see, in pastoral life the dividing of the common land is
unnecessary and inexpedient, and consequently private property in
land is not likely to come into existence.
With the introduction of agriculture appears a tendency to divide
the land among the families composing the community, for each
family living by husbandry requires a definite portion of the soil.
If the land suitable for agricultural purposes be plentiful, each
head of a family may be allowed to take possession of as much of it
as he requires, as was formerly done in the Cossack stanitsas; if,
on the contrary, the area of arable land is small, as is the case
in some Bashkir aouls, there will probably be a regular allotment
of it among the families.
With the tendency to divide the land into definite portions arises
a conflict between the principle of communal and the principle of
private property. Those who obtain definite portions of the soil
are in general likely to keep them and transmit them to their
descendants. In a country, however, like the Steppe--and it is
only of such countries that I am at present speaking--the nature of
the soil and the system of agriculture militate against this
conversion of simple possession into a right of property. A plot
of land is commonly cultivated for only three or four years in
succession. It is then abandoned for at least double that period,
and the cultivators remove to some other portion of the communal
territory. After a time, it is true, they return to the old
portion, which has been in the meantime lying fallow; but as the
soil is tolerably equal in quality, the families or individuals
have no reason to desire the precise plots which they formerly
possessed. Under such circumstances the principle of private
property in the land is not likely to strike root; each family
insists on possessing a certain QUANTITY rather than a certain PLOT
of land, and contents itself with a right of usufruct, whilst the
right of property remains in the hands of the Commune; and it must
not be forgotten that the difference between usufruct and property
here is of great practical importance, for so long as the Commune
retains the right of property it may re-allot the land in any way
it thinks fit.
As the population increases and land becomes less plentiful, the
primitive method of agriculture above alluded to gives place to a
less primitive method, commonly known as "the three-field system,"
according to which the cultivators do not migrate periodically from
one part of the communal territory to another, but till always the
same fields, and are obliged to manure the plots which they occupy.
The principle of communal property rarely survives this change, for
by long possession the families acquire a prescriptive right to the
portions which they cultivate, and those who manure their land well
naturally object to exchange it for land which has been held by
indolent, improvident neighbours. In Russia, however, this change
has not destroyed the principle of communal property. Though the
three-field system has been in use for many generations in the
central provinces, the communal principle, with its periodical re-
allotment of the land, still remains intact.
For the student of sociology the past history and actual condition
of the Don Cossacks present many other features equally interesting
and instructive. He may there see, for instance, how an
aristocracy can be created by military promotion, and how serfage
may originate and become a recognised institution without any
legislative enactment. If he takes an interest in peculiar
manifestations of religious thought and feeling, he will find a
rich field of investigation in the countless religious sects; and
if he is a collector of quaint old customs, he will not lack
occupation.
One curious custom, which has very recently died out, I may here
mention by way of illustration. As the Cossacks knew very little
about land-surveying, and still less about land-registration, the
precise boundary between two contiguous yurts--as the communal land
of a stanitsa was called--was often a matter of uncertainty and a
fruitful source of disputes. When the boundary was once
determined, the following method of registering it was employed.
All the boys of the two stanitsas were collected and driven in a
body like sheep to the intervening frontier. The whole population
then walked along the frontier that had been agreed upon, and at
each landmark a number of boys were soundly whipped and allowed to
run home! This was done in the hope that the victims would
remember, as long as they lived, the spot where they had received
their unmerited castigation.* The device, I have been assured, was
generally very effective, but it was not always quite successful.
Whether from the castigation not being sufficiently severe, or from
some other defect in the method, it sometimes happened that
disputes afterwards arose, and the whipped boys, now grown up to
manhood, gave conflicting testimony. When such a case occurred the
following expedient was adopted. One of the oldest inhabitants was
chosen as arbiter, and made to swear on the Scriptures that he
would act honestly to the best of his knowledge; then taking an
Icon in his hand, he walked along what he believed to be the old
frontier. Whether he made mistakes or not, his decision was
accepted by both parties and regarded as final. This custom
existed in some stanitsas down to the year 1850, when the
boundaries were clearly determined by Government officials.
* A custom of this kind, I am told, existed not very long ago in
England and is still spoken of as "the beating of the bounds."
CHAPTER XVI
FOREIGN COLONISTS ON THE STEPPE
The Steppe--Variety of Races, Languages, and Religions--The German
Colonists--In What Sense the Russians are an Imitative People--The
Mennonites--Climate and Arboriculture--Bulgarian Colonists--Tartar-
Speaking Greeks--Jewish Agriculturists--Russification--A Circassian
Scotchman--Numerical Strength of the Foreign Element.
In European Russia the struggle between agriculture and nomadic
barbarism is now a thing of the past, and the fertile Steppe, which
was for centuries a battle-ground of the Aryan and Turanian races,
has been incorporated into the dominions of the Tsar. The nomadic
tribes have been partly driven out and partly pacified and parked
in "reserves," and the territory which they so long and so
stubbornly defended is now studded with peaceful villages and
tilled by laborious agriculturists.
In traversing this region the ordinary tourist will find little to
interest him. He will see nothing which he can possibly dignify by
the name of scenery, and he may journey on for many days without
having any occasion to make an entry in his note-book. If he
should happen, however, to be an ethnologist and linguist, he may
find occupation, for he will here meet with fragments of many
different races and a variety of foreign tongues.
This ethnological variety is the result of a policy inaugurated by
Catherine II. So long as the southern frontier was pushed forward
slowly, the acquired territory was regularly filled up by Russian
peasants from the central provinces who were anxious to obtain more
land and more liberty than they enjoyed in their native villages;
but during "the glorious age of Catherine" the frontier was pushed
forward so rapidly that the old method of spontaneous emigration no
longer sufficed to people the annexed territory. The Empress had
recourse, therefore, to organised emigration from foreign
countries. Her diplomatic representatives in Western Europe tried
to induce artisans and peasants to emigrate to Russia, and special
agents were sent to various countries to supplement the efforts of
the diplomatists. Thousands accepted the invitation, and were for
the most part settled on the land which had been recently the
pasture-ground of the nomadic hordes.
This policy was adopted by succeeding sovereigns, and the
consequence of it has been that Southern Russia now contains a
variety of races such as is to be found, perhaps, nowhere else in
Europe. The official statistics of New Russia alone--that is to
say, the provinces of Ekaterinoslaf, Tauride, Kherson, and
Bessarabia--enumerate the following nationalities: Great Russians,
Little Russians, Poles, Servians, Montenegrins, Bulgarians,
Moldavians, Germans, English, Swedes, Swiss, French, Italians,
Greeks, Armenians, Tartars, Mordwa, Jews, and Gypsies. The
religions are almost equally numerous. The statistics speak of
Greek Orthodox, Roman Catholics, Gregorians, Lutherans, Calvinists,
Anglicans, Mennonites, Separatists, Pietists, Karaim Jews,
Talmudists, Mahometans, and numerous Russian sects, such as the
Molokanye and the Skoptsi or Eunuchs. America herself could
scarcely show a more motley list in her statistics of population.
It is but fair to state that the above list, though literally
correct, does not give a true idea of the actual population. The
great body of the inhabitants are Russian and Orthodox, whilst
several of the nationalities named are represented by a small
number of souls--some of them, such as the French, being found
exclusively in the towns. Still, the variety even in the rural
population is very great. Once, in the space of three days, and
using only the most primitive means of conveyance, I visited
colonies of Greeks, Germans, Servians, Bulgarians, Montenegrins,
and Jews.
Of all the foreign colonists the Germans are by far the most
numerous. The object of the Government in inviting them to settle
in the country was that they should till the unoccupied land and
thereby increase the national wealth, and that they should at the
same time exercise a civilising influence on the Russian peasantry
in their vicinity. In this latter respect they have totally failed
to fulfil their mission. A Russian village, situated in the midst
of German colonies, shows generally, so far as I could observe, no
signs of German influence. Each nationality lives more majorum,
and holds as little communication as possible with the other. The
muzhik observes carefully--for he is very curious--the mode of life
of his more advanced neighbours, but he never thinks of adopting
it. He looks upon Germans almost as beings of a different world--
as a wonderfully cunning and ingenious people, who have been
endowed by Providence with peculiar qualities not possessed by
ordinary Orthodox humanity. To him it seems in the nature of
things that Germans should live in large, clean, well-built houses,
in the same way as it is in the nature of things that birds should
build nests; and as it has probably never occurred to a human being
to build a nest for himself and his family, so it never occurs to a
Russian peasant to build a house on the German model. Germans are
Germans, and Russians are Russians--and there is nothing more to be
said on the subject.
This stubbornly conservative spirit of the peasantry who live in
the neighbourhood of Germans seems to give the lie direct to the
oft-repeated and universally believed assertion that Russians are
an imitative people strongly disposed to adopt the manners and
customs of any foreigners with whom they may come in contact. The
Russian, it is said, changes his nationality as easily as he
changes his coat, and derives great satisfaction from wearing some
nationality that does not belong to him; but here we have an
important fact which appears to prove the contrary.
The truth is that in this matter we must distinguish between the
Noblesse and the peasantry. The nobles are singularly prone to
adopt foreign manners, customs, and institutions; the peasants, on
the contrary, are as a rule decidedly conservative. It must not,
however, be supposed that this proceeds from a difference of race;
the difference is to be explained by the past history of the two
classes. Like all other peoples, the Russians are strongly
conservative so long as they remain in what may be termed their
primitive moral habitat--that is to say, so long as external
circumstances do not force them out of their accustomed traditional
groove. The Noblesse were long ago violently forced out of their
old groove by the reforming Tsars, and since that time they have
been so constantly driven hither and thither by foreign influences
that they have never been able to form a new one. Thus they easily
enter upon any new path which seems to them profitable or
attractive. The great mass of the people, on the contrary, too
heavy to be thus lifted out of the guiding influence of custom and
tradition, are still animated with a strongly conservative spirit.
In confirmation of this view I may mention two facts which have
often attracted my attention. The first is that the Molokanye--a
primitive Evangelical sect of which I shall speak at length in the
next chapter--succumb gradually to German influence; by becoming
heretics in religion they free themselves from one of the strongest
bonds attaching them to the past, and soon become heretics in
things secular. The second fact is that even the Orthodox peasant,
when placed by circumstances in some new sphere of activity,
readily adopts whatever seems profitable. Take, for example, the
peasants who abandon agriculture and embark in industrial
enterprises; finding themselves, as it were, in a new world, in
which their old traditional notions are totally inapplicable, they
have no hesitation in adopting foreign ideas and foreign
inventions. And when once they have chosen this new path, they are
much more "go-ahead" than the Germans. Freed alike from the
trammels of hereditary conceptions and from the prudence which
experience generates, they often give a loose rein to their
impulsive character, and enter freely on the wildest speculations.
The marked contrast presented by a German colony and a Russian
village in close proximity with each other is often used to
illustrate the superiority of the Teutonic over the Slavonic race,
and in order to make the contrast more striking, the Mennonite
colonies are generally taken as the representatives of the Germans.
Without entering here on the general question, I must say that this
method of argumentation is scarcely fair. The Mennonites, who
formerly lived in the neighbourhood of Danzig and emigrated from
Prussia in order to escape the military conscription, brought with
them to their new home a large store of useful technical knowledge
and a considerable amount of capital, and they received a quantity
of land very much greater than the Russian peasants possess.
Besides this, they enjoyed until very recently several valuable
privileges. They were entirely exempted from military service and
almost entirely exempted from taxation. Altogether their lines
fell in very pleasant places. In material and moral well-being
they stand as far above the majority of the ordinary German
colonists as these latter do above their Russian neighbours. Even
in the richest districts of Germany their prosperity would attract
attention. To compare these rich, privileged, well-educated
farmers with the poor, heavily taxed, uneducated peasantry, and to
draw from the comparison conclusions concerning the capabilities of
the two races, is a proceeding so absurd that it requires no
further comment.
To the wearied traveller who has been living for some time in
Russian villages, one of these Mennonite colonies seems an earthly
paradise. In a little hollow, perhaps by the side of a
watercourse, he suddenly comes on a long row of high-roofed houses
half concealed in trees. The trees may be found on closer
inspection to be little better than mere saplings; but after a long
journey on the bare Steppe, where there is neither tree nor bush of
any kind, the foliage, scant as it is, appears singularly inviting.
The houses are large, well arranged, and kept in such thoroughly
good repair that they always appear to be newly built. The rooms
are plainly furnished, without any pretensions to elegance, but
scrupulously clean. Adjoining the house are the stable and byre,
which would not disgrace a model farm in Germany or England. In
front is a spacious courtyard, which has the appearance of being
swept several times a day, and behind there is a garden well
stocked with vegetables. Fruit trees and flowers are not very
plentiful, for the climate is not favourable to them.
The inhabitants are honest, frugal folk, somewhat sluggish of
intellect and indifferent to things lying beyond the narrow limits
of their own little world, but shrewd enough in all matters which
they deem worthy of their attention. If you arrive amongst them as
a stranger you may be a little chilled by the welcome you receive,
for they are exclusive, reserved, and distrustful, and do not much
like to associate with those who do not belong to their own sect;
but if you can converse with them in their mother tongue and talk
about religious matters in an evangelical tone, you may easily
overcome their stiffness and exclusiveness. Altogether such a
village cannot be recommended for a lengthened sojourn, for the
severe order and symmetry which everywhere prevail would soon prove
irksome to any one having no Dutch blood in his veins;* but as a
temporary resting-place during a pilgrimage on the Steppe, when the
pilgrim is longing for a little cleanliness and comfort, it is very
agreeable.
* The Mennonites were originally Dutchmen. Persecuted for their
religious views in the sixteenth century, a large number of them
accepted an invitation to settle in West Prussia, where they helped
to drain the great marshes between Danzig, Elbing, and Marienburg.
Here in the course of time they forgot their native language.
Their emigration to Russia began in 1789.
The fact that these Mennonites and some other German colonies have
succeeded in rearing a few sickly trees has suggested to some
fertile minds the idea that the prevailing dryness of the climate,
which is the chief difficulty with which the agriculturist of that
region has to contend, might be to some extent counteracted by
arboriculture on a large scale. This scheme, though it has been
seriously entertained by one of his Majesty's ministers, must seem
hardly practicable to any one who knows how much labour and money
the colonists have expended in creating that agreeable shade which
they love to enjoy in their leisure hours. If climate is affected
at all by the existence or non-existence of forests--a point on
which scientific men do not seem to be entirely agreed--any
palpable increase of the rainfall can be produced only by forests
of enormous extent, and it is hardly conceivable that these could
be artificially produced in Southern Russia. It is quite possible,
however, that local ameliorations may be effected. During a visit
to the province of Voronezh in 1903 I found that comparatively
small plantations diminished the effects of drought in their
immediate vicinity by retaining the moisture for a time in the soil
and the surrounding atmosphere.
After the Mennonites and other Germans, the Bulgarian colonists
deserve a passing notice. They settled in this region much more
recently, on the land that was left vacant by the exodus of the
Nogai Tartars after the Crimean War. If I may judge of their
condition by a mere flying visit, I should say that in agriculture
and domestic civilisation they are not very far behind the majority
of German colonists. Their houses are indeed small--so small that
one of them might almost be put into a single room of a Mennonite's
house; but there is an air of cleanliness and comfort about them
that would do credit to a German housewife.
In spite of all this, these Bulgarians were, I could easily
perceive, by no means delighted with their new home. The cause of
their discontent, so far as I could gather from the few laconic
remarks which I extracted from them, seemed to be this: Trusting to
the highly coloured descriptions furnished by the emigration agents
who had induced them to change the rule of the Sultan for the
authority of the Tsar, they came to Russia with the expectation of
finding a fertile and beautiful Promised Land. Instead of a land
flowing with milk and honey, they received a tract of bare Steppe
on which even water could be obtained only with great difficulty--
with no shade to protect them from the heat of summer and nothing
to shelter them from the keen northern blasts that often sweep over
those open plains. As no adequate arrangements had been made for
their reception, they were quartered during the first winter on the
German colonists, who, being quite innocent of any Slavophil
sympathies, were probably not very hospitable to their uninvited
guests. To complete their disappointment, they found that they
could not cultivate the vine, and that their mild, fragrant
tobacco, which is for them a necessary of life, could be obtained
only at a very high price. So disconsolate were they under this
cruel disenchantment that, at the time of my visit, they talked of
returning to their old homes in Turkey.
As an example of the less prosperous colonists, I may mention the
Tartar-speaking Greeks in the neighbourhood of Mariupol, on the
northern shore of the Sea of Azof. Their ancestors lived in the
Crimea, under the rule of the Tartar Khans, and emigrated to Russia
in the time of Catherine II., before Crim Tartary was annexed to
the Russian Empire. They have almost entirely forgotten their old
language, but have preserved their old faith. In adopting the
Tartar language they have adopted something of Tartar indolence and
apathy, and the natural consequence is that they are poor and
ignorant.
But of all the colonists of this region the least prosperous are
the Jews. The Chosen People are certainly a most intelligent,
industrious, frugal race, and in all matters of buying, selling,
and bartering they are unrivalled among the nations of the earth,
but they have been too long accustomed to town life to be good
tillers of the soil. These Jewish colonies were founded as an
experiment to see whether the Israelite could be weaned from his
traditionary pursuits and transferred to what some economists call
the productive section of society. The experiment has failed, and
the cause of the failure is not difficult to find. One has merely
to look at these men of gaunt visage and shambling gait, with their
loop-holed slippers, and black, threadbare coats reaching down to
their ankles, to understand that they are not in their proper
sphere. Their houses are in a most dilapidated condition, and
their villages remind one of the abomination of desolation spoken
of by Daniel the Prophet. A great part of their land is left
uncultivated or let to colonists of a different race. What little
revenue they have is derived chiefly from trade of a more or less
clandestine nature.*
* Mr. Arnold White, who subsequently visited some of these Jewish
Colonies in connection with Baron Hirsch's colonisation scheme,
assured me that he found them in a much more prosperous condition.
As Scandinavia was formerly called officina gentium--a workshop in
which new nations were made--so we may regard Southern Russia as a
workshop in which fragments of old nations are being melted down to
form a new, composite whole. It must be confessed, however, that
the melting process has as yet scarcely begun.
National peculiarities are not obliterated so rapidly in Russia as
in America or in British colonies. Among the German colonists in
Russia the process of assimilation is hardly perceptible. Though
their fathers and grandfathers may have been born in the new
country, they would consider it an insult to be called Russians.
They look down upon the Russian peasantry as poor, ignorant, lazy,
and dishonest, fear the officials on account of their tyranny and
extortion, preserve jealously their own language and customs,
rarely speak Russian well--sometimes not at all--and never
intermarry with those from whom they are separated by nationality
and religion. The Russian influence acts, however, more rapidly on
the Slavonic colonists--Servians, Bulgarians, Montenegrins--who
profess the Greek Orthodox faith, learn more easily the Russian
language, which is closely allied to their own, have no
consciousness of belonging to a Culturvolk, and in general possess
a nature much more pliable than the Teutonic.
The Government has recently attempted to accelerate the fusing
process by retracting the privileges granted to the colonists and
abolishing the peculiar administration under which they were
placed. These measures--especially the universal military service--
may eventually diminish the extreme exclusiveness of the Germans;
the youths, whilst serving in the army, will at least learn the
Russian language, and may possibly imbibe something of the Russian
spirit. But for the present this new policy has aroused a strong
feeling of hostility and greatly intensified the spirit of
exclusiveness. In the German colonies I have often overheard
complaints about Russian tyranny and uncomplimentary remarks about
the Russian national character.
The Mennonites consider themselves specially aggrieved by the so-
called reforms. They came to Russia in order to escape military
service and with the distinct understanding that they should be
exempted from it, and now they are forced to act contrary to the
religious tenets of their sect. This is the ground of complaint
which they put forward in the petitions addressed to the
Government, but they have at the same time another, and perhaps
more important, objection to the proposed changes. They feel, as
several of them admitted to me, that if the barrier which separates
them from the rest of the population were in any way broken down,
they could no longer preserve that stern Puritanical discipline
which at present constitutes their force. Hence, though the
Government was disposed to make important concessions, hundreds of
families sold their property and emigrated to America. The
movement, however, did not become general. At present the Russian
Mennonites number, male and female, about 50,000, divided into 160
colonies and possessing over 800,000 acres of land.
It is quite possible that under the new system of administration
the colonists who profess in common with the Russians the Greek
Orthodox faith may be rapidly Russianised; but I am convinced that
the others will long resist assimilation. Greek orthodoxy and
Protestant sectarianism are so radically different in spirit that
their respective votaries are not likely to intermarry; and without
intermarriage it is impossible that the two nationalities should
blend.
As an instance of the ethnological curiosities which the traveller
may stumble upon unawares in this curious region, I may mention a
strange acquaintance I made when travelling on the great plain
which stretches from the Sea of Azof to the Caspian. One day I
accidentally noticed on my travelling-map the name "Shotlandskaya
Kol6niya" (Scottish Colony) near the celebrated baths of
Piatigorsk. I was at that moment in Stavropol, a town about eighty
miles to the north, and could not gain any satisfactory information
as to what this colony was. Some well-informed people assured me
that it really was what its name implied, whilst others asserted as
confidently that it was simply a small German settlement. To
decide the matter I determined to visit the place myself, though it
did not lie near my intended route, and I accordingly found myself
one morning in the village in question. The first inhabitants whom
I encountered were unmistakably German, and they professed to know
nothing about the existence of Scotsmen in the locality either at
the present or in former times. This was disappointing, and I was
about to turn away and drive off, when a young man, who proved to
be the schoolmaster, came up, and on hearing what I desired,
advised me to consult an old Circassian who lived at the end of the
village and was well acquainted with local antiquities. On
proceeding to the house indicated, I found a venerable old man,
with fine, regular features of the Circassian type, coal-black
sparkling eyes, and a long grey beard that would have done honour
to a patriarch. To him I explained briefly, in Russian, the object
of my visit, and asked whether he knew of any Scotsmen in the
district.
"And why do you wish to know?" he replied, in the same language,
fixing me with his keen, sparkling eyes.
"Because I am myself a Scotsman, and hoped to find fellow-
countrymen here."
Let the reader imagine my astonishment when, in reply to this, he
answered, in genuine broad Scotch, "Od, man, I'm a Scotsman tae!
My name is John Abercrombie. Did ye never hear tell o' John
Abercrombie, the famous Edinburgh doctor?"
I was fairly puzzled by this extraordinary declaration. Dr.
Abercrombie's name was familiar to me as that of a medical
practitioner and writer on psychology, but I knew that he was long
since dead. When I had recovered a little from my surprise, I
ventured to remark to the enigmatical personage before me that,
though his tongue was certainly Scotch, his face was as certainly
Circassian.
"Weel, weel," he replied, evidently enjoying my look of
mystification, "you're no' far wrang. I'm a Circassian Scotsman!"
This extraordinary admission did not diminish my perplexity, so I
begged my new acquaintance to be a little more explicit, and he at
once complied with my request. His long story may be told in a few
words:
In the first years of the present century a band of Scotch
missionaries came to Russia for the purpose of converting the
Circassian tribes, and received from the Emperor Alexander I. a
large grant of land in this place, which was then on the frontier
of the Empire. Here they founded a mission, and began the work;
but they soon discovered that the surrounding population were not
idolaters, but Mussulmans, and consequently impervious to
Christianity. In this difficulty they fell on the happy idea of
buying Circassian children from their parents and bringing them up
as Christians. One of these children, purchased about the year
1806, was a little boy called Teoona. As he had been purchased
with money subscribed by Dr. Abercrombie, he had received in
baptism that gentleman's name, and he considered himself the
foster-son of his benefactor. Here was the explanation of the
mystery.
Teoona, alias Mr. Abercrombie, was a man of more than average
intelligence. Besides his native tongue, he spoke English, German,
and Russian perfectly; and he assured me that he knew several other
languages equally well. His life had been devoted to missionary
work, and especially to translating and printing the Scriptures.
He had laboured first in Astrakhan, then for four years and a half
in Persia--in the service of the Bale mission--and afterwards for
six years in Siberia.
The Scottish mission was suppressed by the Emperor Nicholas about
the year 1835, and all the missionaries except two returned home.
The son of one of these two (Galloway) was the only genuine
Scotsman remaining at the time of my visit. Of the "Circassian
Scotsmen" there were several, most of whom had married Germans.
The other inhabitants were German colonists from the province of
Saratof, and German was the language commonly spoken in the
village.
After hearing so much about foreign colonists, Tartar invaders, and
Finnish aborigines, the reader may naturally desire to know the
numerical strength of this foreign element. Unfortunately we have
no accurate data on this subject, but from a careful examination of
the available statistics I am inclined to conclude that it
constitutes about one-sixth of the population of European Russia,
including Poland, Finland, and the Caucasus, and nearly a third of
the population of the Empire as a whole.
CHAPTER XVII
AMONG THE HERETICS
The Molokanye--My Method of Investigation--Alexandrof-Hai--An
Unexpected Theological Discussion--Doctrines and Ecclesiastical
Organisation of the Molokanye--Moral Supervision and Mutual
Assistance--History of the Sect--A False Prophet--Utilitarian
Christianity--Classification of the Fantastic Sects--The "Khlysti"--
Policy of the Government towards Sectarianism--Two Kinds of
Heresy--Probable Future of the Heretical Sects--Political
Disaffection.
Whilst travelling on the Steppe I heard a great deal about a
peculiar religious sect called the Molokanye, and I felt interested
in them because their religious belief, whatever it was, seemed to
have a beneficial influence on their material welfare. Of the same
race and placed in the same conditions as the Orthodox peasantry
around them, they were undoubtedly better housed, better clad, more
punctual in the payment of their taxes, and, in a word, more
prosperous. All my informants agreed in describing them as quiet,
decent, sober people; but regarding their religious doctrines the
evidence was vague and contradictory. Some described them as
Protestants or Lutherans, whilst others believed them to be the
last remnants of a curious heretical sect which existed in the
early Christian Church.
Desirous of obtaining clear notions on the subject, I determined to
investigate the matter for myself. At first I found this to be no
easy task. In the villages through which I passed I found numerous
members of the sect, but they all showed a decided repugnance to
speak about their religious beliefs. Long accustomed to extortion
and persecution at the hands of the Administration, and suspecting
me to be a secret agent of the Government, they carefully avoided
speaking on any subject beyond the state of the weather and the
prospects of the harvest, and replied to my questions on other
topics as if they had been standing before a Grand Inquisitor.
A few unsuccessful attempts convinced me that it would be
impossible to extract from them their religious beliefs by direct
questioning. I adopted, therefore, a different system of tactics.
From meagre replies already received I had discovered that their
doctrine had at least a superficial resemblance to Presbyterianism,
and from former experience I was aware that the curiosity of
intelligent Russian peasants is easily excited by descriptions of
foreign countries. On these two facts I based my plan of campaign.
When I found a Molokan, or some one whom I suspected to be such, I
talked for some time about the weather and the crops, as if I had
no ulterior object in view. Having fully discussed this matter, I
led the conversation gradually from the weather and crops in Russia
to the weather and crops in Scotland, and then passed slowly from
Scotch agriculture to the Scotch Presbyterian Church. On nearly
every occasion this policy succeeded. When the peasant heard that
there was a country where the people interpreted the Scriptures for
themselves, had no bishops, and considered the veneration of Icons
as idolatry, he invariably listened with profound attention; and
when he learned further that in that wonderful country the parishes
annually sent deputies to an assembly in which all matters
pertaining to the Church were freely and publicly discussed, he
almost always gave free expression to his astonishment, and I had
to answer a whole volley of questions. "Where is that country?"
"Is it to the east, or the west?" "Is it very far away?" "If our
Presbyter could only hear all that!"
This last expression was precisely what I wanted, because it gave
me an opportunity of making the acquaintance of the Presbyter, or
pastor, without seeming to desire it; and I knew that a
conversation with that personage, who is always an uneducated
peasant like the others, but is generally more intelligent and
better acquainted with religious doctrine, would certainly be of
use to me. On more than one occasion I spent a great part of the
night with a Presbyter, and thereby learned much concerning the
religious beliefs and practices of the sect. After these
interviews I was sure to be treated with confidence and respect by
all the Molokanye in the village, and recommended to the brethren
of the faith in the neighbouring villages through which I intended
to pass. Several of the more intelligent peasants with whom I
spoke advised me strongly to visit Alexandrof-Hai, a village
situated on the borders of the Kirghiz Steppe. "We are dark [i.e.,
ignorant] people here," they were wont to say, "and do not know
anything, but in Alexandrof-Hai you will find those who know the
faith, and they will discuss with you." This prediction was
fulfilled in a somewhat unexpected way.
When returning some weeks later from a visit to the Kirghiz of the
Inner Horde, I arrived one evening at this centre of the Molokan
faith, and was hospitably received by one of the brotherhood. In
conversing casually with my host on religious subjects I expressed
to him a desire to find some one well read in Holy Writ and well
grounded in the faith, and he promised to do what he could for me
in this respect. Next morning he kept his promise with a
vengeance. Immediately after the tea-urn had been removed the door
of the room was opened and twelve peasants were ushered in! After
the customary salutations with these unexpected visitors, my host
informed me to my astonishment that his friends had come to have a
talk with me about the faith; and without further ceremony he
placed before me a folio Bible in the old Slavonic tongue, in order
that I might read passages in support of my arguments. As I was
not at all prepared to open a formal theological discussion, I felt
not a little embarrassed, and I could see that my travelling
companions, two Russian friends who cared for none of these things,
were thoroughly enjoying my discomfiture. There was, however, no
possibility of drawing back. I had asked for an opportunity of
having a talk with some of the brethren, and now I had got it in a
way that I certainly did not expect. My friends withdrew--"leaving
me to my fate," as they whispered to me--and the "talk" began.
My fate was by no means so terrible as had been anticipated, but at
first the situation was a little awkward. Neither party had any
clear ideas as to what the other desired, and my visitors expected
that I was to begin the proceedings. This expectation was quite
natural and justifiable, for I had inadvertently invited them to
meet me, but I could not make a speech to them, for the best of all
reasons--that I did not know what to say. If I told them my real
aims, their suspicions would probably be aroused. My usual
stratagem of the weather and the crops was wholly inapplicable.
For a moment I thought of proposing that a psalm should be sung as
a means of breaking the ice, but I felt that this would give to the
meeting a solemnity which I wished to avoid. On the whole it
seemed best to begin at once a formal discussion. I told them,
therefore, that I had spoken with many of their brethren in various
villages, and that I had found what I considered grave errors of
doctrine. I could not, for instance, agree with them in their
belief that it was unlawful to eat pork. This was perhaps an
abrupt way of entering on the subject, but it furnished at least a
locus standi--something to talk about--and an animated discussion
immediately ensued. My opponents first endeavoured to prove their
thesis from the New Testament, and when this argument broke down
they had recourse to the Pentateuch. From a particular article of
the ceremonial law we passed to the broader question as to how far
the ceremonial law is still binding, and from this to other points
equally important.
If the logic of the peasants was not always unimpeachable, their
knowledge of the Scriptures left nothing to be desired. In support
of their views they quoted long passages from memory, and whenever
I indicated vaguely any text which I needed, they at once supplied
it verbatim, so that the big folio Bible served merely as an
ornament. Three or four of them seemed to know the whole of the
New Testament by heart. The course of our informal debate need not
here be described; suffice it to say that, after four hours of
uninterrupted conversation, we agreed to differ on questions of
detail, and parted from each other without a trace of that ill-
feeling which religious discussion commonly engenders. Never have
I met men more honest and courteous in debate, more earnest in the
search after truth, more careless of dialectical triumphs, than
these simple, uneducated muzhiks. If at one or two points in the
discussion a little undue warmth was displayed, I must do my
opponents the justice to say that they were not the offending
party.
This long discussion, as well as numerous discussions which I had
had before and since have had with Molokanye in various parts of
the country, confirmed my first impression that their doctrines
have a strong resemblance to Presbyterianism. There is, however,
an important difference. Presbyterianism has an ecclesiastical
organisation and a written creed, and its doctrines have long since
become clearly defined by means of public discussion, polemical
literature, and general assemblies. The Molokanye, on the
contrary, have had no means of developing their fundamental
principles and forming their vague religious beliefs into a clearly
defined logical system. Their theology is therefore still in a
half-fluid state, so that it is impossible to predict what form it
will ultimately assume. "We have not yet thought about that," I
have frequently been told when I inquired about some abstruse
doctrine; "we must talk about it at the meeting next Sunday. What
is your opinion?" Besides this, their fundamental principles allow
great latitude for individual and local differences of opinion.
They hold that Holy Writ is the only rule of faith and conduct, but
that it must be taken in the spiritual, and not in the literal,
sense. As there is no terrestrial authority to which doubtful
points can be referred, each individual is free to adopt the
interpretation which commends itself to his own judgment. This
will no doubt ultimately lead to a variety of sects, and already
there is a considerable diversity of opinion between different
communities; but this diversity has not yet been recognised, and I
may say that I nowhere found that fanatically dogmatic, quibbling
spirit which is usually the soul of sectarianism.
For their ecclesiastical organisation the Molokanye take as their
model the early Apostolic Church, as depicted in the New Testament,
and uncompromisingly reject all later authorities. In accordance
with this model they have no hierarchy and no paid clergy, but
choose from among themselves a Presbyter and two assistants--men
well known among the brethren for their exemplary life and their
knowledge of the Scriptures--whose duty it is to watch over the
religious and moral welfare of the flock. On Sundays they hold
meetings in private houses--they are not allowed to build churches--
and spend two or three hours in psalm singing, prayer, reading the
Scriptures, and friendly conversation on religious subjects. If
any one has a doctrinal difficulty which he desires to have cleared
up, he states it to the congregation, and some of the others give
their opinions, with the texts on which the opinions are founded.
If the question seems clearly solved by the texts, it is decided;
if not, it is left open.
As in many young sects, there exists among the Molokanye a system
of severe moral supervision. If a member has been guilty of
drunkenness or any act unbecoming a Christian, he is first
admonished by the Presbyter in private or before the congregation;
and if this does not produce the desired effect, he is excluded for
a longer or shorter period from the meetings and from all
intercourse with the members. In extreme cases expulsion is
resorted to. On the other hand, if any one of the members happens
to be, from no fault of his own, in pecuniary difficulties, the
others will assist him. This system of mutual control and mutual
assistance has no doubt something to do with the fact that the
Molokanye are distinguished from the surrounding population by
their sobriety, uprightness, and material prosperity.
Of the history of the sect my friends in Alexandrof-Hai could tell
me very little, but I have obtained from other quarters some
interesting information. The founder was a peasant of the province
of Tambof called Uklein, who lived in the reign of Catherine II.,
and gained his living as an itinerant tailor. For some time he
belonged to the sect of the Dukhobortsi--who are sometimes called
the Russian Quakers, and who have recently become known in Western
Europe through the efforts of Count Tolstoy on their behalf--but he
soon seceded from them, because he could not admit their doctrine
that God dwells in the human soul, and that consequently the chief
source of religious truth is internal enlightenment. To him it
seemed that religious truth was to be found only in the Scriptures.
With this doctrine he soon made many converts, and one day he
unexpectedly entered the town of Tambof, surrounded by seventy
"Apostles" chanting psalms. They were all quickly arrested and
imprisoned, and when the affair was reported to St. Petersburg the
Empress Catherine ordered that they should be handed over to the
ecclesiastical authorities, and that in the event of their proving
obdurate to exhortation they should be tried by the Criminal
Courts. Uklein professed to recant, and was liberated; but he
continued his teaching secretly in the villages, and at the time of
his death he was believed to have no less than five thousand
followers.
As to the actual strength of the sect it is difficult to form even
a conjecture. Certainly it has many thousand members--probably
several hundred thousand. Formerly the Government transported them
from the central provinces to the thinly populated outlying
districts, where they had less opportunity of contaminating
Orthodox neighbours; and accordingly we find them in the
southeastern districts of Samara, on the north coast of the Sea of
Azof, in the Crimea, in the Caucasus, and in Siberia. There are
still, however, very many of them in the central region, especially
in the province of Tambof.
The readiness with which the Molokanye modify their opinions and
beliefs in accordance with what seems to them new light saves them
effectually from bigotry and fanaticism, but it at the same time
exposes them to evils of a different kind, from which they might be
preserved by a few stubborn prejudices. "False prophets arise
among us," said an old, sober-minded member to me on one occasion,
"and lead many away from the faith."
In 1835, for example, great excitement was produced among them by
rumours that the second advent of Christ was at hand, and that the
Son of Man, coming to judge the world, was about to appear in the
New Jerusalem, somewhere near Mount Ararat. As Elijah and Enoch
were to appear before the opening of the Millennium, they were
anxiously awaited by the faithful, and at last Elijah appeared, in
the person of a Melitopol peasant called Belozvorof, who announced
that on a given day he would ascend into heaven. On the day
appointed a great crowd collected, but he failed to keep his
promise, and was handed over to the police as an impostor by the
Molokanye themselves. Unfortunately they were not always so
sensible as on that occasion. In the very next year many of them
were persuaded by a certain Lukian Petrof to put on their best
garments and start for the Promised Land in the Caucasus, where the
Millennium was about to begin.
Of these false prophets the most remarkable in recent times was a
man who called himself Ivan Grigorief, a mysterious personage who
had at one time a Turkish and at another an American passport, but
who seemed in all other respects a genuine Russian. Some years
previously to my visit he appeared at Alexandrof-Hai. Though he
professed himself to be a good Molokan and was received as such, he
enounced at the weekly meetings many new and startling ideas. At
first he simply urged his hearers to live like the early
Christians, and have all things in common. This seemed sound
doctrine to the Molokanye, who profess to take the early Christians
as their model, and some of them thought of at once abolishing
personal property; but when the teacher intimated pretty plainly
that this communism should include free love, a decided opposition
arose, and it was objected that the early Church did not recommend
wholesale adultery and cognate sins. This was a formidable
objection, but "the prophet" was equal to the occasion. He
reminded his friends that in accordance with their own doctrine the
Scriptures should be understood, not in the literal, but in the
spiritual, sense--that Christianity had made men free, and every
true Christian ought to use his freedom.
This account of the new doctrine was given to me by an intelligent
Molokan, who had formerly been a peasant and was now a trader, as I
sat one evening in his house in Novo-usensk, the chief town of the
district in which Alexandrof-Hai is situated. It seemed to me that
the author of this ingenious attempt to conciliate Christianity
with extreme Utilitarianism must be an educated man in disguise.
This conviction I communicated to my host, but he did not agree
with me.
"No, I think not," he replied; "in fact, I am sure he is a peasant,
and I strongly suspect he was at some time a soldier. He has not
much learning, but he has a wonderful gift of talking; never have I
heard any one speak like him. He would have talked over the whole
village, had it not been for an old man who was more than a match
for him. And then he went to Orloff-Hai and there he did talk the
people over." What he really did in this latter place I never
could clearly ascertain. Report said that he founded a communistic
association, of which he was himself president and treasurer, and
converted the members to an extraordinary theory of prophetic
succession, invented apparently for his own sensual gratification.
For further information my host advised me to apply either to the
prophet himself, who was at that time confined in the gaol on a
charge of using a forged passport, or to one of his friends, a
certain Mr. I---- , who lived in the town. As it was a difficult
matter to gain admittance to the prisoner, and I had little time at
my disposal, I adopted the latter alternative.
Mr. I---- was himself a somewhat curious character. He had been a
student in Moscow, and in consequence of some youthful
indiscretions during the University disturbances had been exiled to
this place. After waiting in vain some years for a release, he
gave up the idea of entering one of the learned professions,
married a peasant girl, rented a piece of land, bought a pair of
camels, and settled down as a small farmer.* He had a great deal
to tell about the prophet.
* Here for the first time I saw camels used for agricultural
purposes. When yoked to a small four-wheeled cart, the "ships of
the desert" seemed decidedly out of place.
Grigorief, it seemed, was really simply a Russian peasant, but he
had been from his youth upwards one of those restless people who
can never long work in harness. Where his native place was, and
why he left it, he never divulged, for reasons best known to
himself. He had travelled much, and had been an attentive
observer. Whether he had ever been in America was doubtful, but he
had certainly been in Turkey, and had fraternised with various
Russian sectarians, who are to be found in considerable numbers
near the Danube. Here, probably, he acquired many of his peculiar
religious ideas, and conceived his grand scheme of founding a new
religion--of rivalling the Founder of Christianity! He aimed at
nothing less than this, as he on one occasion confessed, and he did
not see why he should not be successful. He believed that the
Founder of Christianity had been simply a man like himself, who
understood better than others the people around him and the
circumstances of the time, and he was convinced that he himself had
these qualifications. One qualification, however, for becoming a
prophet he certainly did not possess: he had no genuine religious
enthusiasm in him--nothing of the martyr spirit about him. Much of
his own preaching he did not himself believe, and he had a secret
contempt for those who naively accepted it all. Not only was he
cunning, but he knew he was cunning, and he was conscious that he
was playing an assumed part. And yet perhaps it would be unjust to
say that he was merely an impostor exclusively occupied with his
own personal advantage. Though he was naturally a man of sensual
tastes, and could not resist convenient opportunities of gratifying
them, he seemed to believe that his communistic schemes would, if
realised, be beneficial not only to himself, but also to the
people. Altogether a curious mixture of the prophet, the social
reformer, and the cunning impostor!
Besides the Molokanye, there are in Russia many other heretical
sects. Some of them are simply Evangelical Protestants, like the
Stundisti, who have adopted the religious conceptions of their
neighbours, the German colonists; whilst others are composed of
wild enthusiasts, who give a loose rein to their excited
imagination, and revel in what the Germans aptly term "der hohere
Blodsinn." I cannot here attempt to convey even a general idea of
these fantastic sects with their doctrinal and ceremonial
absurdities, but I may offer the following classification of them
for the benefit of those who may desire to study the subject:
1. Sects which take the Scriptures as the basis of their belief,
but interpret and complete the doctrines therein contained by means
of the occasional inspiration or internal enlightenment of their
leading members.
2. Sects which reject interpretation and insist on certain passages
of Scripture being taken in the literal sense. In one of the best
known of these sects--the Skoptsi, or Eunuchs--fanaticism has led
to physical mutilation.
3. Sects which pay little or no attention to Scripture, and derive
their doctrine from the supposed inspiration of their living
teachers.
4. Sects which believe in the re-incarnation of Christ.
5. Sects which confound religion with nervous excitement, and are
more or less erotic in their character. The excitement necessary
for prophesying is commonly produced by dancing, jumping,
pirouetting, or self-castigation; and the absurdities spoken at
such times are regarded as the direct expression of divine wisdom.
The religious exercises resemble more or less closely those of the
"dancing dervishes" and "howling dervishes's with which all who
have visited Constantinople are familiar. There is, however, one
important difference: the dervishes practice their religious
exercises in public, and consequently observe a certain decorum,
whilst these Russian sects assemble in secret, and give free scope
to their excitement, so that most disgusting orgies sometimes take
place at their meetings.
To illustrate the general character of the sects belonging to this
last category, I may quote here a short extract from a description
of the "Khlysti" by one who was initiated into their mysteries:
"Among them men and women alike take upon themselves the calling of
teachers and prophets, and in this character they lead a strict,
ascetic life, refrain from the most ordinary and innocent
pleasures, exhaust themselves by long fasting and wild, ecstatic
religious exercises, and abhor marriage. Under the excitement
caused by their supposed holiness and inspiration, they call
themselves not only teachers and prophets, but also 'Saviours,'
'Redeemers,' 'Christs,' 'Mothers of God.' Generally speaking, they
call themselves simply Gods, and pray to each other as to real Gods
and living Christs or Madonnas. When several of these teachers
come together at a meeting, they dispute with each other in a vain
boasting way as to which of them possesses most grace and power.
In this rivalry they sometimes give each other lusty blows on the
ear, and he who bears the blows most patiently, turning the other
cheek to the smiter, acquires the reputation of having most
holiness."
Another sect belonging to this category is the Jumpers, among whom
the erotic element is disagreeably prominent. Here is a
description of their religious meetings, which are held during
summer in the forest, and during winter in some out-house or barn:
"After due preparation prayers are read by the chief teacher,
dressed in a white robe and standing in the midst of the
congregation. At first he reads in an ordinary tone of voice, and
then passes gradually into a merry chant. When he remarks that the
chanting has sufficiently acted on the hearers, he begins to jump.
The hearers, singing likewise, follow his example. Their ever-
increasing excitement finds expression in the highest possible
jumps. This they continue as long as they can--men and women alike
yelling like enraged savages. When all are thoroughly exhausted,
the leader declares that he hears the angels singing"--and then
begins a scene which cannot be here described.
It is but fair to add that we know very little of these peculiar
sects, and what we do know is furnished by avowed enemies. It is
very possible, therefore, that some of them are not nearly so
absurd as they are commonly represented, and that many of the
stories told are mere calumnies.
The Government is very hostile to sectarianism, and occasionally
endeavours to suppress it. This is natural enough as regards these
fantastic sects, but it seems strange that the peaceful,
industrious, honest Molokanye and Stundisti should be put under the
ban. Why is it that a Russian peasant should be punished for
holding doctrines which are openly professed, with the sanction of
the authorities, by his neighbours, the German colonists?
To understand this the reader must know that according to Russian
conceptions there are two distinct kinds of heresy, distinguished
from each other, not by the doctrines held, but by the nationality
of the holder, it seems to a Russian in the nature of things that
Tartars should be Mahometans, that Poles should be Roman Catholics,
and that Germans should be Protestants; and the mere act of
becoming a Russian subject is not supposed to lay the Tartar, the
Pole, or the German under any obligation to change his faith.
These nationalities are therefore allowed the most perfect freedom
in the exercise of their respective religions, so long as they
refrain from disturbing by propagandism the divinely established
order of things.
This is the received theory, and we must do the Russians the
justice to say that they habitually act up to it. If the
Government has sometimes attempted to convert alien races, the
motive has always been political, and the efforts have never
awakened much sympathy among the people at large, or even among the
clergy. In like manner the missionary societies which have
sometimes been formed in imitation of the Western nations have
never received much popular support. Thus with regard to aliens
this peculiar theory has led to very extensive religious
toleration. With regard to the Russians themselves the theory has
had a very different effect. If in the nature of things the Tartar
is a Mahometan, the Pole a Roman Catholic, and the German a
Protestant, it is equally in the nature of things that the Russian
should be a member of the Orthodox Church. On this point the
written law and public opinion are in perfect accord. If an
Orthodox Russian becomes a Roman Catholic or a Protestant, he is
amenable to the criminal law, and is at the same time condemned by
public opinion as an apostate and renegade--almost as a traitor.
As to the future of these heretical sects it is impossible to speak
with confidence. The more gross and fantastic will probably
disappear as primary education spreads among the people; but the
Protestant sects seem to possess much more vitality. For the
present, at least, they are rapidly spreading. I have seen large
villages where, according to the testimony of the inhabitants,
there was not a single heretic fifteen years before, and where one-
half of the population had already become Molokanye; and this
change, be it remarked, had taken place without any propagandist
organisation. The civil and ecclesiastical authorities were well
aware of the existence of the movement, but they were powerless to
prevent it. The few efforts which they made were without effect,
or worse than useless. Among the Stundisti corporal punishment was
tried as an antidote--without the concurrence, it is to be hoped,
of the central authorities--and to the Molokanye of the province of
Samara a learned monk was sent in the hope of converting them from
their errors by reason and eloquence. What effect the birch-twigs
had on the religious convictions of the Stundisti I have not been
able to ascertain, but I assume that they were not very
efficacious, for according to the latest accounts the numbers of
the sect are increasing. Of the mission in the province of Samara
I happen to know more, and can state on the evidence of many
peasants--some of them Orthodox--that the only immediate effect was
to stir up religious fanaticism, and to induce a certain number of
Orthodox to go over to the heretical camp.
In their public discussions the disputants could find no common
ground on which to argue, for the simple reason that their
fundamental conceptions were different. The monk spoke of the
Church as the terrestrial representative of Christ and the sole
possessor of truth, whilst his opponents knew nothing of a Church
in this sense, and held simply that all men should live in
accordance with the dictates of Scripture. Once the monk consented
to argue with them on their own ground, and on that occasion he
sustained a signal defeat, for he could not produce a single
passage recommending the veneration of Icons--a practice which the
Russian peasants consider an essential part of Orthodoxy. After
this he always insisted on the authority of the early Ecumenical
Councils and the Fathers of the Church--an authority which his
antagonists did not recognise. Altogether the mission was a
complete failure, and all parties regretted that it had been
undertaken. "It was a great mistake," remarked to me
confidentially an Orthodox peasant; "a very great mistake. The
Molokanye are a cunning people. The monk was no match for them;
they knew the Scriptures a great deal better than he did. The
Church should not condescend to discuss with heretics."
It is often said that these heretical sects are politically
disaffected, and the Molokanye are thought to be specially
dangerous in this respect. Perhaps there is a certain foundation
for this opinion, for men are naturally disposed to doubt the
legitimacy of a power that systematically persecutes them. With
regard to the Molokanye, I believe the accusation to be a
groundless calumny. Political ideas seemed entirely foreign to
their modes of thought. During my intercourse with them I often
heard them refer to the police as "wolves which have to be fed,"
but I never heard them speak of the Emperor otherwise than in terms
of filial affection and veneration.
CHAPTER XVIII
THE DISSENTERS
Dissenters not to be Confounded with Heretics--Extreme Importance
Attached to Ritual Observances--The Raskol, or Great Schism in the
Seventeenth Century--Antichrist Appears!--Policy of Peter the Great
and Catherine II.--Present Ingenious Method of Securing Religious
Toleration--Internal Development of the Raskol--Schism among the
Schismatics--The Old Ritualists--The Priestless People--Cooling of
the Fanatical Enthusiasm and Formation of New Sects--Recent Policy
of the Government towards the Sectarians--Numerical Force and
Political Significance of Sectarianism.
We must be careful not to confound those heretical sects,
Protestant and fantastical, of which I have spoken in the preceding
chapter, with the more numerous Dissenters or Schismatics, the
descendants of those who seceded from the Russian Church--or more
correctly from whom the Russian Church seceded--in the seventeenth
century. So far from regarding themselves as heretics, these
latter consider themselves more orthodox than the official Orthodox
Church. They are conservatives, too, in the social as well as the
religious sense of the term. Among them are to be found the last
remnants of old Russian life, untinged by foreign influences.
The Russian Church, as I have already had occasion to remark, has
always paid inordinate attention to ceremonial observances and
somewhat neglected the doctrinal and moral elements of the faith
which it professes. This peculiarity greatly facilitated the
spread of its influence among a people accustomed to pagan rites
and magical incantations, but it had the pernicious effect of
confirming in the new converts their superstitious belief in the
virtue of mere ceremonies. Thus the Russians became zealous
Christians in all matters of external observance, without knowing
much about the spiritual meaning of the rites which they practised.
They looked upon the rites and sacraments as mysterious charms
which preserved them from evil influences in the present life and
secured them eternal felicity in the life to come, and they
believed that these charms would inevitably lose their efficacy if
modified in the slightest degree. Extreme importance was therefore
attached to the ritual minutiae, and the slightest modification of
these minutiae assumed the importance of an historical event. In
the year 1476, for instance, the Novgorodian Chronicler gravely
relates:
"This winter some philosophers (!) began to sing, 'O Lord, have
mercy,' and others merely, 'Lord, have mercy.'" And this attaching
of enormous importance to trifles was not confined to the ignorant
multitude. An Archbishop of Novgorod declared solemnly that those
who repeat the word "Alleluia" only twice at certain points in the
liturgy "sing to their own damnation," and a celebrated
Ecclesiastical Council, held in 1551, put such matters as the
position of the fingers when making the sign of the cross on the
same level as heresies--formally anathematising those who acted in
such trifles contrary to its decisions.
This conservative spirit in religious concerns had a considerable
influence on social life. As there was no clear line of
demarcation between religious observances and simple traditional
customs, the most ordinary act might receive a religious
significance, and the slightest departure from a traditional custom
might be looked upon as a deadly sin. A Russian of the olden time
would have resisted the attempt to deprive him of his beard as
strenuously as a Calvinist of the present day would resist the
attempt to make him abjure the doctrine of Predestination--and both
for the same reason. As the doctrine of Predestination is for the
Calvinist, so the wearing of a beard was for the old Russian--an
essential of salvation. "Where," asked one of the Patriarchs of
Moscow, "will those who shave their chins stand at the Last Day?--
among the righteous adorned with beards, or among the beardless
heretics?" The question required no answer.
In the seventeenth century this superstitious, conservative spirit
reached its climax. The civil wars and foreign invasions,
accompanied by pillage, famine, and plagues with which that century
opened, produced a wide-spread conviction that the end of all
things was at hand. The mysterious number of the Beast was found
to indicate the year 1666, and timid souls began to discover signs
of that falling away from the Faith which is spoken of in the
Apocalypse. The majority of the people did not perhaps share this
notion, but they believed that the sufferings with which they had
been visited were a Divine punishment for having forsaken the
ancient customs. And it could not be denied that considerable
changes had taken place. Orthodox Russia was now tainted with the
presence of heretics. Foreigners who shaved their chins and smoked
the accursed weed had been allowed to settle in Moscow, and the
Tsars not only held converse with them, but had even adopted some
of their "pagan" practises. Besides this, the Government had
introduced innovations and reforms, many of which were displeasing
to the people. In short, the country was polluted with "heresy"--a
subtle, evil influence lurking in everything foreign, and very
dangerous to the spiritual and temporal welfare of the Faithful--
something of the nature of an epidemic, but infinitely more
dangerous; for disease kills merely the body, whereas "heresy"
kills the soul, and causes both soul and body to be cast into hell-
fire.
Had the Government introduced the innovations slowly and
cautiously, respecting as far as possible all outward forms, it
might have effected much without producing a religious panic; but,
instead of acting circumspectly as the occasion demanded, it ran
full-tilt against the ancient prejudices and superstitious fears,
and drove the people into open resistance. When the art of
printing was introduced, it became necessary to choose the best
texts of the Liturgy, Psalter, and other religious books, and on
examination it was found that, through the ignorance and
carelessness of copyists, numerous errors had crept into the
manuscripts in use. This discovery led to further investigation,
which showed that certain irregularities had likewise crept into
the ceremonial. The chief of the clerical errors lay in the
orthography of the word "Jesus," and the chief irregularity in the
ceremonial regarded the position of the fingers when making the
sign of the cross.
To correct these errors the celebrated Nikon, who was Patriarch in
the time of Tsar Alexis, father of Peter the Great, ordered all the
old liturgical books and the old Icons to be called in, and new
ones to be distributed; but the clergy and the people resisted.
Believing these "Nikonian novelties" to be heretical, they clung to
their old Icons, their old missals and their old religious customs
as the sole anchors of safety which could save the Faithful from
drifting to perdition. In vain the Patriarch assured the people
that the change was a return to the ancient forms still preserved
in Greece and Constantinople. "The Greek Church," it was replied,
"is no longer free from heresy. Orthodoxy has become many-coloured
from the violence of the Turkish Mahomet; and the Greeks, under the
sons of Hagar, have fallen away from the ancient traditions."
An anathema, formally pronounced by an Ecclesiastical Council
against these Nonconformists, had no more effect than the
admonitions of the Patriarch. They persevered in their obstinacy,
and refused to believe that the blessed saints and holy martyrs who
had used the ancient forms had not prayed and crossed themselves
aright. "Not those holy men of old, but the present Patriarch and
his counsellors must be heretics." "Woe to us! Woe to us!" cried
the monks of Solovetsk when they received the new Liturgies. "What
have you done with the Son of God? Give him back to us! You have
changed Isus [the old Russian form of Jesus] into Iisus! It is
fearful not only to commit such a sin, but even to think of it!"
And the sturdy monks shut their gates, and defied Patriarch,
Council, and Tsar for seven long years, till the monastery was
taken by an armed force.
The decree of excommunication pronounced by the Ecclesiastical
Council placed the Nonconformists beyond the pale of the Church,
and the civil power undertook the task of persecuting them.
Persecution had of course merely the effect of confirming the
victims in their belief that the Church and the Tsar had become
heretical. Thousands fled across the frontier and settled in the
neighbouring countries--Poland, Russia, Sweden, Austria, Turkey,
the Caucasus, and Siberia. Others concealed themselves in the
northern forests and the densely wooded region near the Polish
frontier, where they lived by agriculture or fishing, and prayed,
crossed themselves and buried their dead according to the customs
of their forefathers. The northern forests were their favourite
place of refuge. Hither flocked many of those who wished to keep
themselves pure and undefiled. Here the more learned men among the
Nonconformists--well acquainted with Holy Writ, with fragmentary
translations from the Greek Fathers, and with the more important
decisions of the early Ecumenical Councils--wrote polemical and
edifying works for the confounding of heretics and the confirming
of true believers. Hence were sent out in all directions zealous
missionaries, in the guise of traders, peddlers, and labourers, to
sow what they called the living seed, and what the official Church
termed "Satan's tares." When the Government agents discovered
these retreats, the inmates generally fled from the "ravenous
wolves"; but on more than one occasion a large number of fanatical
men and women, shutting themselves up, set fire to their houses,
and voluntarily perished in the flames. In Paleostrofski
Monastery, for instance, in the year 1687, no less than 2,700
fanatics gained the crown of martyrdom in this way; and many
similar instances are on record.* As in all periods of religious
panic, the Apocalypse was carefully studied, and the Millennial
ideas rapidly spread. The signs of the time were plain: Satan was
being let loose for a little season. Men anxiously looked for the
reappearance of Antichrist--and Antichrist appeared!
* A list of well-authenticated cases is given by Nilski, "Semeinaya
zhizn v russkom Raskole," St. Petersburg, 1869; part I., pp. 55-57.
The number of these self-immolators certainly amounted to many
thousands.
The man in whom the people recognised the incarnate spirit of evil
was no other than Peter the Great.
From the Nonconformist point of view, Peter had very strong claims
to be considered Antichrist. He had none of the staid, pious
demeanour of the old Tsars, and showed no respect for many things
which were venerated by the people. He ate, drank, and habitually
associated with heretics, spoke their language, wore their costume,
chose from among them his most intimate friends, and favoured them
more than his own people. Imagine the horror and commotion which
would be produced among pious Catholics if the Pope should some day
appear in the costume of the Grand Turk, and should choose Pashas
as his chief counsellors! The horror which Peter's conduct
produced among a large section of his subjects was not less great.
They could not explain it otherwise than by supposing him to be the
Devil in disguise, and they saw in all his important measures
convincing proofs of his Satanic origin. The newly invented
census, or "revision," was a profane "numbering of the people," and
an attempt to enrol in the service of Be lzebub those whose names?
were written in the Lamb's Book of Life. The new title of
Imperator was explained to mean something very diabolical. The
passport bearing the Imperial arms was the seal of Antichrist. The
order to shave the beard was an attempt to disfigure "the image of
God," after which man had been created, and by which Christ would
recognise His own at the Last Day. The change in the calendar, by
which New Year's Day was transferred from September to January, was
the destruction of "the years of our Lord," and the introduction of
the years of Satan in their place. Of the ingenious arguments by
which these theses were supported, I may quote one by way of
illustration. The world, it was explained, could not have been
created in January as the new calendar seemed to indicate, because
apples are not ripe at that season, and consequently Eve could not
have been tempted in the way described!*
* I found this ingenious argument in one of the polemical treatises
of the Old Believers.
These ideas regarding Peter and his reforms were strongly confirmed
by the vigorous persecutions which took place during the earlier
years of his reign. The Nonconformists were constantly convicted
of political disaffection--especially of "insulting the Imperial
Majesty"--and were accordingly flogged, tortured, and beheaded
without mercy. But when Peter had succeeded in putting down all
armed opposition, and found that the movement was no longer
dangerous for the throne, he adopted a policy more in accordance
with his personal character. Whether he had himself any religious
belief whatever may be doubted; certainly he had not a spark of
religious fanaticism in his nature. Exclusively occupied with
secular concerns, he took no interest in subtle questions of
religious ceremonial, and was profoundly indifferent as to how his
subjects prayed and crossed themselves, provided they obeyed his
orders in worldly matters and paid their taxes regularly. As soon,
therefore, as political considerations admitted of clemency, he
stopped the persecutions, and at last, in 1714, issued ukazes to
the effect that all Dissenters might live unmolested, provided they
inscribed themselves in the official registers and paid a double
poll-tax. Somewhat later they were allowed to practise freely all
their old rites and customs, on condition of paying certain fines.
With the accession of Catherine II., "the friend of philosophers,"
the Raskol,* as the schism had come to be called, entered on a new
phase. Penetrated with the ideas of religious toleration then in
fashion in Western Europe, Catherine abolished the disabilities to
which the Raskolniks were subjected, and invited those of them who
had fled across the frontier to return to their homes. Thousands
accepted the invitation, and many who had hitherto sought to
conceal themselves from the eyes of the authorities became rich and
respected merchants. The peculiar semi-monastic religious
communities, which had up till that time existed only in the
forests of the northern and western provinces, began to appear in
Moscow, and were officially recognised by the Administration. At
first they took the form of hospitals for the sick, or asylums for
the aged and infirm, but soon they became regular monasteries, the
superiors of which exercised an undefined spiritual authority not
only over the inmates, but also over the members of the sect
throughout the length and breadth of the Empire.
* The term is derived from two Russian words--ras, asunder; and
kolot, to split. Those who belong to the Raskol are called
Raskolniki. They call themselves Staro-obriadtsi (Old Ritualists)
or Staroveri (Old Believers).
From that time down to the present the Government has followed a
wavering policy, oscillating between complete tolerance and active
persecution. It must, however, be said that the persecution has
never been of a very searching kind. In persecution, as in all
other manifestations, the Russian Church directs its attention
chiefly to external forms. It does not seek to ferret out heresy
in a man's opinions, but complacently accepts as Orthodox all who
annually appear at confession and communion, and who refrain from
acts of open hostility. Those who can make these concessions to
convenience are practically free from molestation, and those who
cannot so trifle with their conscience have an equally convenient
method of escaping persecution. The parish clergy, with their
customary indifference to things spiritual and their traditional
habit of regarding their functions from the financial point of
view, are hostile to sectarianism chiefly because it diminishes
their revenues by diminishing the number of parishioners requiring
their ministrations. This cause of hostility can easily be removed
by a certain pecuniary sacrifice on the part of the sectarians, and
accordingly there generally exists between them and their parish
priest a tacit contract, by which both parties are perfectly
satisfied. The priest receives his income as if all his
parishioners belonged to the State Church, and the parishioners are
left in peace to believe and practise what they please. By this
rude, convenient method a very large amount of toleration is
effectually secured. Whether the practise has a beneficial moral
influence on the parish clergy is, of course, an entirely different
question.
When the priest has been satisfied, there still remains the police,
which likewise levies an irregular tax on heterodoxy; but the
negotiations are generally not difficult, for it is in the interest
of both parties that they should come to terms and live in good-
fellowship. Thus practically the Raskolniki live in the same
condition as in the time of Peter: they pay a tax and are not
molested--only the money paid does not now find its way into the
Imperial Exchequer.
These external changes in the history of the Raskol have exercised
a powerful influence on its internal development.
When formally anathematised and excluded from the dominant Church
the Nonconformists had neither a definite organisation nor a
positive creed. The only tie that bound them together was
hostility to the "Nikonian novelties," and all they desired was to
preserve intact the beliefs and customs of their forefathers. At
first they never thought of creating any permanent organisation.
The more moderate believed that the Tsar would soon re-establish
Orthodoxy, and the more fanatical imagined that the end of all
things was at hand.* In either case they had only to suffer for a
little season, keeping themselves free from the taint of heresy and
from all contact with the kingdom of Antichrist.
* Some had coffins made, and lay down in them at night, in the
expectation that the Second Advent might take place before the
morning.
But years passed, and neither of these expectations was fulfilled.
The fanatics awaited in vain the sound of the last trump and the
appearance of Christ, coming with His angels to judge the world.
The sun continued to rise, and the seasons followed each other in
their accustomed course, but the end was not yet. Nor did the
civil power return to the old faith. Nikon fell a victim to Court
intrigues and his own overweening pride, and was formally deposed.
Tsar Alexis in the fulness of time was gathered unto his fathers.
But there was no sign of a re-establishment of the old Orthodoxy.
Gradually the leading Raskolniki perceived that they must make
preparations, not for the Day of Judgment, but for a terrestrial
future--that they must create some permanent form of ecclesiastical
organisation. In this work they encountered at the very outset not
only practical, but also theoretical difficulties.
So long as they confined themselves simply to resisting the
official innovations, they seemed to be unanimous; but when they
were forced to abandon this negative policy and to determine
theoretically their new position, radical differences of opinion
became apparent. All were convinced that the official Russian
Church had become heretical, and that it had now Antichrist instead
of Christ as its head; but it was not easy to determine what should
be done by those who refused to bow the knee to the Son of
Destruction. According to Protestant conceptions there was a very
simple solution of the difficulty: the Nonconformists had simply to
create a new Church for themselves, and worship God in the way that
seemed good to them. But to the Russians of that time such notions
were still more repulsive than the innovations of Nikon. These men
were Orthodox to the backbone--"plus royalistes que le roi"--and
according to Orthodox conceptions the founding of a new Church is
an absurdity. They believed that if the chain of historic
continuity were once broken, the Church must necessarily cease to
exist, in the same way as an ancient family becomes extinct when
its sole representative dies without issue. If, therefore, the
Church had already ceased to exist, there was no longer any means
of communication between Christ and His people, the sacraments were
no longer efficacious, and mankind was forever deprived of the
ordinary means of grace.
Now, on this important point there was a difference of opinion
among the Dissenters. Some of them believed that, though the
ecclesiastical authorities had become heretical, the Church still
existed in the communion of those who had refused to accept the
innovations. Others declared boldly that the Orthodox Church had
ceased to exist, that the ancient means of grace had been
withdrawn, and that those who had remained faithful must
thenceforth seek salvation, not in the sacraments, but in prayer
and such other religious exercises as did not require the co-
operation of duly consecrated priests. Thus took place a schism
among the Schismatics. The one party retained all the sacraments
and ceremonial observances in the older form; the other refrained
from the sacraments and from many of the ordinary rites, on the
ground that there was no longer a real priesthood, and that
consequently the sacraments could not be efficacious. The former
party are termed Staro-obriadsti, or Old Ritualists; the latter are
called Bezpopoftsi--that is to say, people "without priests" (bez
popov).
The succeeding history of these two sections of the Nonconformists
has been widely different. The Old Ritualists, being simply
ecclesiastical Conservatives desirous of resisting all innovations,
have remained a compact body little troubled by differences of
opinion. The Priestless People, on the contrary, ever seeking to
discover some new effectual means of salvation, have fallen into an
endless number of independent sects.
The Old Ritualists had still, however, one important theoretical
difficulty. At first they had amongst themselves plenty of
consecrated priests for the celebration of the ordinances, but they
had no means of renewing the supply. They had no bishops, and
according to Orthodox belief the lower degrees of the clergy cannot
be created without episcopal consecration. At the time of the
schism one bishop had thrown in his lot with the Schismatics, but
he had died shortly afterwards without leaving a successor, and
thereafter no bishop had joined their ranks. As time wore on, the
necessity of episcopal consecration came to be more and more felt,
and it is not a little interesting to observe how these rigorists,
who held to the letter of the law and declared themselves ready to
die for a jot or a tittle, modified their theory in accordance with
the changing exigencies of their position. When the priests who
had kept themselves "pure and undefiled"--free from all contact
with Antichrist--became scarce, it was discovered that certain
priests of the dominant Church might be accepted if they formally
abjured the Nikonian novelties. At first, however, only those who
had been consecrated previous to the supposed apostasy of the
Church were accepted, for the very good reason that consecration by
bishops who had become heretical could not be efficacious. When
these could no longer be obtained it was discovered that those who
had been baptised previous to the apostasy might be accepted; and
when even these could no longer be found, a still further
concession was made to necessity, and all consecrated priests were
received on condition of their solemnly abjuring their errors. Of
such priests there was always an abundant supply. If a regular
priest could not find a parish, or if he was deposed by the
authorities for some crime or misdemeanour, he had merely to pass
over to the Old Ritualists, and was sure to find among them a
hearty welcome and a tolerable salary.
By these concessions the indefinite prolongation of Old Ritualism
was secured, but many of the Old Ritualists could not but feel that
their position was, to say the least, extremely anomalous. They
had no bishops of their own, and their priests were all consecrated
by bishops whom they believed to be heretical! For many years they
hoped to escape from this dilemma by discovering "Orthodox"--that
is to say, Old Ritualist--bishops somewhere in the East; but when
the East had been searched in vain, and all their efforts to obtain
native bishops proved fruitless, they conceived the design of
creating a bishopric somewhere beyond the frontier, among the Old
Ritualists who had in times of persecution fled to Prussia,
Austria, and Turkey. There were, however, immense difficulties in
the way. In the first place it was necessary to obtain the formal
permission of some foreign Government; and in the second place an
Orthodox bishop must be found, willing to consecrate an Old
Ritualist or to become an Old Ritualist himself. Again and again
the attempt was made, and failed; but at last, after years of
effort and intrigue, the design was realised. In 1844 the Austrian
Government gave permission to found a bishopric at Belaya Krinitsa,
in Galicia, a few miles from the Russian frontier; and two years
later the deposed Metropolitan of Bosnia consented, after much
hesitation, to pass over to the Old Ritualist confession and accept
the diocese.* From that time the Old Ritualists have had their own
bishops, and have not been obliged to accept the runaway priests of
the official Church.
* An interesting account of these negotiations, and a most curious
picture of the Orthodox ecciestiastical world in Constantinople, is
given by Subbotiny, "Istoria Belokrinitskoi Ierarkhii," Moscow,
1874.
The Old Ritualists were naturally much grieved by the schism, and
were often sorely tried by persecution, but they have always
enjoyed a certain spiritual tranquillity, proceeding from the
conviction that they have preserved for themselves the means of
salvation. The position of the more extreme section of the
Schismatics was much more tragical. They believed that the
sacraments had irretrievably lost their efficacy, that the ordinary
means of salvation were forever withdrawn, that the powers of
darkness had been let loose for a little season, that the
authorities were the agents of Satan, and that the personage who
filled the place of the old God-fearing Tsars was no other than
Antichrist. Under the influence of these horrible ideas they fled
to the woods and the caves to escape from the rage of the Beast,
and to await the second coming of Our Lord.
This state of things could not continue permanently. Extreme
religious fanaticism, like all other abnormal states, cannot long
exist in a mass of human beings without some constant exciting
cause. The vulgar necessities of everyday life, especially among
people who have to live by the labour of their hands, have a
wonderfully sobering influence on the excited brain, and must
always, sooner or later, prove fatal to inordinate excitement. A
few peculiarly constituted individuals may show themselves capable
of a lifelong enthusiasm, but the multitude is ever spasmodic in
its fervour, and begins to slide back to its former apathy as soon
as the exciting cause ceases to act.
All this we find exemplified in the history of the Priestless
People. When it was found that the world did not come to an end,
and that the rigorous system of persecution was relaxed, the less
excitable natures returned to their homes, and resumed their old
mode of life; and when Peter the Great made his politic
concessions, many who had declared him to be Antichrist came to
suspect that he was really not so black as he was painted. This
idea struck deep root in a religious community near Lake Onega
(Vuigovski Skit) which had received special privileges on condition
of supplying labourers for the neighbouring mines; and here was
developed a new theory which opened up a way of reconciliation with
the Government. By a more attentive study of Holy Writ and ancient
books it was discovered that the reign of Antichrist would consist
of two periods. In the former, the Son of Destruction would reign
merely in the spiritual sense, and the Faithful would not be much
molested; in the latter, he would reign visibly in the flesh, and
true believers would be subjected to the most frightful
persecution. The second period, it was held, had evidently not yet
arrived, for the Faithful now enjoyed "a time of freedom, and not
of compulsion or oppression." Whether this theory is strictly in
accordance with Apocalyptic prophecy and patristic theology may be
doubted, but it fully satisfied those who had already arrived at
the conclusion by a different road, and who sought merely a means
of justifying their position. Certain it is that very many
accepted it, and determined to render unto Caesar the things that
were Caesar's, or, in secular language, to pray for the Tsar and to
pay their taxes.
This ingenious compromise was not accepted by all the Priestless
People. On the contrary, many of them regarded it as a woeful
backsliding--a new device of the Evil One; and among these
irreconcilables was a certain peasant called Theodosi, a man of
little education, but of remarkable intellectual power and unusual
strength of character. He raised anew the old fanaticism by his
preaching and writings--widely circulated in manuscript--and
succeeded in founding a new sect in the forest region near the
Polish frontier.
The Priestless Nonconformists thus fell into two sections; the one,
called Pomortsi,* accepted at least a partial reconciliation with
the civil power; the other, called Theodosians, after their
founder, held to the old opinions, and refused to regard the Tsar
otherwise than as Antichrist.
*The word Pomortsi means "those who live near the seashore." It is
commonly applied to the inhabitants of the Northern provinces--that
is, those who live near the shore of the White Sea, the only
maritime frontier that Russia possessed previous to the conquests
of Peter the Great.
These latter were at first very wild in their fanaticism, but ere
long they gave way to the influences which had softened the
fanaticism of the Pomortsi. Under the liberal, conciliatory rule
of Catherine they lived in contentment, and many of them enriched
themselves by trade. Their fanatical zeal and exclusiveness
evaporated under the influence of material well-being and constant
contact with the outer world, especially after they were allowed to
build a monastery in Moscow. The Superior of this monastery, a man
of much shrewdness and enormous wealth, succeeded in gaining the
favour not only of the lower officials, who could be easily bought,
but even of high-placed dignitaries, and for many years he
exercised a very real, if undefined, authority over all sections of
the Priestless People. "His fame," it is said, "sounded throughout
Moscow, and the echoes were heard in Petropol (St. Petersburg),
Riga, Astrakhan, Nizhni-Novgorod, and other lands of piety"; and
when deputies came to consult him, they prostrated themselves in
his presence, as before the great ones of the earth. Living thus
not only in peace and plenty, but even in honour and luxury, "the
proud Patriarch of the Theodosian Church" could not consistently
fulminate against "the ravenous wolves" with whom he was on
friendly terms, or excite the fanaticism of his followers by highly
coloured descriptions of "the awful sufferings and persecution of
God's people in these latter days," as the founder of the sect had
been wont to do. Though he could not openly abandon any
fundamental doctrines, he allowed the ideas about the reign of
Antichrist to fall into the background, and taught by example, if
not by precept, that the Faithful might, by prudent concessions,
live very comfortably in this present evil world. This seed fell
upon soil already prepared for its reception. The Faithful
gradually forgot their old savage fanaticism, and they have since
contrived, while holding many of their old ideas in theory, to
accommodate themselves in practice to the existing order of things.
The gradual softening and toning down of the original fanaticism in
these two sects are strikingly exemplified in their ideas of
marriage. According to Orthodox doctrine, marriage is a sacrament
which can only be performed by a consecrated priest, and
consequently for the Priestless People the celebration of marriage
was an impossibility. In the first ages of sectarianism a state of
celibacy was quite in accordance with their surroundings. Living
in constant fear of their persecutors, and wandering from one place
of refuge to another, the sufferers for the Faith had little time
or inclination to think of family ties, and readily listened to the
monks, who exhorted them to mortify the lusts of the flesh.
The result, however, proved that celibacy in the creed by no means
ensures chastity in practice. Not only in the villages of the
Dissenters, but even in those religious communities which professed
a more ascetic mode of life, a numerous class of "orphans" began to
appear, who knew not who their parents were; and this ignorance of
blood-relationship naturally led to incestuous connections.
Besides this, the doctrine of celibacy had grave practical
inconveniences, for the peasant requires a housewife to attend to
domestic concerns and to help him in his agricultural occupations.
Thus the necessity of re-establishing family life came to be felt,
and the feeling soon found expression in a doctrinal form both
among the Pomortsi and among the Theodsians. Learned dissertations
were written and disseminated in manuscript copies, violent
discussions took place, and at last a great Council was held in
Moscow to discuss the question.* The point at issue was never
unanimously decided, but many accepted the ingenious arguments in
favour of matrimony, and contracted marriages which were, of
course, null and void in the eye of the law and of the Church, but
valid in all other respects.
* I cannot here enter into the details of this remarkable
controversy, but I may say that in studying it I have been
frequently astonished by the dialectical power and logical subtlety
displayed by the disputants, some of them simple peasants.
This new backsliding of the unstable multitude produced a new
outburst of fanaticism among the stubborn few. Some of those who
had hitherto sought to conceal the origin of the "orphan" class
above referred to now boldly asserted that the existence of this
class was a religious necessity, because in order to be saved men
must repent, and in order to repent men must sin! At the same time
the old ideas about Antichrist were revived and preached with
fervour by a peasant called Philip, who founded a new sect called
the Philipists. This sect still exists. They hold fast to the old
belief that the Tsar is Antichrist, and that the civil and
ecclesiastical authorities are the servants of Satan--an idea that
was kept alive by the corruption and extortion for which the
Administration was notorious. They do not venture on open
resistance to the authorities, but the bolder members take little
pains to conceal their opinions and sentiments, and may be easily
recognised by their severe aspect, their Puritanical manner, and
their Pharisaical horror of everything which they suppose heretical
and unclean. Some of them, it is said, carry this fastidiousness
to such an extent that they throw away the handle of a door if it
has been touched by a heretic!
It may seem that we have here reached the extreme limits of
fanaticism, but in reality there were men whom even the Pharisaical
Puritanism of the Philipists did not satisfy. These new zealots,
who appeared in the time of Catherine II., but first became known
to the official world in the reign of Nicholas I., rebuked the
lukewarmness of their brethren, and founded a new sect in order to
preserve intact the asceticism practised immediately after the
schism. This sect still exists. They call themselves "Christ's
people" (Christoviye Lyudi), but are better known under the popular
name of "Wanderers" (Stranniki), or "Fugitives" (Beguny). Of all
the sects they are the most hostile to the existing political and
social organisation. Not content with condemning the military
conscription, the payment of taxes, the acceptance of passports,
and everything connected with the civil and ecclesiastical
authorities, they consider it sinful to live peaceably among an
orthodox--that is, according to their belief, a heretical--
population, and to have dealings with any who do not share their
extreme views. Holding the Antichrist doctrine in the extreme
form, they declare that Tsars are the vessels of Satan, that the
Established Church is the dwelling-place of the Father of Lies, and
that all who submit to the authorities are children of the Devil.
According to this creed, those who wish to escape from the wrath to
come must have neither houses nor fixed places of abode, must sever
all ties that bind them to the world, and must wander about
continually from place to place. True Christians are but strangers
and pilgrims in the present life, and whoso binds himself to the
world will perish with the world.
Such is the theory of these Wanderers, but among them, as among the
less fanatical sects, practical necessities have produced
concessions and compromises. As it is impossible to lead a nomadic
life in Russian forests, the Wanderers have been compelled to admit
into their ranks what may be called lay-brethren--men who nominally
belong to the sect, but who live like ordinary mortals and have
some rational way of gaining a livelihood. These latter live in
the villages or towns, support themselves by agriculture or trade,
accept passports from the authorities, pay their taxes regularly,
and conduct themselves in all outward respects like loyal subjects.
Their chief religious duty consists in giving food and shelter to
their more zealous brethren, who have adopted a vagabond life in
practise as well as in theory. It is only when they feel death
approaching that they consider it necessary to separate themselves
from the heretical world, and they effect this by having themselves
carried out to some neighbouring wood--or into a garden if there is
no wood at hand--where they may die in the open air.
Thus, we see, there is among the Russian Nonconformist sects what
may be called a gradation of fanaticism, in which is reflected the
history of the Great Schism. In the Wanderers we have the
representatives of those who adopted and preserved the Antichrist
doctrine in its extreme form--the successors of those who fled to
the forests to escape from the rage of the Beast and to await the
second coming of Christ. In the Philipists we have the
representatives of those who adopted these ideas in a somewhat
softer form, and who came to recognise the necessity of having some
regular means of subsistence until the last trump should be heard.
The Theodosians represent those who were in theory at one with the
preceding category, but who, having less religious fanaticism,
considered it necessary to yield to force and make peace with the
Government without sacrificing their convictions. In the Pomortsi
we see those who preserved only the religious ideas of the schism,
and became reconciled with the civil power. Lastly we have the Old
Ritualists, who differed from all the other sects in retaining the
old ordinances, and who simply rejected the spiritual authority of
the dominant Church. Besides these chief sections of the
Nonconformists there are a great many minor denominations (tolki),
differing from each other on minor points of doctrine. In certain
districts, it is said, nearly every village has one or two
independent sects. This is especially the case among the Don
Cossacks and the Cossacks of the Ural, who are in part descendants
of the men who fled from the early persecutions.
Of all the sects the Old Ritualists stand nearest to the official
Church. They hold the same dogmas, practise the same rites, and
differ only in trifling ceremonial matters, which few people
consider essential. In the hope of inducing them to return to the
official fold the Government created at the beginning of last
century special churches, in which they were allowed to retain
their ceremonial peculiarities on condition of accepting regularly
consecrated priests and submitting to ecclesiastical jurisdiction.
As yet the design has not met with much success. The great
majority of the Old Ritualists regard it as a trap, and assert that
the Church in making this concession has been guilty of self-
contradiction. "The Ecclesiastical Council of Moscow," they say,
"anathematised our forefathers for holding to the old ritual, and
declared that the whole course of nature would be changed sooner
than the curse be withdrawn. The course of nature has not been
changed, but the anathema has been cancelled." This argument ought
to have a certain weight with those who believe in the
infallibility of Ecclesiastical Councils.
Towards the Priestless People the Government has always acted in a
much less conciliatory spirit. Its severity has been sometimes
justified on the ground that sectarianism has had a political as
well as a religious significance. A State like Russia cannot
overlook the existence of sects which preach the duty of systematic
resistance to the civil and ecclesiastical authorities and hold
doctrines which lead to the grossest immorality. This argument, it
must be admitted, is not without a certain force, but it seems to
me that the policy adopted tended to increase rather than diminish
the evils which it sought to cure. Instead of dispelling the
absurd idea that the Tsar was Antichrist by a system of strict and
evenhanded justice, punishing merely actual crimes and
delinquencies, the Government confirmed the notion in the minds of
thousands by persecuting those who had committed no crime and who
desired merely to worship God according to their conscience. Above
all it erred in opposing and punishing those marriages which,
though legally irregular, were the best possible means of
diminishing fanaticism, by leading back the fanatics to healthy
social life. Fortunately these errors have now been abandoned. A
policy of greater clemency and conciliation has been adopted, and
has proved much more efficacious than persecution. The Dissenters
have not returned to the official fold, but they have lost much of
their old fanaticism and exclusiveness.
In respect of numbers the sectarians compose a very formidable
body. Of Old Ritualists and Priestless People there are, it is
said, no less than eleven millions; and the Protestant and
fantastical sects comprise probably about five millions more. If
these numbers be correct, the sectarians constitute about an eighth
of the whole population of the Empire. They count in their ranks
none of the nobles--none of the so-called enlightened class--but
they include in their number a respectable proportion of the
peasants, a third of the rich merchant class, the majority of the
Don Cossacks, and nearly all the Cossacks of the Ural.
Under these circumstances it is important to know how far the
sectarians are politically disaffected. Some people imagine that
in the event of an insurrection or a foreign invasion they might
rise against the Government, whilst others believe that this
supposed danger is purely imaginary. For my own part I agree with
the latter opinion, which is strongly supported by the history of
many important events, such as the French invasion in 1812, the
Crimean War, and the last Polish insurrection. The great majority
of the Schismatics and heretics are, I believe, loyal subjects of
the Tsar. The more violent sects, which are alone capable of
active hostility against the authorities, are weak in numbers, and
regard all outsiders with such profound mistrust that they are
wholly impervious to inflammatory influences from without. Even if
all the sects were capable of active hostility, they would not be
nearly so formidable as their numbers seem to indicate, for they
are hostile to each other, and are wholly incapable of combining
for a common purpose.
Though sectarianism is thus by no means a serious political danger,
it has nevertheless a considerable political significance. It
proves satisfactorily that the Russian people is by no means so
docile and pliable as is commonly supposed, and that it is capable
of showing a stubborn, passive resistance to authority when it
believes great interests to be at stake. The dogged energy which
it has displayed in asserting for centuries its religious liberty
may perhaps some day be employed in the arena of secular politics.
CHAPTER XIX
CHURCH AND STATE
The Russian Orthodox Church--Russia Outside of the Mediaeval Papal
Commonwealth--Influence of the Greek Church--Ecclesiastical History
of Russia--Relations between Church and State--Eastern Orthodoxy
and the Russian National Church--The Synod--Ecclesiastical
Grumbling--Local Ecclesiastical Administration--The Black Clergy
and the Monasteries--The Character of the Eastern Church Reflected
in the History of Religious Art--Practical Consequences--The Union
Scheme.
From the curious world of heretics and Dissenters let us pass now
to the Russian Orthodox Church, to which the great majority of the
Russian people belong. It has played an important part in the
national history, and has exercised a powerful influence in the
formation of the national character.
Russians are in the habit of patriotically and proudly
congratulating themselves on the fact that their forefathers always
resisted successfully the aggressive tendencies of the Papacy, but
it may be doubted whether, from a worldly point of view, the
freedom from Papal authority has been an unmixed blessing for the
country. If the Popes failed to realise their grand design of
creating a vast European empire based on theocratic principles,
they succeeded at least in inspiring with a feeling of brotherhood
and a vague consciousness of common interest all the nations which
acknowledged their spiritual supremacy. These nations, whilst
remaining politically independent and frequently coming into
hostile contact with each other, all looked to Rome as the capital
of the Christian world, and to the Pope as the highest terrestrial
authority. Though the Church did not annihilate nationality, it
made a wide breach in the political barriers, and formed a channel
for international communication by which the social and
intellectual progress of each nation became known to all the other
members of the great Christian confederacy. Throughout the length
and breadth of the Papal Commonwealth educated men had a common
language, a common literature, a common scientific method, and to a
certain extent a common jurisprudence. Western Christendom was
thus all through the Middle Ages not merely an abstract conception
or a geographical expression: if not a political, it was at least a
religious and intellectual unit, and all the countries of which it
was composed benefited more or less by the connection.
For centuries Russia stood outside of this religious and
intellectual confederation, for her Church connected her not with
Rome, but with Constantinople, and Papal Europe looked upon her as
belonging to the barbarous East. When the Mongol hosts swept over
her plains, burnt her towns and villages, and finally incorporated
her into the great empire of Genghis khan, the so-called Christian
world took no interest in the struggle except in so far as its own
safety was threatened. And as time wore on, the barriers which
separated the two great sections of Christendom became more and
more formidable. The aggressive pretensions and ambitious schemes
of the Vatican produced in the Greek Orthodox world a profound
antipathy to the Roman Catholic Church and to Western influence of
every kind. So strong was this aversion that when the nations of
the West awakened in the fifteenth and sixteenth centuries from
their intellectual lethargy and began to move forward on the path
of intellectual and material progress, Russia not only remained
unmoved, but looked on the new civilisation with suspicion and fear
as a thing heretical and accursed. We have here one of the chief
reasons why Russia, at the present day, is in many respects less
civilised than the nations of Western Europe.
But it is not merely in this negative way that the acceptance of
Christianity from Constantinople has affected the fate of Russia.
The Greek Church, whilst excluding Roman Catholic civilisation,
exerted at the same time a powerful positive influence on the
historical development of the nation.
The Church of the West inherited from old Rome something of that
logical, juridical, administrative spirit which had created the
Roman law, and something of that ambition and dogged, energetic
perseverance that had formed nearly the whole known world into a
great centralised empire. The Bishops of Rome early conceived the
design of reconstructing that old empire on a new basis, and long
strove to create a universal Christian theocratic State, in which
kings and other civil authorities should be the subordinates of
Christ's Vicar upon earth. The Eastern Church, on the contrary,
has remained true to her Byzantine traditions, and has never
dreamed of such lofty pretensions. Accustomed to lean on the civil
power, she has always been content to play a secondary part, and
has never strenuously resisted the formation of national churches.
For about two centuries after the introduction of Christianity--
from 988 to 1240--Russia formed, ecclesiastically speaking, part of
the Patriarchate of Constantinople. The metropolitans and the
bishops were Greek by birth and education, and the ecclesiastical
administration was guided and controlled by the Byzantine
Patriarchs. But from the time of the Mongol invasion, when
communication with Constantinople became more difficult and
educated native priests had become more numerous, this complete
dependence on the Patriarch of Constantinople ceased. The Princes
gradually arrogated to themselves the right of choosing the
Metropolitan of Kief--who was at that time the chief ecclesiastical
dignitary in Russia--and merely sent their nominees to
Constantinople for consecration. About 1448 this formality came to
be dispensed with, and the Metropolitan was commonly consecrated by
a Council of Russian bishops. A further step in the direction of
ecclesiastical autonomy was taken in 1589, when the Tsar succeeded
in procuring the consecration of a Russian Patriarch, equal in
dignity and authority to the Patriarchs of Constantinople,
Jerusalem, Antioch, and Alexandria.
In all matters of external form the Patriarch of Moscow was a very
important personage. He exercised a certain influence in civil as
well as ecclesiastical affairs, bore the official title of "Great
Lord" (Veliki Gosudar), which had previously been reserved for the
civil head of the State, and habitually received from the people
scarcely less veneration than the Tsar himself. But in reality he
possessed very little independent power. The Tsar was the real
ruler in ecclesiastical as well as in civil affairs.*
* As this is frequently denied by Russians, it may be well to quote
one authority out of many that might be cited. Bishop Makarii,
whose erudition and good faith are alike above suspicion, says of
Dmitri of the Don: "He arrogated to himself full, unconditional
power over the Head of the Russian Church, and through him over the
whole Russian Church itself." ("Istoriya Russkoi Tserkvi," V., p.
101.) This is said of a Grand Prince who had strong rivals and had
to treat the Church as an ally. When the Grand Princes became
Tsars and had no longer any rivals, their power was certainly not
diminished. Any further confirmation that may be required will be
found in the Life of the famous Patriarch Nikon.
The Russian Patriarchate came to an end in the time of Peter the
Great. Peter wished, among other things, to reform the
ecclesiastical administration, and to introduce into his country
many novelties which the majority of the clergy and of the people
regarded as heretical; and he clearly perceived that a bigoted,
energetic Patriarch might throw considerable obstacles in his way,
and cause him infinite annoyance. Though such a Patriarch might be
deposed without any flagrant violation of the canonical
formalities, the operation would necessarily be attended with great
trouble and loss of time. Peter was no friend of roundabout,
tortuous methods, and preferred to remove the difficulty in his
usual thorough, violent fashion. When the Patriarch Adrian died,
the customary short interregnum was prolonged for twenty years, and
when the people had thus become accustomed to having no Patriarch,
it was announced that no more Patriarchs would be elected. Their
place was supplied by an ecclesiastical council, or Synod, in
which, as a contemporary explained, "the mainspring was Peter's
power, and the pendulum his understanding." The great autocrat
justly considered that such a council could be much more easily
managed than a stubborn Patriarch, and the wisdom of the measure
has been duly appreciated by succeeding sovereigns. Though the
idea of re-establishing the Patriarchate has more than once been
raised, it has never been carried into execution. The Holy Synod
remains the highest ecclesiastical authority.
But the Emperor? What is his relation to the Synod and to the
Church in general?
This is a question about which zealous Orthodox Russians are
extremely sensitive. If a foreigner ventures to hint in their
presence that the Emperor seems to have a considerable influence in
the Church, he may inadvertently produce a little outburst of
patriotic warmth and virtuous indignation. The truth is that many
Russians have a pet theory on this subject, and have at the same
time a dim consciousness that the theory is not quite in accordance
with reality. They hold theoretically that the Orthodox Church has
no "Head" but Christ, and is in some peculiar undefined sense
entirely independent of all terrestrial authority. In this respect
it is often contrasted with the Anglican Church, much to the
disadvantage of the latter; and the supposed differences between
the two are made a theme for semi-religious, semi-patriotic
exultation. Khomiakof, for instance, in one of his most vigorous
poems, predicts that God will one day take the destiny of the world
out of the hands of England in order to give it to Russia, and he
adduces as one of the reasons for this transfer the fact that
England "has chained, with sacrilegious hand, the Church of God to
the pedestal of the vain earthly power." So far the theory. As to
the facts, it is unquestionable that the Tsar exercises a much
greater influence in ecclesiastical affairs than the King and
Parliament in England. All who know the internal history of Russia
are aware that the Government does not draw a clear line of
distinction between the temporal and the spiritual, and that it
occasionally uses the ecclesiastical organisation for political
purposes.
What, then, are the relations between Church and State?
To avoid confusion, we must carefully distinguish between the
Eastern Orthodox Church as a whole and that section of it which is
known as the Russian Church.
The Eastern Orthodox Church* is, properly speaking, a confederation
of independent churches without any central authority--a unity
founded on the possession of a common dogma and on the theoretical
but now unrealisable possibility of holding Ecumenical Councils.
The Russian National Church is one of the members of this
ecclesiastical confederation. In matters of faith it is bound by
the decisions of the ancient Ecumenical Councils, but in all other
respects it enjoys complete independence and autonomy.
* Or Greek Orthodox Church, as it is sometimes called.
In relation to the Orthodox Church as a whole the Emperor of Russia
is nothing more than a simple member, and can no more interfere
with its dogmas or ceremonial than a King of Italy or an Emperor of
the French could modify Roman Catholic theology; but in relation to
the Russian National Church his position is peculiar. He is
described in one of the fundamental laws as "the supreme defender
and preserver of the dogmas of the dominant faith," and immediately
afterwards it is said that "the autocratic power acts in the
ecclesiastical administration by means of the most Holy Governing
Synod, created by it."* This describes very fairly the relations
between the Emperor and the Church. He is merely the defender of
the dogmas, and cannot in the least modify them; but he is at the
same time the chief administrator, and uses the Synod as an
instrument.
* Svod Zakonov I., 42, 43.
Some ingenious people who wish to prove that the creation of the
Synod was not an innovation represent the institution as a
resuscitation of the ancient local councils; but this view is
utterly untenable. The Synod is not a council of deputies from
various sections of the Church, but a permanent college, or
ecclesiastical senate, the members of which are appointed and
dismissed by the Emperor as he thinks fit. It has no independent
legislative authority, for its legislative projects do not become
law till they have received the Imperial sanction; and they are
always published, not in the name of the Church, but in the name of
the Supreme Power. Even in matters of simple administration it is
not independent, for all its resolutions require the consent of the
Procureur, a layman nominated by his Majesty. In theory this
functionary protests only against those resolutions which are not
in accordance with the civil law of the country; but as he alone
has the right to address the Emperor directly on ecclesiastical
concerns, and as all communications between the Emperor and the
Synod pass through his hands, he possesses in reality considerable
power. Besides this, he can always influence the individual
members by holding out prospects of advancement and decorations,
and if this device fails, he can make refractory members retire,
and fill up their places with men of more pliant disposition. A
Council constituted in this way cannot, of course, display much
independence of thought or action, especially in a country like
Russia, where no one ventures to oppose openly the Imperial will.
It must not, however, be supposed that the Russian ecclesiastics
regard the Imperial authority with jealousy or dislike. They are
all most loyal subjects, and warm adherents of autocracy. Those
ideas of ecclesiastical independence which are so common in Western
Europe, and that spirit of opposition to the civil power which
animates the Roman Catholic clergy, are entirely foreign to their
minds. If a bishop sometimes complains to an intimate friend that
he has been brought to St. Petersburg and made a member of the
Synod merely to append his signature to official papers and to give
his consent to foregone conclusions, his displeasure is directed,
not against the Emperor, but against the Procureur. He is full of
loyalty and devotion to the Tsar, and has no desire to see his
Majesty excluded from all influence in ecclesiastical affairs; but
he feels saddened and humiliated when he finds that the whole
government of the Church is in the hands of a lay functionary, who
may be a military man, and who looks at all matters from a layman's
point of view.
This close connection between Church and State and the thoroughly
national character of the Russian Church is well illustrated by the
history of the local ecclesiastical administration. The civil and
the ecclesiastical administration have always had the same
character and have always been modified by the same influences.
The terrorism which was largely used by the Muscovite Tsars and
brought to a climax by Peter the Great appeared equally in both.
In the episcopal circulars, as in the Imperial ukazes, we find
frequent mention of "most cruel corporal punishment," "cruel
punishment with whips, so that the delinquent and others may not
acquire the habit of practising such insolence," and much more of
the same kind. And these terribly severe measures were sometimes
directed against very venial offences. The Bishop of Vologda, for
instance, in 1748 decrees "cruel corporal punishment" against
priests who wear coarse and ragged clothes,* and the records of the
Consistorial courts contain abundant proof that such decrees were
rigorously executed. When Catherine II. introduced a more humane
spirit into the civil administration, corporal punishment was at
once abolished in the Consistorial courts, and the procedure was
modified according to the accepted maxims of civil jurisprudence.
But I must not weary the reader with tiresome historical details.
Suffice it to say that, from the time of Peter the Great downwards,
the character of all the more energetic sovereigns is reflected in
the history of the ecclesiastical administration.
* Znamenski, "Prikhodskoe Dukhovenstvo v Rossii so vremeni reformy
Petra," Kazan, 1873.
Each province, or "government," forms a diocese, and the bishop,
like the civil governor, has a Council which theoretically controls
his power, but practically has no controlling influence whatever.
The Consistorial Council, which has in the theory of ecclesiastical
procedure a very imposing appearance, is in reality the bishop's
chancellerie, and its members are little more than secretaries,
whose chief object is to make themselves agreeable to their
superior. And it must be confessed that, so long as they remain
what they are, the less power they possess the better it will be
for those who have the misfortune to be under their jurisdiction.
The higher dignitaries have at least larger aims and a certain
consciousness of the dignity of their position; but the lower
officials, who have no such healthy restraints and receive
ridiculously small salaries, grossly misuse the little authority
which they possess, and habitually pilfer and extort in the most
shameless manner. The Consistories are, in fact, what the public
offices were in the time of Nicholas I.
The higher ecclesiastical administration has always been in the
hands of the monks, or "Black Clergy," as they are commonly termed,
who form a large and influential class. The monks who first
settled in Russia were, like those who first visited north-western
Europe, men of the earnest, ascetic, missionary type. Filled with
zeal for the glory of God and the salvation of souls, they took
little or no thought for the morrow, and devoutly believed that
their Heavenly Father, without whose knowledge no sparrow falls to
the ground, would provide for their humble wants. Poor, clad in
rags, eating the most simple fare, and ever ready to share what
they had with any one poorer than themselves, they performed
faithfully and earnestly the work which their Master had given them
to do. But this ideal of monastic life soon gave way in Russia, as
in the West, to practices less simple and austere. By the liberal
donations and bequests of the faithful the monasteries became rich
in gold, in silver, in precious stones, and above all in land and
serfs. Troitsa, for instance, possessed at one time 120,000 serfs
and a proportionate amount of land, and it is said that at the
beginning of the eighteenth century more than a fourth of the
entire population had fallen under the jurisdiction of the Church.
Many of the monasteries engaged in commerce, and the monks were, if
we may credit Fletcher, who visited Russia in 1588, the most
intelligent merchants of the country.
During the eighteenth century the Church lands were secularised,
and the serfs of the Church became serfs of the State. This was a
severe blow for the monasteries, but it did not prove fatal, as
many people predicted. Some monasteries were abolished and others
were reduced to extreme poverty, but many survived and prospered.
These could no longer possess serfs, but they had still three
sources of revenue: a limited amount of real property, Government
subsidies, and the voluntary offerings of the faithful. At present
there are about 500 monastic establishments, and the great majority
of them, though not wealthy, have revenues more than sufficient to
satisfy all the requirements of an ascetic life.
Thus in Russia, as in Western Europe, the history of monastic
institutions is composed of three chapters, which may be briefly
entitled: asceticism and missionary enterprise; wealth, luxury, and
corruption; secularisation of property and decline. But between
Eastern and Western monasticism there is at least one marked
difference. The monasticism of the West made at various epochs of
its history a vigorous, spontaneous effort at self-regeneration,
which found expression in the foundation of separate Orders, each
of which proposed to itself some special aim--some special sphere
of usefulness. In Russia we find no similar phenomenon. Here the
monasteries never deviated from the rules of St. Basil, which
restrict the members to religious ceremonies, prayer, and
contemplation. From time to time a solitary individual raised his
voice against the prevailing abuses, or retired from his monastery
to spend the remainder of his days in ascetic solitude; but neither
in the monastic population as a whole, nor in any particular
monastery, do we find at any time a spontaneous, vigorous movement
towards reform. During the last two hundred years reforms have
certainly been effected, but they have all been the work of the
civil power, and in the realisation of them the monks have shown
little more than the virtue of resignation. Here, as elsewhere, we
have evidence of that inertness, apathy, and want of spontaneous
vigour which form one of the most characteristic traits of Russian
national life. In this, as in other departments of national
activity, the spring of action has lain not in the people, but in
the Government.
It is only fair to the monks to state that in their dislike to
progress and change of every kind they merely reflect the
traditional spirit of the Church to which they belong. The Russian
Church, like the Eastern Orthodox Church generally, is essentially
conservative. Anything in the nature of a religious revival is
foreign to her traditions and character. Quieta non movere is her
fundamental principle of conduct. She prides herself as being
above terrestrial influences.
The modifications that have been made in her administrative
organisation have not affected her inner nature. In spirit and
character she is now what she was under the Patriarchs in the time
of the Muscovite Tsars, holding fast to the promise that no jot or
tittle shall pass from the law till all be fulfilled. To those who
talk about the requirements of modern life and modern science she
turns a deaf ear. Partly from the predominance which she gives to
the ceremonial element, partly from the fact that her chief aim is
to preserve unmodified the doctrine and ceremonial as determined by
the early Ecumenical Councils, and partly from the low state of
general culture among the clergy, she has ever remained outside of
the intellectual movements. The attempts of the Roman Catholic
Church to develop the traditional dogmas by definition and
deduction, and the efforts of Protestants to reconcile their creeds
with progressive science and the ever-varying intellectual currents
of the time, are alike foreign to her nature. Hence she has
produced no profound theological treatises conceived in a
philosophical spirit, and has made no attempt to combat the spirit
of infidelity in its modern forms. Profoundly convinced that her
position is impregnable, she has "let the nations rave," and
scarcely deigned to cast a glance at their intellectual and
religious struggles. In a word, she is "in the world, but not of
it."
If we wish to see represented in a visible form the peculiar
characteristics of the Russian Church, we have only to glance at
Russian religious art, and compare it with that of Western Europe.
In the West, from the time of the Renaissance downwards, religious
art has kept pace with artistic progress. Gradually it emancipated
itself from archaic forms and childish symbolism, converted the
lifeless typical figures into living individuals, lit up their dull
eyes and expressionless faces with human intelligence and human
feeling, and finally aimed at archaeological accuracy in costume
and other details. Thus in the West the Icon grew slowly into the
naturalistic portrait, and the rude symbolical groups developed
gradually into highly-finished historical pictures. In Russia the
history of religious art has been entirely different. Instead of
distinctive schools of painting and great religious artists, there
has been merely an anonymous traditional craft, destitute of any
artistic individuality. In all the productions of this craft the
old Byzantine forms have been faithfully and rigorously preserved,
and we can see reflected in the modern Icons--stiff, archaic,
expressionless--the immobility of the Eastern Church in general,
and of the Russian Church in particular.
To the Roman Catholic, who struggles against science as soon as it
contradicts traditional conceptions, and to the Protestant, who
strives to bring his religious beliefs into accordance with his
scientific knowledge, the Russian Church may seem to resemble an
antediluvian petrifaction, or a cumbrous line-of-battle ship that
has been long stranded. It must be confessed, however, that the
serene inactivity for which she is distinguished has had very
valuable practical consequences. The Russian clergy have neither
that haughty, aggressive intolerance which characterises their
Roman Catholic brethren, nor that bitter, uncharitable, sectarian
spirit which is too often to be found among Protestants. They
allow not only to heretics, but also to members of their own
communion, the most complete intellectual freedom, and never think
of anathematising any one for his scientific or unscientific
opinions. All that they demand is that those who have been born
within the pale of Orthodoxy should show the Church a certain
nominal allegiance; and in this matter of allegiance they are by no
mean very exacting. So long as a member refrains from openly
attacking the Church and from going over to another confession, he
may entirely neglect all religious ordinances and publicly profess
scientific theories logically inconsistent with any kind of
dogmatic religious belief without the slightest danger of incurring
ecclesiastical censure.
This apathetic tolerance may be partly explained by the national
character, but it is also to some extent due to the peculiar
relations between Church and State. The government vigilantly
protects the Church from attack, and at the same time prevents her
from attacking her enemies. Hence religious questions are never
discussed in the Press, and the ecclesiastical literature is all
historical, homiletic, or devotional. The authorities allow public
oral discussions to be held during Lent in the Kremlin of Moscow
between members of the State Church and Old Ritualists; but these
debates are not theological in our sense of the term. They turn
exclusively on details of Church history, and on the minutiae of
ceremonial observance.
A few years ago there was a good deal of vague talk about a
possible union of the Russian and Anglican Churches. If by "union"
is meant simply union in the bonds of brotherly love, there can be,
of course, no objection to any amount of such pia desideria; but if
anything more real and practical is intended, the project is an
absurdity. A real union of the Russian and Anglican Churches would
be as difficult of realisation, and is as undesirable, as a union
of the Russian Council of State and the British House of Commons.*
* I suppose that the more serious partisans of the union scheme
mean union with the Eastern Orthodox, and not with the Russian,
Church. To them the above remarks are not addressed. Their scheme
is, in my opinion, unrealisable and undesirable, but it contains
nothing absurd.
CHAPTER XX
THE NOBLESSE
The Nobles In Early Times--The Mongol Domination--The Tsardom of
Muscovy--Family Dignity--Reforms of Peter the Great--The Nobles
Adopt West-European Conceptions--Abolition of Obligatory Service--
Influence of Catherine II.--The Russian Dvoryanstvo Compared with
the French Noblesse and the English Aristocracy--Russian Titles--
Probable Future of the Russian Noblesse.
Hitherto I have been compelling the reader to move about among what
we should call the lower classes--peasants, burghers, traders,
parish priests, Dissenters, heretics, Cossacks, and the like--and
he feels perhaps inclined to complain that he has had no
opportunity of mixing with what old-fashioned people call gentle-
folk and persons of quality. By way of making amends to him for
this reprehensible conduct on my part, I propose now to present him
to the whole Noblesse* in a body, not only those at present living,
but also their near and distant ancestors, right back to the
foundation of the Russian Empire a thousand years ago. Thereafter
I shall introduce him to some of the country families and invite
him to make with me a few country-house visits.
* I use here a foreign, in preference to an English, term, because
the word "Nobility" would convey a false impression.
Etymologically the Russian word "Dvoryanin" means a Courtier (from
Dvor=court); but this term is equally objectionable, because the
great majority of the Dvoryanstvo have nothing to do with the
Court.
In the old times, when Russia was merely a collection of some
seventy independent principalities, each reigning prince was
surrounded by a group of armed men, composed partly of Boyars, or
large landed proprietors, and partly of knights, or soldiers of
fortune. These men, who formed the Noblesse of the time, were to a
certain extent under the authority of the Prince, but they were by
no means mere obedient, silent executors of his will. The Boyars
might refuse to take part in his military expeditions, and the
"free-lances" might leave his service and seek employment
elsewhere. If he wished to go to war without their consent, they
could say to him, as they did on one occasion, "You have planned
this yourself, Prince, so we will not go with you, for we knew
nothing of it." Nor was this resistance to the princely will
always merely passive. Once, in the principality of Galitch, the
armed men seized their prince, killed his favourites, burned his
mistress, and made him swear that he would in future live with his
lawful wife. To his successor, who had married the wife of a
priest, they spoke thus: "We have not risen against YOU, Prince,
but we will not do reverence to a priest's wife: we will put her to
death, and then you may marry whom you please." Even the energetic
Bogolubski, one of the most remarkable of the old Princes, did not
succeed in having his own way. When he attempted to force the
Boyars he met with stubborn opposition, and was finally
assassinated. From these incidents, which might be indefinitely
multiplied from the old chronicles, we see that in the early period
of Russian history the Boyars and knights were a body of free men,
possessing a considerable amount of political power.
Under the Mongol domination this political equilibrium was
destroyed. When the country had been conquered, the Princes became
servile vassals of the Khan and arbitrary rulers towards their own
subjects. The political significance of the nobles was thereby
greatly diminished. It was not, however, by any means annihilated.
Though the Prince no longer depended entirely on their support, he
had an interest in retaining their services, to protect his
territory in case of sudden attack, or to increase his possessions
at the expense of his neighbours when a convenient opportunity
presented itself. Theoretically, such conquests were impossible,
for all removing of the ancient landmarks depended on the decision
of the Khan; but in reality the Khan paid little attention to the
affairs of his vassals so long as the tribute was regularly paid;
and much took place in Russia without his permission. We find,
therefore, in some of the principalities the old relations still
subsisting under Mongol rule. The famous Dmitri of the Don, for
instance, when on his death-bed, speaks thus to his Boyars: "You
know my habits and my character; I was born among you, grew up
among you, governed with you--fighting by your side, showing you
honour and love, and placing you over towns and districts. I loved
your children, and did evil to no one. I rejoiced with you in your
joy, mourned with you in your grief, and called you the princes of
my land." Then, turning to his children, he adds, as a parting
advice: "Love your Boyars, my children; show them the honour which
their services merit, and undertake nothing without their consent."
When the Grand Princes of Moscow brought the other principalities
under their power, and formed them into the Tsardom of Muscovy, the
nobles descended another step in the political scale. So long as
there were many principalities they could quit the service of a
Prince as soon as he gave them reason to be discontented, knowing
that they would be well received by one of his rivals; but now they
had no longer any choice. The only rival of Moscow was Lithuania,
and precautions were taken to prevent the discontented from
crossing the Lithuanian frontier. The nobles were no longer
voluntary adherents of a Prince, but had become subjects of a Tsar;
and the Tsars were not as the old Princes had been. By a violent
legal fiction they conceived themselves to be the successors of the
Byzantine Emperors, and created a new court ceremonial, borrowed
partly from Constantinople and partly from the Mongol Horde. They
no longer associated familiarly with the Boyars, and no longer
asked their advice, but treated them rather as menials. When the
nobles entered their august master's presence they prostrated
themselves in Oriental fashion--occasionally as many as thirty
times--and when they incurred his displeasure they were summarily
flogged or executed, according to the Tsar's good pleasure. In
succeeding to the power of the Khans, the Tsars had adopted, we
see, a good deal of the Mongol system of government.
It may seem strange that a class of men which had formerly shown a
proud spirit of independence should have submitted quietly to such
humiliation and oppression without making a serious effort to curb
the new power, which had no longer a Tartar Horde at its back to
quell opposition. But we must remember that the nobles, as well as
the Princes, had passed in the meantime through the school of the
Mongol domination. In the course of two centuries they had
gradually become accustomed to despotic rule in the Oriental sense.
If they felt their position humiliating and irksome, they must have
felt, too, how difficult it was to better it. Their only resource
lay in combining against the common oppressor; and we have only to
glance at the motley, disorganised group, as they cluster round the
Tsar, to perceive that combination was extremely difficult. We can
distinguish there the mediatised Princes, still harbouring designs
for the recovery of their independence; the Moscow Boyars, jealous
of their family honour and proud of Muscovite supremacy; Tartar
Murzi, who have submitted to be baptised and have received land
like the other nobles; the Novgorodian magnate, who cannot forget
the ancient glory of his native city; Lithuanian nobles, who find
it more profitable to serve the Tsar than their own sovereign;
petty chiefs who have fled from the opposition of the Teutonic
order; and soldiers of fortune from every part of Russia. Strong,
permanent political factors are not easily formed out of such
heterogeneous material.
At the end of the sixteenth century the old dynasty became extinct,
and after a short period of political anarchy, commonly called "the
troublous times" (smutnoe vremya), the Romanof family were raised
to the throne by the will of the people, or at least by those who
were assumed to be its representatives. By this change the
Noblesse acquired a somewhat better position. They were no longer
exposed to capricious tyranny and barbarous cruelty, such as they
had experienced at the hands of Ivan the Terrible, but they did
not, as a class, gain any political influence. There were still
rival families and rival factions, but there were no political
parties in the proper sense of the term, and the highest aim of
families and factions was to gain the favour of the Tsar.
The frequent quarrels about precedence which took place among the
rival families at this period form one of the most curious episodes
of Russian history. The old patriarchal conception of the family
as a unit, one and indivisible, was still so strong among these men
that the elevation or degradation of one member of a family was
considered to affect deeply the honour of all the other members.
Each noble family had its rank in a recognised scale of dignity,
according to the rank which it held, or had previously held, in the
Tsar's service; and a whole family would have considered itself
dishonoured if one of its members accepted a post lower than that
to which he was entitled. Whenever a vacant place in the service
was filled up, the subordinates of the successful candidate
examined the official records and the genealogical trees of their
families, in order to discover whether some ancestor of their new
superior had not served under one of their own ancestors. If the
subordinate found such a case, he complained to the Tsar that it
was not becoming for him to serve under a man who had less family
honour than himself.
Unfounded complaints of this kind often entailed imprisonment or
corporal punishment, but in spite of this the quarrels for
precedence were very frequent. At the commencement of a campaign
many such disputes were sure to arise, and the Tsar's decision was
not always accepted by the party who considered himself aggrieved.
I have met at least with one example of a great dignitary
voluntarily mutilating his hand in order to escape the necessity of
serving under a man whom he considered his inferior in family
dignity. Even at the Tsar's table these rivalries sometimes
produced unseemly incidents, for it was almost impossible to
arrange the places so as to satisfy all the guests. In one
recorded instance a noble who received a place lower than that to
which he considered himself entitled openly declared to the Tsar
that he would rather be condemned to death than submit to such an
indignity. In another instance of a similar kind the refractory
guest was put on his chair by force, but saved his family honour by
slipping under the table!
The next transformation of the Noblesse was effected by Peter the
Great. Peter was by nature and position an autocrat, and could
brook no opposition. Having set before himself a great aim, he
sought everywhere obedient, intelligent, energetic instruments to
carry out his designs. He himself served the State zealously--as a
common artisan, when he considered it necessary--and he insisted on
all his subjects doing likewise, under pain of merciless
punishment. To noble birth and long pedigrees he habitually showed
a most democratic, or rather autocratic, indifference. Intent on
obtaining the service of living men, he paid no attention to the
claims of dead ancestors, and gave to his servants the pay and
honour which their services merited, irrespectively of birth or
social position. Hence many of his chief coadjutors had no
connection with the old Russian families. Count Yaguzhinski, who
long held one of the most important posts in the State, was the son
of a poor sacristan; Count Devier was a Portuguese by birth, and
had been a cabin-boy; Baron Shafirof was a Jew; Hannibal, who died
with the rank of Commander in Chief, was a negro who had been
bought in Constantinople; and his Serene Highness Prince Menshikof
had begun life, it was said, as a baker's apprentice! For the
future, noble birth was to count for nothing. The service of the
State was thrown open to men of all ranks, and personal merit was
to be the only claim to promotion.
This must have seemed to the Conservatives of the time a most
revolutionary and reprehensible proceeding, but it did not satisfy
the reforming tendencies of the great autocrat. He went a step
further, and entirely changed the legal status of the Noblesse.
Down to his time the nobles were free to serve or not as they
chose, and those who chose to serve enjoyed land on what we should
call a feudal tenure. Some served permanently in the military or
civil administration, but by far the greater number lived on their
estates, and entered the active service merely when the militia was
called out in view of war. This system was completely changed when
Peter created a large standing army and a great centralised
bureaucracy. By one of those "fell swoops" which periodically
occur in Russian history, he changed the feudal into freehold
tenures, and laid down the principle that all nobles, whatever
their landed possessions might be, should serve the State in the
army, the fleet, or the civil administration, from boyhood to old
age. In accordance with this principle, any noble who refused to
serve was not only deprived of his estate, as in the old times, but
was declared to be a traitor and might be condemned to capital
punishment.
The nobles were thus transformed into servants of the State, and
the State in the time of Peter was a hard taskmaster. They
complained bitterly, and with reason, that they had been deprived
of their ancient rights, and were compelled to accept quietly and
uncomplainingly whatever burdens their master chose to place upon
them. "Though our country," they said, "is in no danger of
invasion, no sooner is peace concluded than plans are laid for a
new war, which has generally no other foundation than the ambition
of the Sovereign, or perhaps merely the ambition of one of his
Ministers. To please him our peasants are utterly exhausted, and
we ourselves are forced to leave our homes and families, not as
formerly for a single campaign, but for long years. We are
compelled to contract debts and to entrust our estates to thieving
overseers, who commonly reduce them to such a condition that when
we are allowed to retire from the service, in consequence of old
age or illness, we cannot to the end of our lives retrieve our
prosperity. In a word, we are so exhausted and ruined by the
keeping up of a standing army, and by the consequences flowing
therefrom, that the most cruel enemy, though he should devastate
the whole Empire, could not cause us one-half of the injury."*
* These complaints have been preserved by Vockerodt, a Prussian
diplomatic agent of the time.
This Spartan regime, which ruthlessly sacrificed private interests
to considerations of State policy, could not long be maintained in
its pristine severity. It undermined its own foundations by
demanding too much. Draconian laws threatening confiscation and
capital punishment were of little avail. Nobles became monks,
inscribed themselves as merchants, or engaged themselves as
domestic servants, in order to escape their obligations. "Some,"
says a contemporary, "grow old in disobedience and have never once
appeared in active service. . . . There is, for instance, Theodore
Mokeyef. . . . In spite of the strict orders sent regarding him no
one could ever catch him. Some of those sent to take him he
belaboured with blows, and when he could not beat the messengers,
he pretended to be dangerously ill, or feigned idiocy, and, running
into the pond, stood in the water up to his neck; but as soon as
the messengers were out of sight he returned home and roared like a
lion." *
* Pososhkof, "O skudosti i bogatstve."
After Peter's death the system was gradually relaxed, but the
Noblesse could not be satisfied by partial concessions. Russia had
in the meantime moved, as it were, out of Asia into Europe, and had
become one of the great European Powers. The upper classes had
been gradually learning something of the fashions, the literature,
the institutions, and the moral conceptions of Western Europe, and
the nobles naturally compared the class to which they belonged with
the aristocracies of Germany and France. For those who were
influenced by the new foreign ideas the comparison was humiliating.
In the West the Noblesse was a free and privileged class, proud of
its liberty, its rights, and its culture; whereas in Russia the
nobles were servants of the State, without privileges, without
dignity, subject to corporal punishment, and burdened with onerous
duties from which there was no escape. Thus arose in that section
of the Noblesse which had some acquaintance with Western
civilisation a feeling of discontent, and a desire to gain a social
position similar to that of the nobles in France and Germany.
These aspirations were in part realised by Peter III., who in 1762
abolished the principle of obligatory service. His consort,
Catherine II., went much farther in the same direction, and
inaugurated a new epoch in the history of the Dvoryanstvo, a period
in which its duties and obligations fell into the background, and
its rights and privileges came to the front.
Catherine had good reason to favour the Noblesse. As a foreigner
and a usurper, raised to the throne by a Court conspiracy, she
could not awaken in the masses that semi-religious veneration which
the legitimate Tsars have always enjoyed, and consequently she had
to seek support in the upper classes, who were less rigid and
uncompromising in their conceptions of legitimacy. She confirmed,
therefore, the ukaz which abolished obligatory service of the
nobles, and sought to gain their voluntary service by honours and
rewards. In her manifestoes she always spoke of them in the most
flattering terms; and tried to convince them that the welfare of
the country depended on their loyalty and devotion. Though she had
no intention of ceding any of her political power, she formed the
nobles of each province into a corporation, with periodical
assemblies, which were supposed to resemble the French Provincial
Parliaments, and entrusted to each of these corporations a large
part of the local administration. By these and similar means,
aided by her masculine energy and feminine tact, she made herself
very popular, and completely changed the old conceptions about the
public service. Formerly service had been looked on as a burden;
now it came to be looked on as a privilege. Thousands who had
retired to their estates after the publication of the liberation
edict now flocked back and sought appointments, and this tendency
was greatly increased by the brilliant campaigns against the Turks,
which excited the patriotic feelings and gave plentiful
opportunities of promotion. "Not only landed proprietors," it is
said in a comedy of the time,* "but all men, even shopkeepers and
cobblers, aim at becoming officers, and the man who has passed his
whole life without official rank seems to be not a human being."
* Knyazhnina, "Khvastun."
And Catherine did more than this. She shared the idea--generally
accepted throughout Europe since the brilliant reign of Louis XIV.--
that a refined, pomp-loving, pleasure-seeking Court Noblesse was
not only the best bulwark of Monarchy, but also a necessary
ornament of every highly civilised State; and as she ardently
desired that her country should have the reputation of being highly
civilised, she strove to create this national ornament. The love
of French civilisation, which already existed among the upper
classes of her subjects, here came to her aid, and her efforts in
this direction were singularly successful. The Court of St.
Petersburg became almost as brilliant, as galant, and as frivolous
as the Court of Versailles. All who aimed at high honours adopted
French fashions, spoke the French language, and affected an
unqualified admiration for French classical literature. The
Courtiers talked of the point d'honneur, discussed the question as
to what was consistent with the dignity of a noble, sought to
display "that chivalrous spirit which constitutes the pride and
ornament of France"; and looked back with horror on the humiliating
position of their fathers and grandfathers. "Peter the Great,"
writes one of them, "beat all who surrounded him, without
distinction of family or rank; but now, many of us would certainly
prefer capital punishment to being beaten or flogged, even though
the castigation were applied by the sacred hands of the Lord's
Anointed."
The tone which reigned in the Court circle of St. Petersburg spread
gradually towards the lower ranks of the Dvoryanstvo, and it seemed
to superficial observers that a very fair imitation of the French
Noblesse had been produced; but in reality the copy was very unlike
the model. The Russian Dvoryanin easily learned the language and
assumed the manners of the French gentilhomme, and succeeded in
changing his physical and intellectual exterior; but all those
deeper and more delicate parts of human nature which are formed by
the accumulated experience of past generations could not be so
easily and rapidly changed. The French gentilhomme of the
eighteenth century was the direct descendant of the feudal baron,
with the fundamental conceptions of his ancestors deeply embedded
in his nature. He had not, indeed, the old haughty bearing towards
the Sovereign, and his language was tinged with the fashionable
democratic philosophy of the time; but he possessed a large
intellectual and moral inheritance that had come down to him
directly from the palmy days of feudalism--an inheritance which
even the Great Revolution, which was then preparing, could not
annihilate. The Russian noble, on the contrary, had received from
his ancestors entirely different traditions. His father and
grandfather had been conscious of the burdens rather than the
privileges of the class to which they belonged. They had
considered it no disgrace to receive corporal punishment, and had
been jealous of their honour, not as gentlemen or descendants of
Boyars, but as Brigadiers, College Assessors, or Privy Counsellors.
Their dignity had rested not on the grace of God, but on the will
of the Tsar. Under these circumstances even the proudest magnate
of Catherine's Court, though he might speak French as fluently as
his mother tongue, could not be very deeply penetrated with the
conception of noble blood, the sacred character of nobility, and
the numerous feudal ideas interwoven with these conceptions. And
in adopting the outward forms of a foreign culture the nobles did
not, it seems, gain much in true dignity. "The old pride of the
nobles has fallen!" exclaims one who had more genuine aristocratic
feeling than his fellows.* "There are no longer any honourable
families; but merely official rank and personal merits. All seek
official rank, and as all cannot render direct services,
distinctions are sought by every possible means--by flattering the
Monarch and toadying the important personages." There was
considerable truth in this complaint, but the voice of this
solitary aristocrat was as of one crying in the wilderness. The
whole of the educated classes--men of old family and parvenus
alike--were, with few exceptions, too much engrossed with place-
hunting to attend to such sentimental wailing.
* Prince Shtcherbatof.
If the Russian Noblesse was thus in its new form but a very
imperfect imitation of its French model, it was still more unlike
the English aristocracy. Notwithstanding the liberal phrases in
which Catherine habitually indulged, she never had the least
intention of ceding one jot or tittle of her autocratic power, and
the Noblesse as a class never obtained even a shadow of political
influence. There was no real independence under the new airs of
dignity and hauteur. In all their acts and openly expressed
opinions the courtiers were guided by the real or supposed wishes
of the Sovereign, and much of their political sagacity was employed
in endeavouring to discover what would please her. "People never
talk politics in the salons," says a contemporary witness,* not
even to praise the Government. Fear has produced habits of
prudence, and the Frondeurs of the Capital express their opinions
only in the confidence of intimate friendship or in a relationship
still more confidential. Those who cannot bear this constraint
retire to Moscow, which cannot be called the centre of opposition,
for there is no such thing as opposition in a country with an
autocratic Government, but which is the capital of the
discontented." And even there the discontent did not venture to
show itself in the Imperial presence. "In Moscow," says another
witness, accustomed to the obsequiousness of Versailles, "you might
believe yourself to be among republicans who have just thrown off
the yoke of a tyrant, but as soon as the Court arrives you see
nothing but abject slaves."**
* Segur, long Ambassador of France at the Court of Catherine.
** Sabathier de Cabres, "Catherine II. et la Cour de Russie en
1772."
Though thus excluded from direct influence in political affairs the
Noblesse might still have acquired a certain political significance
in the State, by means of the Provincial Assemblies, and by the
part they took in local administration; but in reality they had
neither the requisite political experience nor the requisite
patience, nor even the desire to pursue such a policy. The
majority of the proprietors preferred the chances of promotion in
the Imperial service to the tranquil life of a country gentleman;
and those who resided permanently on their estates showed
indifference or positive antipathy to everything connected with the
local administration. What was officially described as "a
privilege conferred on the nobles for their fidelity, and for the
generous sacrifice of their lives in their country's cause," was
regarded by those who enjoyed it as a new kind of obligatory
service--an obligation to supply judges and officers of rural
police.
If we require any additional proof that the nobles amidst all these
changes were still as dependent as ever on the arbitrary will or
caprice of the Monarch, we have only to glance at their position in
the time of Paul I., the capricious, eccentric, violent son and
successor of Catherine. The autobiographical memoirs of the time
depict in vivid colours the humiliating position of even the
leading men in the State, in constant fear of exciting by act,
word, or look the wrath of the Sovereign. As we read these
contemporary records we seem to have before us a picture of ancient
Rome under the most despotic and capricious of her Emperors.
Irritated and embittered before his accession to the throne by the
haughty demeanour of his mother's favourites, Paul lost no
opportunity of showing his contempt for aristocratic pretensions,
and of humiliating those who were supposed to harbour them.
"Apprenez, Monsieur," he said angrily on one occasion to Dumouriez,
who had accidentally referred to one of the "considerable"
personages of the Court, "Apprenez qu'il n'y a pas de considerable
ici, que la personne a laquelle je parle et pendant le temps que je
lui parle!"*
* This saying is often falsely attributed to Nicholas. The
anecdote is related by Segur.
From the time of Catherine down to the accession of Alexander II.
in 1855 no important change was made in the legal status of the
Noblesse, but a gradual change took place in its social character
by the continual influx of Western ideas and Western culture. The
exclusively French culture in vogue at the Court of Catherine
assumed a more cosmopolitan colouring, and permeated downwards till
all who had any pretensions to being civilises spoke French with
tolerable fluency and possessed at least a superficial acquaintance
with the literature of Western Europe. What chiefly distinguished
them in the eye of the law from the other classes was the privilege
of possessing "inhabited estates"--that is to say, estates with
serfs. By the emancipation of the serfs in 1861 this valuable
privilege was abolished, and about one-half of their landed
property passed into the hands of the peasantry. By the
administrative reforms which have since taken place, any little
significance which the provincial corporations may have possessed
has been annihilated. Thus at the present day the nobles are on a
level with the other classes with regard to the right of possessing
landed property and the administration of local affairs.
From this rapid sketch the reader will easily perceive that the
Russian Noblesse has had a peculiar historical development. In
Germany, France, and England the nobles were early formed into a
homogeneous organised body by the political conditions in which
they were placed. They had to repel the encroaching tendencies of
the Monarchy on the one hand, and of the bourgeoisie on the other;
and in this long struggle with powerful rivals they instinctively
held together and developed a vigorous esprit de corps. New
members penetrated into their ranks, but these intruders were so
few in number that they were rapidly assimilated without modifying
the general character or recognised ideals of the class, and
without rudely disturbing the fiction of purity of blood. The
class thus assumed more and more the nature of a caste with a
peculiar intellectual and moral culture, and stoutly defended its
position and privileges till the ever-increasing power of the
middle classes undermined its influence. Its fate in different
countries has been different. In Germany it clung to its feudal
traditions, and still preserves its social exclusiveness. In
France it was deprived of its political influence by the Monarchy
and crushed by the Revolution. In England it moderated its
pretensions, allied itself with the middle classes, created under
the disguise of constitutional monarchy an aristocratic republic,
and conceded inch by inch, as necessity demanded, a share of its
political influence to the ally that had helped it to curb the
Royal power. Thus the German baron, the French gentilhomme, and
the English nobleman represent three distinct, well-marked types;
but amidst all their diversities they have much in common. They
have all preserved to a greater or less extent a haughty
consciousness of innate inextinguishable superiority over the lower
orders, together with a more or less carefully disguised dislike
for the class which has been, and still is, an aggressive rival.
The Russian Noblesse has not these characteristics. It was formed
out of more heterogeneous materials, and these materials did not
spontaneously combine to form an organic whole, but were crushed
into a conglomerate mass by the weight of the autocratic power. It
never became a semi-independent factor in the State. What rights
and privileges it possesses it received from the Monarchy, and
consequently it has no deep-rooted jealousy or hatred of the
Imperial prerogative. On the other hand, it has never had to
struggle with the other social classes, and therefore it harbours
towards them no feelings of rivalry or hostility. If we hear a
Russian noble speak with indignation of autocracy or with acrimony
of the bourgeoisie, we may be sure that these feelings have their
source, not in traditional conceptions, but in principles learned
from the modern schools of social and political philosophy. The
class to which he belongs has undergone so many transformations
that it has no hoary traditions or deep-rooted prejudices, and
always willingly adapts itself to existing conditions. Indeed, it
may be said in general that it looks more to the future than the
past, and is ever ready to accept any new ideas that wear the badge
of progress. Its freedom from traditions and prejudices makes it
singularly susceptible of generous enthusiasm and capable of
vigorous spasmodic action, but calm moral courage and tenacity of
purpose are not among its prominent attributes. In a word, we find
in it neither the peculiar virtues nor the peculiar vices which are
engendered and fostered by an atmosphere of political liberty.
However we may explain the fact, there is no doubt that the Russian
Noblesse has little or nothing of what we call aristocratic
feeling--little or nothing of that haughty, domineering, exclusive
spirit which we are accustomed to associate with the word
aristocracy. We find plenty of Russians who are proud of their
wealth, of their culture, or of their official position, but we
rarely find a Russian who is proud of his birth or imagines that
the fact of his having a long pedigree gives him any right to
political privileges or social consideration. Hence there is a
certain amount of truth in the oft-repeated saying that there is in
reality no aristocracy in Russia.
Certainly the Noblesse as a whole cannot be called an aristocracy.
If the term is to be used at all, it must be applied to a group of
families which cluster around the Court and form the highest ranks
of the Noblesse. This social aristocracy contains many old
families, but its real basis is official rank and general culture
rather than pedigree or blood. The feudal conceptions of noble
birth, good family, and the like have been adopted by some of its
members, but do not form one of its conspicuous features. Though
habitually practising a certain exclusiveness, it has none of those
characteristics of a caste which we find in the German Adel, and is
utterly unable to understand such institutions as Tafelf higkeit,?
by which a man who has not a pedigree of a certain length is
considered unworthy to sit down at a royal table. It takes rather
the English aristocracy as its model, and harbours the secret hope
of one day obtaining a social and political position similar to
that of the nobility and gentry of England. Though it has no
peculiar legal privileges, its actual position in the
Administration and at Court gives its members great facilities for
advancement in the public service. On the other hand, its semi-
bureaucratic character, together with the law and custom of
dividing landed property among the children at the death of their
parents, deprives it of stability. New men force their way into it
by official distinction, whilst many of the old families are
compelled by poverty to retire from its ranks. The son of a small
proprietor, or even of a parish priest, may rise to the highest
offices of State, whilst the descendants of the half-mythical Rurik
may descend to the position of peasants. It is said that not very
long ago a certain Prince Krapotkin gained his living as a cabman
in St. Petersburg!
It is evident, then, that this social aristocracy must not be
confounded with the titled families. Titles do not possess the
same value in Russia as in Western Europe. They are very common--
because the titled families are numerous, and all the children bear
the titles of the parents even while the parents are still alive--
and they are by no means always associated with official rank,
wealth, social position, or distinction of any kind. There are
hundreds of princes and princesses who have not the right to appear
at Court, and who would not be admitted into what is called in St.
Petersburg la societe, or indeed into refined society in any
country.
The only genuine Russian title is Knyaz, commonly translated
"Prince." It is borne by the descendants of Rurik, of the
Lithuanian Prince Ghedimin, and of the Tartar Khans and Murzi
officially recognised by the Tsars. Besides these, there are
fourteen families who have adopted it by Imperial command during
the last two centuries. The titles of count and baron are modern
importations, beginning with the time of Peter the Great. From
Peter and his successors about seventy families have received the
title of count and ten that of baron. The latter are all, with two
exceptions, of foreign extraction, and are mostly descended from
Court bankers.*
* Besides these, there are of course the German counts and barons
of the Baltic Provinces, who are Russian subjects.
There is a very common idea that Russian nobles are as a rule
enormously rich. This is a mistake. The majority of them are
poor. At the time of the Emancipation, in 1861, there were 100,247
landed proprietors, and of these, more than 41,000 were possessors
of less than twenty-one male serfs--that is to say, were in a
condition of poverty. A proprietor who was owner of 500 serfs was
not considered as by any means very rich, and yet there were only
3,803 proprietors belonging in that category. There were a few,
indeed, whose possessions were enormous. Count Sheremetief, for
instance, possessed more than 150,000 male serfs, or in other words
more than 300,000 souls; and thirty years ago Count Orloff-Davydof
owned considerably more than half a million of acres. The Demidof
family derive colossal revenues from their mines, and the
Strogonofs have estates which, if put together, would be sufficient
in extent to form a good-sized independent State in Western Europe.
The very rich families, however, are not numerous. The lavish
expenditure in which Russian nobles often indulge indicates too
frequently not large fortune, but simply foolish ostentation and
reckless improvidence.
Perhaps, after having spoken so much about the past history of the
Noblesse, I ought to endeavour to cast its horoscope, or at least
to say something of its probable future. Though predictions are
always hazardous, it is sometimes possible, by tracing the great
lines of history in the past, to follow them for a little distance
into the future. If it be allowable to apply this method of
prediction in the present matter, I should say that the Russian
Dvoryanstvo will assimilate with the other classes, rather than
form itself into an exclusive corporation. Hereditary
aristocracies may be preserved--or at least their decomposition may
be retarded--where they happen to exist, but it seems that they can
no longer be created. In Western Europe there is a large amount of
aristocratic sentiment, both in the nobles and in the people; but
it exists in spite of, rather than in consequence of, actual social
conditions. It is not a product of modern society, but an heirloom
that has come down to us from feudal times, when power, wealth, and
culture were in the hands of a privileged few. If there ever was
in Russia a period corresponding to the feudal times in Western
Europe, it has long since been forgotten. There is very little
aristocratic sentiment either in the people or in the nobles, and
it is difficult to imagine any source from which it could now be
derived. More than this, the nobles do not desire to make such an
acquisition. In so far as they have any political aspirations,
they aim at securing the political liberty of the people as a
whole, and not at acquiring exclusive rights and privileges for
their own class.
In that section which I have called a social aristocracy there are
a few individuals who desire to gain exclusive political influence
for the class to which they belong, but there is very little chance
of their succeeding. If their desires were ever by chance
realised, we should probably have a repetition of the scene which
occurred in 1730. When in that year some of the great families
raised the Duchess of Courland to the throne on condition of her
ceding part of her power to a supreme council, the lower ranks of
the Noblesse compelled her to tear up the constitution which she
had signed! Those who dislike the autocratic power dislike the
idea of an aristocratic oligarchy infinitely more. Nobles and
people alike seem to hold instinctively the creed of the French
philosopher, who thought it better to be governed by a lion of good
family than by a hundred rats of his own species.
Of the present condition of the Noblesse I shall again have
occasion to speak when I come to consider the consequences of the
Emancipation.
CHAPTER XXI
LANDED PROPRIETORS OF THE OLD SCHOOL
Russian Hospitality--A Country-House--Its Owner Described--His
Life, Past and Present--Winter Evenings--Books---Connection with
the Outer World--The Crimean War and the Emancipation--A Drunken,
Dissolute Proprietor--An Old General and his Wife--"Name Days"--A
Legendary Monster--A Retired Judge--A Clever Scribe--Social
Leniency--Cause of Demoralisation.
Of all the foreign countries in which I have travelled, Russia
certainly bears off the palm in the matter of hospitality. Every
spring I found myself in possession of a large number of
invitations from landed proprietors in different parts of the
country--far more than I could possibly accept--and a great part of
the summer was generally spent in wandering about from one country-
house to another. I have no intention of asking the reader to
accompany me in all these expeditions--for though pleasant in
reality, they might be tedious in description--but I wish to
introduce him to some typical examples of the landed proprietors.
Among them are to be found nearly all ranks and conditions of men,
from the rich magnate, surrounded with the refined luxury of West-
European civilisation, to the poor, ill-clad, ignorant owner of a
few acres which barely supply him with the necessaries of life.
Let us take, first of all, a few specimens from the middle ranks.
In one of the central provinces, near the bank of a sluggish,
meandering stream, stands an irregular group of wooden
constructions--old, unpainted, blackened by time, and surmounted by
high, sloping roofs of moss-covered planks. The principal building
is a long, one-storied dwelling-house, constructed at right angles
to the road. At the front of the house is a spacious, ill-kept
yard, and at the back an equally spacious shady, garden, in which
art carries on a feeble conflict with encroaching nature. At the
other side of the yard, and facing the front door--or rather the
front doors, for there are two--stand the stables, hay-shed, and
granary, and near to that end of the house which is farthest from
the road are two smaller houses, one of which is the kitchen, and
the other the Lyudskaya, or servants' apartments. Beyond these we
can perceive, through a single row of lime-trees, another group of
time-blackened wooden constructions in a still more dilapidated
condition. That is the farmyard.
There is certainly not much symmetry in the disposition of these
buildings, but there is nevertheless a certain order and meaning in
the apparent chaos. All the buildings which do not require stoves
are built at a considerable distance from the dwelling-house and
kitchen, which are more liable to take fire; and the kitchen stands
by itself, because the odour of cookery where oil is used is by no
means agreeable, even for those whose olfactory nerves are not very
sensitive. The plan of the house is likewise not without a certain
meaning. The rigorous separation of the sexes, which formed a
characteristic trait of old Russian society, has long since
disappeared, but its influence may still be traced in houses built
on the old model. The house in question is one of these, and
consequently it is composed of three sections--at the one end the
male apartments, at the other the female apartments, and in the
middle the neutral territory, comprising the dining-room and the
salon. This arrangement has its conveniences, and explains the
fact that the house has two front doors. At the back is a third
door, which opens from the neutral territory into a spacious
verandah overlooking the garden.
Here lives, and has lived for many years, Ivan Ivanovitch K----, a
gentleman of the old school, and a very worthy man of his kind. If
we look at him as he sits in his comfortable armchair, with his
capacious dressing-gown hanging loosely about him, we shall be able
to read at a glance something of his character. Nature endowed him
with large bones and broad shoulders, and evidently intended him to
be a man of great muscular power, but he has contrived to frustrate
this benevolent intention, and has now more fat than muscle. His
close-cropped head is round as a bullet, and his features are
massive and heavy, but the heaviness is relieved by an expression
of calm contentment and imperturbable good-nature, which
occasionally blossoms into a broad grin. His face is one of those
on which no amount of histrionic talent could produce a look of
care and anxiety, and for this it is not to blame, for such an
expression has never been demanded of it. Like other mortals, he
sometimes experiences little annoyances, and on such occasions his
small grey eyes sparkle and his face becomes suffused with a
crimson glow that suggests apoplexy; but ill-fortune has never been
able to get sufficiently firm hold of him to make him understand
what such words as care and anxiety mean. Of struggle,
disappointment, hope, and all the other feelings which give to
human life a dramatic interest, he knows little by hearsay and
nothing by experience. He has, in fact, always lived outside of
that struggle for existence which modern philosophers declare to be
the law of nature.
Somewhere about seventy years ago Ivan Ivan'itch was born in the
house where he still lives. His first lessons he received from the
parish priest, and afterwards he was taught by a deacon's son, who
had studied in the ecclesiastical seminary to so little purpose
that he was unable to pass the final examination. By both of these
teachers he was treated with extreme leniency, and was allowed to
learn as little as he chose. His father wished him to study hard,
but his mother was afraid that study might injure his health, and
accordingly gave him several holidays every week. Under these
circumstances his progress was naturally not very rapid, and he was
still very slightly acquainted with the elementary rules of
arithmetic, when his father one day declared that he was already
eighteen years of age, and must at once enter the service.
But what kind of service? Ivan had no natural inclination for any
kind of activity. The project of entering him as a Junker in a
cavalry regiment, the colonel of which was an old friend of the
family, did not at all please him. He had no love for military
service, and positively disliked the prospect of an examination.
Whilst seeming, therefore, to bow implicitly to the paternal
authority, he induced his mother to oppose the scheme.
The dilemma in which Ivan found himself was this: in deference to
his father he wished to be in the service and gain that official
rank which every Russian noble desires to possess, and at the same
time, in deference to his mother and his own tastes, he wished to
remain at home and continue his indolent mode of life. The Marshal
of the Noblesse, who happened to call one day, helped him out of
the difficulty by offering to inscribe him as secretary in the
Dvoryanskaya Opeka, a bureau which acts as curator for the estates
of minors. All the duties of this office could be fulfilled by a
paid secretary, and the nominal occupant would be periodically
promoted as if he were an active official. This was precisely what
Ivan required. He accepted eagerly the proposal, and obtained, in
the course of seven years, without any effort on his part, the rank
of "collegiate secretary," corresponding to the "capitaine-en-
second" of the military hierarchy. To mount higher he would have
had to seek some place where he could not have fulfilled his duty
by proxy, so he determined to rest on his laurels, and sent in his
resignation.
Immediately after the termination of his official life his married
life began. Before his resignation had been accepted he suddenly
found himself one morning on the high road to matrimony. Here
again there was no effort on his part. The course of true love,
which is said never to run smooth for ordinary mortals, ran smooth
for him. He never had even the trouble of proposing. The whole
affair was arranged by his parents, who chose as bride for their
son the only daughter of their nearest neighbour. The young lady
was only about sixteen years of age, and was not remarkable for
beauty, talent, or any other peculiarity, but she had one very
important qualification--she was the daughter of a man who had an
estate contiguous to their own, and who might give as a dowry a
certain bit of land which they had long desired to add to their own
property. The negotiations, being of a delicate nature, were
entrusted to an old lady who had a great reputation for diplomatic
skill in such matters, and she accomplished her mission with such
success that in the course of a few weeks the preliminaries were
arranged and the day fixed for the wedding. Thus Ivan Ivan'itch
won his bride as easily as he had won his tchin of "collegiate
secretary."
Though the bridegroom had received rather than taken to himself a
wife, and did not imagine for a moment that he was in love, he had
no reason to regret the choice that was made for him. Maria
Petrovna was exactly suited by character and education to be the
wife of a man like Ivan Ivan'itch. She had grown up at home in the
society of nurses and servant-maids, and had never learned anything
more than could be obtained from the parish priest and from
"Ma'mselle," a personage occupying a position midway between a
servant-maid and a governess. The first events of her life were
the announcement that she was to be married and the preparations
for the wedding. She still remembers the delight which the
purchase of her trousseau afforded her, and keeps in her memory a
full catalogue of the articles bought. The first years of her
married life were not very happy, for she was treated by her
mother-in-law as a naughty child who required to be frequently
snubbed and lectured; but she bore the discipline with exemplary
patience, and in due time became her own mistress and autocratic
ruler in all domestic affairs. From that time she has lived an
active, uneventful life. Between her and her husband there is as
much mutual attachment as can reasonably be expected in phlegmatic
natures after half a century of matrimony. She has always devoted
her energies to satisfying his simple material wants--of
intellectual wants he has none--and securing his comfort in every
possible way. Under this fostering care he "effeminated himself"
(obabilsya), as he is wont to say. His love of shooting died out,
he cared less and less to visit his neighbours, and each successive
year he spent more and more time in his comfortable arm-chair.
The daily life of this worthy couple is singularly regular and
monotonous, varying only with the changing seasons. In summer Ivan
Ivan'itch gets up about seven o'clock, and puts on, with the
assistance of his valet de chambre, a simple costume, consisting
chiefly of a faded, plentifully stained dressing-gown. Having
nothing particular to do, he sits down at the open window and looks
into the yard. As the servants pass he stops and questions them,
and then gives them orders, or scolds them, as circumstances
demand. Towards nine o'clock tea is announced, and he goes into
the dining-room--a long, narrow apartment with bare wooden floor
and no furniture but a table and chairs, all in a more or less
rickety condition. Here he finds his wife with the tea-urn before
her. In a few minutes the grandchildren come in, kiss their
grandpapa's hand, and take their places round the table. As this
morning meal consists merely of bread and tea, it does not last
long; and all disperse to their several occupations. The head of
the house begins the labours of the day by resuming his seat at the
open window. When he has smoked some cigarettes and indulged in a
proportionate amount of silent contemplation, he goes out with the
intention of visiting the stables and farmyard, but generally
before he has crossed the court he finds the heat unbearable, and
returns to his former position by the open window. Here he sits
tranquilly till the sun has so far moved round that the verandah at
the back of the house is completely in the shade, when he has his
arm-chair removed thither, and sits there till dinner-time.
Maria Petrovna spends her morning in a more active way. As soon as
the breakfast table has been cleared she goes to the larder, takes
stock of the provisions, arranges the menu du jour, and gives to
the cook the necessary materials, with detailed instructions as to
how they are to be prepared. The rest of the morning she devotes
to her other household duties.
Towards one o'clock dinner is announced, and Ivan Ivan'itch
prepares his appetite by swallowing at a gulp a wineglassful of
home-made bitters. Dinner is the great event of the day. The food
is abundant and of good quality, but mushrooms, onions, and fat
play a rather too important part in the repast, and the whole is
prepared with very little attention to the recognised principles of
culinary hygiene. Many of the dishes, indeed, would make a British
valetudinarian stand aghast, but they seem to produce no bad effect
on those Russian organisms which have never been weakened by town
life, nervous excitement, or intellectual exertion.
No sooner has the last dish been removed than a deathlike stillness
falls upon the house: it is the time of the after-dinner siesta.
The young folks go into the garden, and all the other members of
the household give way to the drowsiness naturally engendered by a
heavy meal on a hot summer day. Ivan Ivan'itch retires to his own
room, from which the flies have been carefully expelled. Maria
Petrovna dozes in an arm-chair in the sitting-room, with a pocket-
handkerchief spread over her face. The servants snore in the
corridors, the garret, or the hay-shed; and even the old watch-dog
in the corner of the yard stretches himself out at full length on
the shady side of his kennel.
In about two hours the house gradually re-awakens. Doors begin to
creak; the names of various servants are bawled out in all tones,
from bass to falsetto; and footsteps are heard in the yard. Soon a
man-servant issues from the kitchen bearing an enormous tea-urn,
which puffs like a little steam-engine. The family assembles for
tea. In Russia, as elsewhere, sleep after a heavy meal produces
thirst, so that the tea and other beverages are very acceptable.
Then some little delicacies are served--such as fruit and wild
berries, or cucumbers with honey, or something else of the kind,
and the family again disperses. Ivan Ivan'itch takes a turn in the
fields on his begovuiya droshki--an extremely light vehicle
composed of two pairs of wheels joined together by a single board,
on which the driver sits stride-legged; and Maria Petrovna probably
receives a visit from the Popadya (the priest's wife), who is the
chief gossipmonger of the neighbourhood. There is not much scandal
in the district, but what little there is the Popadya carefully
collects, and distributes among her acquaintances with
undiscriminating generosity.
In the evening it often happens that a little group of peasants
come into the court, and ask to see the "master." The master goes
to the door, and generally finds that they have some favour to
request. In reply to his question, "Well, children, what do you
want?" they tell their story in a confused, rambling way, several
of them speaking at a time, and he has to question and cross-
question them before he comes to understand clearly what they
desire. If he tells them he cannot grant it, they probably do not
accept a first refusal, but endeavour by means of supplication to
make him reconsider his decision. Stepping forward a little, and
bowing low, one of the group begins in a half-respectful, half-
familiar, caressing tone: "Little Father, Ivan Ivan'itch, be
gracious; you are our father, and we are your children"--and so on.
Ivan Ivan'itch good-naturedly listens, and again explains that he
cannot grant what they ask; but they have still hopes of gaining
their point by entreaty, and continue their supplications till at
last his patience is exhausted and he says to them in a paternal
tone, "Now, enough! enough! you are blockheads--blockheads all
round! There's no use talking; it can't be done." And with these
words he enters the house, so as to prevent all further discussion.
A regular part of the evening's occupation is the interview with
the steward. The work that has just been done, and the programme
for the morrow, are always discussed at great length; and much time
is spent in speculating as to the weather during the next few days.
On this latter point the calendar is always carefully consulted,
and great confidence is placed in its predictions, though past
experience has often shown that they are not to be implicitly
trusted. The conversation drags on till supper is announced, and
immediately after that meal, which is an abridged repetition of
dinner, all retire for the night.
Thus pass the days and weeks and months in the house of Ivan
Ivan'itch, and rarely is there any deviation from the ordinary
programme. The climate necessitates, of course, some slight
modifications. When it is cold, the doors and windows have to be
kept shut, and after heavy rains those who do not like to wade in
mud have to remain in the house or garden. In the long winter
evenings the family assembles in the sitting-room, and all kill
time as best they can. Ivan Ivan'itch smokes and meditates or
listens to the barrel-organ played by one of the children. Maria
Petrovna knits a stocking. The old aunt, who commonly spends the
winter with them, plays Patience, and sometimes draws from the game
conclusions as to the future. Her favourite predictions are that a
stranger will arrive, or that a marriage will take place, and she
can determine the sex of the stranger and the colour of the
bridegroom's hair; but beyond this her art does not go, and she
cannot satisfy the young ladies' curiosity as to further details.
Books and newspapers are rarely seen in the sitting-room, but for
those who wish to read there is a book-case full of miscellaneous
literature, which gives some idea of the literary tastes of the
family during several generations. The oldest volumes were bought
by Ivan Ivan'itch's grandfather--a man who, according to the family
traditions, enjoyed the confidence of the great Catherine. Though
wholly overlooked by recent historians, he was evidently a man who
had some pretensions to culture. He had his portrait painted by a
foreign artist of considerable talent--it still hangs in the
sitting-room--and he bought several pieces of Sevres ware, the last
of which stands on a commode in the corner and contrasts strangely
with the rude home-made furniture and squalid appearance of the
apartment. Among the books which bear his name are the tragedies
of Sumarokof, who imagined himself to be "the Russian Voltaire";
the amusing comedies of Von-Wisin, some of which still keep the
stage; the loud-sounding odes of the courtly Derzhavin; two or
three books containing the mystic wisdom of Freemasonry as
interpreted by Schwarz and Novikoff; Russian translations of
Richardson's "Pamela," "Sir Charles Grandison," and "Clarissa
Harlowe"; Rousseau's "Nouvelle Heloise," in Russian garb; and three
or four volumes of Voltaire in the original. Among the works
collected at a somewhat later period are translations of Ann
Radcliffe, of Scott's early novels, and of Ducray Dumenil, whose
stories, "Lolotte et Fanfan" and "Victor," once enjoyed a great
reputation. At this point the literary tastes of the family appear
to have died out, for the succeeding literature is represented
exclusively by Kryloff's Fables, a farmer's manual, a handbook of
family medicine, and a series of calendars. There are, however,
some signs of a revival, for on the lowest shelf stand recent
editions of Pushkin, Lermontof, and Gogol, and a few works by
living authors.
Sometimes the monotony of the winter is broken by visiting
neighbours and receiving visitors in return, or in a more decided
way by a visit of a few days to the capital of the province. In
the latter case Maria Petrovna spends nearly all her time in
shopping, and brings home a large collection of miscellaneous
articles. The inspection of these by the assembled family forms an
important domestic event, which completely throws into the shade
the occasional visits of peddlers and colporteurs. Then there are
the festivities at Christmas and Easter, and occasionally little
incidents of less agreeable kind. It may be that there is a heavy
fall of snow, so that it is necessary to cut roads to the kitchen
and stables; or wolves enter the courtyard at night and have a
fight with the watch-dogs; or the news is brought that a peasant
who had been drinking in a neighbouring village has been found
frozen to death on the road.
Altogether the family live a very isolated life, but they have one
bond of connection with the great outer world. Two of the sons are
officers in the army and both of them write home occasionally to
their mother and sisters. To these two youths is devoted all the
little stock of sentimentality which Maria Petrovna possesses. She
can talk of them by the hour to any one who will listen to her, and
has related to the Popadya a hundred times every trivial incident
of their lives. Though they have never given her much cause for
anxiety, and they are now men of middle age, she lives in constant
fear that some evil may befall them. What she most fears is that
they may be sent on a campaign or may fall in love with actresses.
War and actresses are, in fact, the two bug-bears of her existence,
and whenever she has a disquieting dream she asks the priest to
offer up a moleben for the safety of her absent ones. Sometimes
she ventures to express her anxiety to her husband, and recommends
him to write to them; but he considers writing a letter a very
serious bit of work, and always replies evasively, "Well, well, we
must think about it."
During the Crimean War Ivan Ivan'itch half awoke from his habitual
lethargy, and read occasionally the meagre official reports
published by the Government. He was a little surprised that no
great victories were reported, and that the army did not at once
advance on Constantinople. As to causes he never speculated. Some
of his neighbours told him that the army was disorganised, and the
whole system of Nicholas had been proved to be utterly worthless.
That might all be very true, but he did not understand military and
political matters. No doubt it would all come right in the end.
All did come right, after a fashion, and he again gave up reading
newspapers; but ere long he was startled by reports much more
alarming than any rumours of war. People began to talk about the
peasant question, and to say openly that the serfs must soon be
emancipated. For once in his life Ivan Ivan'itch asked
explanations. Finding one of his neighbours, who had always been a
respectable, sensible man, and a severe disciplinarian, talking in
this way, he took him aside and asked what it all meant. The
neighbour explained that the old order of things had shown itself
bankrupt and was doomed, that a new epoch was opening, that
everything was to be reformed, and that the Emperor, in accordance
with a secret clause of the Treaty with the Allies, was about to
grant a Constitution! Ivan Ivan'itch listened for a little in
silence, and then, with a gesture of impatience, interrupted the
speaker: "Polno duratchitsya! enough of fun and tomfoolery.
Vassili Petrovitch, tell me seriously what you mean."
When Vassili Petrovitch vowed that he spoke in all seriousness, his
friend gazed at him with a look of intense compassion, and
remarked, as he turned away, "So you, too, have gone out of your
mind!"
The utterances of Vassili Petrovitch, which his lethargic, sober-
minded friend regarded as indicating temporary insanity in the
speaker, represented fairly the mental condition of very many
Russian nobles at that time, and were not without a certain
foundation. The idea about a secret clause in the Treaty of Paris
was purely imaginary, but it was quite true that the country was
entering on an epoch of great reforms, among which the Emancipation
question occupied the chief place. Of this even the sceptical Ivan
Ivan'itch was soon convinced. The Emperor formally declared to the
Noblesse of the province of Moscow that the actual state of things
could not continue forever, and called on the landed proprietors to
consider by what means the condition of their serfs might be
ameliorated. Provincial committees were formed for the purpose of
preparing definite projects, and gradually it became apparent that
the emancipation of the serfs was really at hand.
Ivan Ivan'itch was alarmed at the prospect of losing his authority
over his serfs. Though he had never been a cruel taskmaster, he
had not spared the rod when he considered it necessary, and he
believed birch twigs to be a necessary instrument in the Russian
system of agriculture. For some time he drew consolation from the
thought that peasants were not birds of the air, that they must
under all circumstances require food and clothing, and that they
would be ready to serve him as agricultural labourers; but when he
learned that they were to receive a large part of the estate for
their own use, his hopes fell, and he greatly feared that he would
be inevitably ruined.
These dark forebodings have not been by any means realised. His
serfs were emancipated and received about a half of the estate, but
in return for the land ceded they paid him annually a considerable
sum, and they were always ready to cultivate his fields for a fair
remuneration. The yearly outlay was considerably greater, but the
price of grain rose, and this counterbalanced the additional yearly
expenditure. The administration of the estate has become much less
patriarchal; much that was formerly left to custom and tacit
understanding is now regulated by express agreement on purely
commercial principles; a great deal more money is paid out and a
great deal more received; there is much less authority in the hands
of the master, and his responsibilities are proportionately
diminished; but in spite of all these changes, Ivan Ivan'itch would
have great difficulty in deciding whether he is a richer or a
poorer man. He has fewer horses and fewer servants, but he has
still more than he requires, and his mode of life has undergone no
perceptible alteration. Maria Petrovna complains that she is no
longer supplied with eggs, chickens, and homespun linen by the
peasants, and that everything is three times as dear as it used to
be; but somehow the larder is still full, and abundance reigns in
the house as of old.
Ivan Ivan'itch certainly does not possess transcendent qualities of
any kind. It would be impossible to make a hero out of him, even
though his own son should be his biographer. Muscular Christians
may reasonably despise him, an active, energetic man may fairly
condemn him for his indolence and apathy. But, on the other hand,
he has no very bad qualities. His vices are of the passive,
negative kind. He is a respectable if not a distinguished member
of society, and appears a very worthy man when compared with many
of his neighbours who have been brought up in similar conditions.
Take, for instance, his younger brother Dimitri, who lives a short
way off.
Dimitri Ivanovitch, like his brother Ivan, had been endowed by
nature with a very decided repugnance to prolonged intellectual
exertion, but as he was a man of good parts he did not fear a
Junker's examination--especially when he could count on the
colonel's protection--and accordingly entered the army. In his
regiment were a number of jovial young officers like himself,
always ready to relieve the monotony of garrison life by boisterous
dissipation, and among these he easily acquired the reputation of
being a thoroughly good fellow. In drinking bouts he could hold
his own with the best of them, and in all mad pranks invariably
played the chief part. By this means he endeared himself to his
comrades, and for a time all went well. The colonel had himself
sown wild oats plentifully in his youth, and was quite disposed to
overlook, as far as possible, the bacchanalian peccadilloes of his
subordinates. But before many years had passed, the regiment
suddenly changed its character. Certain rumours had reached
headquarters, and the Emperor Nicholas appointed as colonel a stern
disciplinarian of German origin, who aimed at making the regiment a
kind of machine that should work with the accuracy of a
chronometer.
This change did not at all suit the tastes of Dimitri Ivan'itch.
He chafed under the new restraints, and as soon as he had gained
the rank of lieutenant retired from the service to enjoy the
freedom of country life. Shortly afterwards his father died, and
he thereby became owner of an estate, with two hundred serfs. He
did not, like his elder brother, marry, and "effeminate himself,"
but he did worse. In his little independent kingdom--for such was
practically a Russian estate in the good old times--he was lord of
all he surveyed, and gave full scope to his boisterous humour, his
passion for sport, and his love of drinking and dissipation. Many
of the mad pranks in which he indulged will long be preserved by
popular tradition, but they cannot well be related here.
Dimitri Ivan'itch is now a man long past middle age, and still
continues his wild, dissipated life. His house resembles an ill-
kept, disreputable tavern. The floor is filthy, the furniture
chipped and broken, the servants indolent, slovenly, and in rags.
Dogs of all breeds and sizes roam about the rooms and corridors.
The master, when not asleep, is always in a more or less complete
state of intoxication. Generally he has one or two guests staying
with him--men of the same type as himself--and days and nights are
spent in drinking and card-playing. When he cannot have his usual
boon-companions he sends for one or two small proprietors who live
near--men who are legally nobles, but who are so poor that they
differ little from peasants. Formerly, when ordinary resources
failed, he occasionally had recourse to the violent expedient of
ordering his servants to stop the first passing travellers, whoever
they might be, and bring them in by persuasion or force, as
circumstances might demand. If the travellers refused to accept
such rough, undesired hospitality, a wheel would be taken off their
tarantass, or some indispensable part of the harness would be
secreted, and they might consider themselves fortunate if they
succeeded in getting away next morning.*
* This custom has fortunately gone out of fashion even in outlying
districts, but an incident of the kind happened to a friend of mine
as late as 1871. He was detained against his will for two whole
days by a man whom he had never seen before, and at last effected
his escape by bribing the servants of his tyrannical host.
In the time of serfage the domestic serfs had much to bear from
their capricious, violent master. They lived in an atmosphere of
abusive language, and were subjected not unfrequently to corporal
punishment. Worse than this, their master was constantly
threatening to "shave their forehead"--that is to say, to give them
as recruits--and occasionally he put his threat into execution, in
spite of the wailings and entreaties of the culprit and his
relations. And yet, strange to say, nearly all of them remained
with him as free servants after the Emancipation.
In justice to the Russian landed proprietors, I must say that the
class represented by Dimitri Ivan'itch has now almost disappeared.
It was the natural result of serfage and social stagnation--of a
state of society in which there were few legal and moral
restraints, and few inducements to honourable activity.
Among the other landed proprietors of the district, one of the best
known is Nicolai Petrovitch B----, an old military man with the
rank of general. Like Ivan Ivan'itch, he belongs to the old
school; but the two men must be contrasted rather than compared.
The difference in their lives and characters is reflected in their
outward appearance. Ivan Ivan'itch, as we know, is portly in form
and heavy in all his movements, and loves to loll in his arm-chair
or to loaf about the house in a capacious dressing-gown. The
General, on the contrary, is thin, wiry, and muscular, wears
habitually a close-buttoned military tunic, and always has a stern
expression, the force of which is considerably augmented by a
bristly moustache resembling a shoe-brush. As he paces up and down
the room, knitting his brows and gazing at the floor, he looks as
if he were forming combinations of the first magnitude; but those
who know him well are aware that this is an optical delusion, of
which he is himself to some extent a victim. He is quite innocent
of deep thought and concentrated intellectual effort. Though he
frowns so fiercely he is by no means of a naturally ferocious
temperament. Had he passed all his life in the country he would
probably have been as good-natured and phlegmatic as Ivan Ivan'itch
himself, but, unlike that worshipper of tranquillity, he had
aspired to rise in the service, and had adopted the stern, formal
bearing which the Emperor Nicholas considered indispensable in an
officer. The manner which he had at first put on as part of his
uniform became by the force of habit almost a part of his nature,
and at the age of thirty he was a stern disciplinarian and
uncompromising formalist, who confined his attention exclusively to
drill and other military duties. Thus he rose steadily by his own
merit, and reached the goal of his early ambition--the rank of
general.
As soon as this point was reached he determined to leave the
service and retire to his property. Many considerations urged him
to take this step. He enjoyed the title of Excellency which he had
long coveted, and when he put on his full uniform his breast was
bespangled with medals and decorations. Since the death of his
father the revenues of his estate had been steadily decreasing, and
report said that the best wood in his forest was rapidly
disappearing. His wife had no love for the country, and would have
preferred to settle in Moscow or St. Petersburg, but they found
that with their small income they could not live in a large town in
a style suitable to their rank.
The General determined to introduce order into his estate, and
become a practical farmer; but a little experience convinced him
that his new functions were much more difficult than the commanding
of a regiment. He has long since given over the practical
management of the property to a steward, and he contents himself
with exercising what he imagines to be an efficient control.
Though he wishes to do much, he finds small scope for his activity,
and spends his days in pretty much the same way as Ivan Ivan'itch,
with this difference, that he plays cards whenever he gets an
opportunity, and reads regularly the Moscow Gazette and Russki
Invalid, the official military paper. What specially interests him
is the list of promotions, retirements, and Imperial rewards for
merit and seniority. When he sees the announcement that some old
comrade has been made an officer of his Majesty's suite or has
received a grand cordon, he frowns a little more than usual, and is
tempted to regret that he retired from the service. Had he waited
patiently, perhaps a bit of good fortune might have fallen likewise
to his lot. This idea takes possession of him, and during the
remainder of the day he is taciturn and morose. His wife notices
the change, and knows the reason of it, but has too much good sense
and tact to make any allusion to the subject.
Anna Alexandrovna--as the good lady is called--is an elderly dame
who does not at all resemble the wife of Ivan Ivan'itch. She was
long accustomed to a numerous military society, with dinner-
parties, dancing, promenades, card-playing, and all the other
amusements of garrison life, and she never contracted a taste for
domestic concerns. Her knowledge of culinary affairs is extremely
vague, and she has no idea of how to make preserves, nalivka, and
other home-made delicacies, though Maria Petrovna, who is
universally acknowledged to be a great adept in such matters, has
proposed a hundred times to give her some choice recipes. In
short, domestic affairs are a burden to her, and she entrusts them
as far as possible to the housekeeper. Altogether she finds
country life very tiresome, but, possessing that placid,
philosophical temperament which seems to have some casual
connection with corpulence, she submits without murmuring, and
tries to lighten a little the unavoidable monotony by paying visits
and receiving visitors. The neighbours within a radius of twenty
miles are, with few exceptions, more or less of the Ivan Ivan'itch
and Maria Petrovna type--decidedly rustic in their manners and
conceptions; but their company is better than absolute solitude,
and they have at least the good quality of being always able and
willing to play cards for any number of hours. Besides this, Anna
Alexandrovna has the satisfaction of feeling that amongst them she
is almost a great personage, and unquestionably an authority in all
matters of taste and fashion; and she feels specially well disposed
towards those of them who frequently address her as "Your
Excellency."
The chief festivities take place on the "name-days" of the General
and his spouse--that is to say, the days sacred to St. Nicholas and
St. Anna. On these occasions all the neighbours come to offer
their congratulations, and remain to dinner as a matter of course.
After dinner the older visitors sit down to cards, and the young
people extemporise a dance. The fete is specially successful when
the eldest son comes home to take part in it, and brings a brother
officer with him. He is now a general like his father.* In days
gone by one of his comrades was expected to offer his hand to Olga
Nekola'vna, the second daughter, a delicate young lady who had been
educated in one of the great Instituts--gigantic boarding-schools,
founded and kept up by the Government, for the daughters of those
who are supposed to have deserved well of their country.
Unfortunately the expected offer was never made, and she and her
sister live at home as old maids, bewailing the absence of
"civilised" society, and killing time in a harmless, elegant way by
means of music, needlework, and light literature.
* Generals are much more common in Russia than in other countries.
A few years ago there was an old lady in Moscow who had a family of
ten sons, all of whom were generals! The rank may be obtained in
the civil as well as the military service.
At these "name-day" gatherings one used to meet still more
interesting specimens of the old school. One of them I remember
particularly. He was a tall, corpulent old man, in a threadbare
frock-coat, which wrinkled up about his waist. His shaggy eyebrows
almost covered his small, dull eyes, his heavy moustache partially
concealed a large mouth strongly indicating sensuous tendencies.
His hair was cut so short that it was difficult to say what its
colour would be if it were allowed to grow. He always arrived in
his tarantass just in time for the zakuska--the appetising
collation that is served shortly before dinner--grunted out a few
congratulations to the host and hostess and monosyllabic greetings
to his acquaintances, ate a copious meal, and immediately
afterwards placed himself at a card-table, where he sat in silence
as long as he could get any one to play with him. People did not
like, however, to play with Andrei Vassil'itch, for his society was
not agreeable, and he always contrived to go home with a well-
filled purse.
Andrei Vassil'itch was a noted man in the neighbourhood. He was
the centre of a whole cycle of legends, and I have often heard that
his name was used with effect by nurses to frighten naughty
children. I never missed an opportunity of meeting him, for I was
curious to see and study a legendary monster in the flesh. How far
the numerous stories told about him were true I cannot pretend to
say, but they were certainly not without foundation. In his youth
he had served for some time in the army, and was celebrated, even
in an age when martinets had always a good chance of promotion, for
his brutality to his subordinates. His career was cut short,
however, when he had only the rank of captain. Having compromised
himself in some way, he found it advisable to send in his
resignation and retire to his estate. Here he organised his house
on Mahometan rather than Christian principles, and ruled his
servants and peasants as he had been accustomed to rule his
soldiers--using corporal punishment in merciless fashion. His wife
did not venture to protest against the Mahometan arrangements, and
any peasant who stood in the way of their realisation was at once
given as a recruit, or transported to Siberia, in accordance with
his master's demand.* At last his tyranny and extortion drove his
serfs to revolt. One night his house was surrounded and set on
fire, but he contrived to escape the fate that was prepared for
him, and caused all who had taken part in the revolt to be
mercilessly punished. This was a severe lesson, but it had no
effect upon him. Taking precautions against a similar surprise, he
continued to tyrannise and extort as before, until in 1861 the
serfs were emancipated, and his authority came to an end.
* When a proprietor considered any of his serfs unruly he could,
according to law, have them transported to Siberia without trial,
on condition of paying the expenses of transport. Arrived at their
destination, they received land, and lived as free colonists, with
the single restriction that they were not allowed to leave the
locality where they settled.
A very different sort of man was Pavel Trophim'itch, who likewise
came regularly to pay his respects and present his congratulations
to the General and "Gheneralsha."* It was pleasant to turn from
the hard, wrinkled, morose features of the legendary monster to the
soft, smooth, jovial face of this man, who had been accustomed to
look at the bright side of things, till his face had caught
something of their brightness. "A good, jovial, honest face!" a
stranger might exclaim as he looked at him. Knowing something of
his character and history, I could not endorse such an opinion.
Jovial he certainly was, for few men were more capable of making
and enjoying mirth. Good he might he also called, if the word were
taken in the sense of good-natured, for he never took offence, and
was always ready to do a kindly action if it did not cost him any
trouble. But as to his honesty, that required some qualification.
Wholly untarnished his reputation certainly could not be, for he
had been a judge in the District Court before the time of the
judicial reforms; and, not being a Cato, he had succumbed to the
usual temptations. He had never studied law, and made no
pretensions to the possession of great legal knowledge. To all who
would listen to him he declared openly that he knew much more about
pointers and setters than about legal formalities. But his estate
was very small, and he could not afford to give up his appointment.
* The female form of the word General.
Of these unreformed Courts, which are happily among the things of
the past, I shall have occasion to speak in the sequel. For the
present I wish merely to say that they were thoroughly corrupt, and
I hasten to add that Pavel Trophim'itch was by no means a judge of
the worst kind. He had been known to protect widows and orphans
against those who wished to despoil them, and no amount of money
would induce him to give an unjust decision against a friend who
had privately explained the case to him; but when he knew nothing
of the case or of the parties he readily signed the decision
prepared by the secretary, and quietly pocketed the proceeds,
without feeling any very disagreeable twinges of conscience. All
judges, he knew, did likewise, and he had no pretension to being
better than his fellows.
When Pavel Trophim'itch played cards at the General's house or
elsewhere, a small, awkward, clean-shaven man, with dark eyes and a
Tartar cast of countenance, might generally be seen sitting at the
same table. His name was Alexei Petrovitch T----. Whether he
really had any Tartar blood in him it is impossible to say, but
certainly his ancestors for one or two generations were all good
orthodox Christians. His father had been a poor military surgeon
in a marching regiment, and he himself had become at an early age a
scribe in one of the bureaux of the district town. He was then
very poor, and had great difficulty in supporting life on the
miserable pittance which he received as a salary; but he was a
sharp, clever youth, and soon discovered that even a scribe had a
great many opportunities of extorting money from the ignorant
public.
These opportunities Alexei Petrovitch used with great ability, and
became known as one of the most accomplished bribe-takers
(vzyatotchniki) in the district. His position, however, was so
very subordinate that he would never have become rich had he not
fallen upon a very ingenious expedient which completely succeeded.
Hearing that a small proprietor, who had an only daughter, had come
to live in the town for a few weeks, he took a room in the inn
where the newcomers lived, and when he had made their acquaintance
he fell dangerously ill. Feeling his last hours approaching, he
sent for a priest, confided to him that he had amassed a large
fortune, and requested that a will should be drawn up. In the will
he bequeathed large sums to all his relations, and a considerable
sum to the parish church. The whole affair was to be kept a secret
till after his death, but his neighbour--the old gentleman with the
daughter--was called in to act as a witness. When all this had
been done he did not die, but rapidly recovered, and now induced
the old gentleman to whom he had confided his secret to grant him
his daughter's hand. The daughter had no objections to marry a man
possessed of such wealth, and the marriage was duly celebrated.
Shortly after this the father died--without discovering, it is to
be hoped, the hoax that had been perpetrated--and Alexei Petrovitch
became virtual possessor of a very comfortable little estate. With
the change in his fortunes he completely changed his principles, or
at least his practice. In all his dealings he was strictly honest.
He lent money, it is true, at from ten to fifteen per cent., but
that was considered in these parts not a very exorbitant rate of
interest, nor was he unnecessarily hard upon his debtors.
It may seem strange that an honourable man like the General should
receive in his house such a motley company, comprising men of
decidedly tarnished reputation; but in this respect he was not at
all peculiar. One constantly meets in Russian society persons who
are known to have been guilty of flagrant dishonesty, and we find
that men who are themselves honourable enough associate with them
on friendly terms. This social leniency, moral laxity, or whatever
else it may be called, is the result of various causes. Several
concurrent influences have tended to lower the moral standard of
the Noblesse. Formerly, when the noble lived on his estate, he
could play with impunity the petty tyrant, and could freely indulge
his legitimate and illegitimate caprices without any legal or moral
restraint. I do not at all mean to assert that all proprietors
abused their authority, but I venture to say that no class of men
can long possess such enormous arbitrary power over those around
them without being thereby more or less demoralised. When the
noble entered the service he had not the same immunity from
restraint--on the contrary, his position resembled rather that of
the serf--but he breathed an atmosphere of peculation and jobbery,
little conducive to moral purity and uprightness. If an official
had refused to associate with those who were tainted with the
prevailing vices, he would have found himself completely isolated,
and would have been ridiculed as a modern Don Quixote. Add to this
that all classes of the Russian people have a certain kindly,
apathetic good-nature which makes them very charitable towards
their neighbours, and that they do not always distinguish between
forgiving private injury and excusing public delinquencies. If we
bear all this in mind, we may readily understand that in the time
of serfage and maladministration a man could be guilty of very
reprehensible practises without incurring social excommunication.
During the period of moral awakening, after the Crimean War and the
death of Nicholas I., society revelled in virtuous indignation
against the prevailing abuses, and placed on the pillory the most
prominent delinquents; but the intensity of the moral feeling has
declined, and something of the old apathy has returned. This might
have been predicted by any one well acquainted with the character
and past history of the Russian people. Russia advances on the
road of progress, not in that smooth, gradual, prosaic way to which
we are accustomed, but by a series of unconnected, frantic efforts,
each of which is naturally followed by a period of temporary
exhaustion.
CHAPTER XXII
PROPRIETORS OF THE MODERN SCHOOL
A Russian Petit Maitre--His House and Surroundings--Abortive
Attempts to Improve Agriculture and the Condition of the Serfs-- A
Comparison--A "Liberal" Tchinovnik--His Idea of Progress--A Justice
of the Peace--His Opinion of Russian Literature, Tchinovniks, and
Petits Maitres--His Supposed and Real Character--An Extreme
Radical--Disorders in the Universities--Administrative Procedure--
Russia's Capacity for Accomplishing Political and Social
Evolutions--A Court Dignitary in his Country House.
Hitherto I have presented to the reader old-fashioned types which
were common enough thirty years ago, when I first resided in
Russia, but which are rapidly disappearing. Let me now present a
few of the modern school.
In the same district as Ivan Ivan'itch and the General lives Victor
Alexandr'itch L----. As we approach his house we can at once
perceive that he differs from the majority of his neighbours. The
gate is painted and moves easily on its hinges, the fence is in
good repair, the short avenue leading up to the front door is well
kept, and in the garden we can perceive at a glance that more
attention is paid to flowers than to vegetables. The house is of
wood, and not large, but it has some architectural pretensions in
the form of a great, pseudo-Doric wooden portico that covers three-
fourths of the fa ade. In the interior we remark everywhere the?
influence of Western civilisation. Victor Alexandr'itch is by no
means richer than Ivan Ivan'itch, but his rooms are much more
luxuriously furnished. The furniture is of a lighter model, more
comfortable, and in a much better state of preservation. Instead
of the bare, scantily furnished sitting-room, with the old-
fashioned barrel-organ which played only six airs, we find an
elegant drawing-room, with a piano by one of the most approved
makers, and numerous articles of foreign manufacture, comprising a
small buhl table and two bits of genuine old Wedgwood. The
servants are clean, and dressed in European costume. The master,
too, is very different in appearance. He pays great attention to
his toilette, wearing a dressing-gown only in the early morning,
and a fashionable lounging coat during the rest of the day. The
Turkish pipes which his grandfather loved he holds in abhorrence,
and habitually smokes cigarettes. With his wife and daughters he
always speaks French, and calls them by French or English names.
But the part of the house which most strikingly illustrates the
difference between old and new is "le cabinet de monsieur." In the
cabinet of Ivan Ivan'itch the furniture consists of a broad sofa
which serves as a bed, a few deal chairs, and a clumsy deal table,
on which are generally to be found a bundle of greasy papers, an
old chipped ink-bottle, a pen, and a calendar. The cabinet of
Victor Alexandr'itch has an entirely different appearance. It is
small, but at once comfortable and elegant. The principal objects
which it contains are a library-table, with ink-stand, presse-
papier, paper-knives, and other articles in keeping, and in the
opposite corner a large bookcase. The collection of books is
remarkable, not from the number of volumes or the presence of rare
editions, but from the variety of the subjects. History, art,
fiction, the drama, political economy, and agriculture are
represented in about equal proportions. Some of the works are in
Russian, others in German, a large number in French, and a few in
Italian. The collection illustrates the former life and present
occupations of the owner.
The father of Victor Alexandr'itch was a landed proprietor who had
made a successful career in the civil service, and desired that his
son should follow the same profession. For this purpose Victor was
first carefully trained at home, and then sent to the University of
Moscow, where he spent four years as a student of law. From the
University he passed to the Ministry of the Interior in St.
Petersburg, but he found the monotonous routine of official life
not at all suited to his taste, and very soon sent in his
resignation. The death of his father had made him proprietor of an
estate, and thither he retired, hoping to find there plenty of
occupation more congenial than the writing of official papers.
At the University of Moscow he had attended lectures on history and
philosophy, and had got through a large amount of desultory
reading. The chief result of his studies was the acquisition of
many ill-digested general principles, and certain vague, generous,
humanitarian aspirations. With this intellectual capital he hoped
to lead a useful life in the country. When he had repaired and
furnished the house he set himself to improve the estate. In the
course of his promiscuous reading he had stumbled on some
descriptions of English and Tuscan agriculture, and had there
learned what wonders might be effected by a rational system of
farming. Why should not Russia follow the example of England and
Tuscany? By proper drainage, plentiful manure, good ploughs, and
the cultivation of artificial grasses, the production might be
multiplied tenfold; and by the introduction of agricultural
machines the manual labour might be greatly diminished. All this
seemed as simple as a sum in arithmetic, and Victor Alexandr'itch,
more scholarum rei familiaris ignarus, without a moment's
hesitation expended his ready money in procuring from England a
threshing-machine, ploughs, harrows, and other implements of the
newest model.
The arrival of these was an event that was long remembered. The
peasants examined them with attention, not unmixed with wonder, but
said nothing. When the master explained to them the advantages of
the new instruments, they still remained silent. Only one old man,
gazing at the threshing-machine, remarked, in an audible "aside,"
"A cunning people, these Germans!"* On being asked for their
opinion, they replied vaguely, "How should we know? It OUGHT to be
so." But when their master had retired, and was explaining to his
wife and the French governess that the chief obstacle to progress
in Russia was the apathetic indolence and conservative spirit of
the peasantry, they expressed their opinions more freely. "These
may be all very well for the Germans, but they won't do for us.
How are our little horses to drag these big ploughs? And as for
that [the threshing-machine], it's of no use." Further examination
and reflection confirmed this first impression, and it was
unanimously decided that no good would come of the new-fangled
inventions.
* The Russian peasant comprehends all the inhabitants of Western
Europe under the term Nyemtsi, which in the language of the
educated designates only Germans. The rest of humanity is composed
of Pravoslavniye (Greek Orthodox), Busurmanye (Mahometans), and
Poliacki (Poles).
These apprehensions proved to be only too well founded. The
ploughs were much too heavy for the peasants' small horses, and the
threshing-machine broke down at the first attempt to use it. For
the purchase of lighter implements or stronger horses there was no
ready money, and for the repairing of the threshing-machine there
was not an engineer within a radius of a hundred and fifty miles.
The experiment was, in short, a complete failure, and the new
purchases were put away out of sight.
For some weeks after this incident Victor Alexandr'itch felt very
despondent, and spoke more than usual about the apathy and
stupidity of the peasantry. His faith in infallible science was
somewhat shaken, and his benevolent aspirations were for a time
laid aside. But this eclipse of faith was not of long duration.
Gradually he recovered his normal condition, and began to form new
schemes. From the study of certain works on political economy he
learned that the system of communal property was ruinous to the
fertility of the soil, and that free labour was always more
productive than serfage. By the light of these principles he
discovered why the peasantry in Russia were so poor, and by what
means their condition could he ameliorated. The Communal land
should he divided into family lots, and the serfs, instead of being
forced to work for the proprietor, should pay a yearly sum as rent.
The advantages of this change he perceived clearly--as clearly as
he had formerly perceived the advantages of English agricultural
implements--and he determined to make the experiment on his own
estate.
His first step was to call together the more intelligent and
influential of his serfs, and to explain to them his project; but
his efforts at explanation were eminently unsuccessful. Even with
regard to ordinary current affairs he could not express himself in
that simple, homely language with which alone the peasants are
familiar, and when he spoke on abstract subjects he naturally
became quite unintelligible to his uneducated audience. The serfs
listened attentively, but understood nothing. He might as well
have spoken to them, as he often did in another kind of society,
about the comparative excellence of Italian and German music. At a
second attempt he had rather more success. The peasants came to
understand that what he wished was to break up the Mir, or rural
Commune, and to put them all on obrok--that is to say, make them
pay a yearly sum instead of giving him a certain amount of
agricultural labour. Much to his astonishment, his scheme did not
meet with any sympathy. As to being put on obrok, the serfs did
not much object, though they preferred to remain as they were; but
his proposal to break up the Mir astonished and bewildered them.
They regarded it as a sea-captain might regard the proposal of a
scientific wiseacre to knock a hole in the ship's bottom in order
to make her sail faster. Though they did not say much, he was
intelligent enough to see that they would offer a strenuous passive
resistance, and as he did not wish to act tyrannically, he let the
matter drop. Thus a second benevolent scheme was shipwrecked.
Many other schemes had a similar fate, and Victor Alexandr'itch
began to perceive that it was very difficult to do good in this
world, especially when the persons to be benefited were Russian
peasants.
In reality the fault lay less with the serfs than with their
master. Victor Alexandr'itch was by no means a stupid man. On the
contrary, he had more than average talents. Few men were more
capable of grasping a new idea and forming a scheme for its
realisation, and few men could play more dexterously with abstract
principles. What he wanted was the power of dealing with concrete
facts. The principles which he had acquired from University
lectures and desultory reading were far too vague and abstract for
practical use. He had studied abstract science without gaining any
technical knowledge of details, and consequently when he stood face
to face with real life he was like a student who, having studied
mechanics in text-books, is suddenly placed in a workshop and
ordered to construct a machine. Only there was one difference:
Victor Alexandr'itch was not ordered to do anything. Voluntarily,
without any apparent necessity, he set himself to work with tools
which he could not handle. It was this that chiefly puzzled the
peasants. Why should he trouble himself with these new schemes,
when he might live comfortably as he was? In some of his projects
they could detect a desire to increase the revenue, but in others
they could discover no such motive. In these latter they
attributed his conduct to pure caprice, and put it into the same
category as those mad pranks in which proprietors of jovial humour
sometimes indulged.
In the last years of serfage there were a good many landed
proprietors like Victor Alexandr'itch--men who wished to do
something beneficent, and did not know how to do it. When serfage
was being abolished the majority of these men took an active part
in the great work and rendered valuable service to their country.
Victor Alexandr'itch acted otherwise. At first he sympathised
warmly with the proposed emancipation and wrote several articles on
the advantages of free labour, but when the Government took the
matter into its own hands he declared that the officials had
deceived and slighted the Noblesse, and he went over to the
opposition. Before the Imperial Edict was signed he went abroad,
and travelled for three years in Germany, France, and Italy.
Shortly after his return he married a pretty, accomplished young
lady, the daughter of an eminent official in St. Petersburg, and
since that time he has lived in his country-house.
Though a man of education and culture, Victor Alexandr'itch spends
his time in almost as indolent a way as the men of the old school.
He rises somewhat later, and instead of sitting by the open window
and gazing into the courtyard, he turns over the pages of a book or
periodical. Instead of dining at midday and supping at nine
o'clock, he takes dejeuner at twelve and dines at five. He spends
less time in sitting in the verandah and pacing up and down with
his hands behind his back, for he can vary the operation of time-
killing by occasionally writing a letter, or by standing behind his
wife at the piano while she plays selections from Mozart and
Beethoven. But these peculiarities are merely variations in
detail. If there is any essential difference between the lives of
Victor Alexandr'itch and of Ivan Ivan'itch, it is in the fact that
the former never goes out into the fields to see how the work is
done, and never troubles himself with the state of the weather, the
condition of the crops, and cognate subjects. He leaves the
management of his estate entirely to his steward, and refers to
that personage all peasants who come to him with complaints or
petitions. Though he takes a deep interest in the peasant as an
impersonal, abstract entity, and loves to contemplate concrete
examples of the genus in the works of certain popular authors, he
does not like to have any direct relations with peasants in the
flesh. If he has to speak with them he always feels awkward, and
suffers from the odour of their sheepskins. Ivan Ivan'itch is ever
ready to talk with the peasants, and give them sound, practical
advice or severe admonitions; and in the old times he was apt, in
moments of irritation, to supplement his admonitions by a free use
of his fists. Victor Alexandr'itch, on the contrary, never could
give any advice except vague commonplace, and as to using his fist,
he would have shrunk from that, not only from respect to
humanitarian principles, but also from motives which belong to the
region of aesthetic sensitiveness.
This difference between the two men has an important influence on
their pecuniary affairs. The stewards of both steal from their
masters; but that of Ivan Ivan'itch steals with difficulty, and to
a very limited extent, whereas that of Victor Alexandr'itch steals
regularly and methodically, and counts his gains, not by kopecks,
but by roubles. Though the two estates are of about the same size
and value, they give a very different revenue. The rough,
practical man has a much larger income than his elegant, well-
educated neighbour, and at the same time spends very much less.
The consequences of this, if not at present visible, must some day
become painfully apparent. Ivan Ivan'itch will doubtless leave to
his children an unencumbered estate and a certain amount of
capital. The children of Victor Alexandr'itch have a different
prospect. He has already begun to mortgage his property and to cut
down the timber, and he always finds a deficit at the end of the
year. What will become of his wife and children when the estate
comes to be sold for payment of the mortgage, it is difficult to
predict. He thinks very little of that eventuality, and when his
thoughts happen to wander in that direction he consoles himself
with the thought that before the crash comes he will have inherited
a fortune from a rich uncle who has no children.
The proprietors of the old school lead the same uniform, monotonous
life year after year, with very little variation. Victor
Alexandr'itch, on the contrary, feels the need of a periodical
return to "civilised society," and accordingly spends a few weeks
every winter in St. Petersburg. During the summer months he has
the society of his brother--un homme tout a fait civilise--who
possesses an estate a few miles off.
This brother, Vladimir Alexandr'itch, was educated in the School of
Law in St. Petersburg, and has since risen rapidly in the service.
He holds now a prominent position in one of the Ministries, and has
the honourary court title of "Chambellan de sa Majeste." He is a
marked man in the higher circles of the Administration, and will,
it is thought, some day become Minister. Though an adherent of
enlightened views, and a professed "Liberal," he contrives to keep
on very good terms with those who imagine themselves to be
"Conservatives." In this he is assisted by his soft, oily manner.
If you express an opinion to him he will always begin by telling
you that you are quite right; and if he ends by showing you that
you are quite wrong, he will at least make you feel that your error
is not only excusable, but in some way highly creditable to your
intellectual acuteness or goodness of heart. In spite of his
Liberalism he is a staunch Monarchist, and considers that the time
has not yet come for the Emperor to grant a Constitution. He
recognises that the present order of things has its defects, but
thinks that, on the whole, it acts very well, and would act much
better if certain high officials were removed, and more energetic
men put in their places. Like all genuine St. Petersburg
tchinovniks (officials), he has great faith in the miraculous power
of Imperial ukazes and Ministerial circulars, and believes that
national progress consists in multiplying these documents, and
centralising the Administration, so as to give them more effect.
As a supplementary means of progress he highly approves of
aesthetic culture, and he can speak with some eloquence of the
humanising influence of the fine arts. For his own part he is well
acquainted with French and English classics, and particularly
admires Macaulay, whom he declares to have been not only a great
writer, but also a great statesman. Among writers of fiction he
gives the palm to George Eliot, and speaks of the novelists of his
own country, and, indeed, of Russian literature as a whole, in the
most disparaging terms.
A very different estimate of Russian literature is held by
Alexander Ivan'itch N----, formerly arbiter in peasant affairs, and
afterwards justice of the peace. Discussions on this subject often
take place between the two. The admirer of Macaulay declares that
Russia has, properly speaking, no literature whatever, and that the
works which bear the names of Russian authors are nothing but a
feeble echo of the literature of Western Europe. "Imitators," he
is wont to say, "skilful imitators, we have produced in abundance.
But where is there a man of original genius? What is our famous
poet Zhukofski? A translator. What is Pushkin? A clever pupil of
the romantic school. What is Lermontoff? A feeble imitator of
Byron. What is Gogol?"
At this point Alexander Ivan'itch invariable intervenes. He is
ready to sacrifice all the pseudo-classic and romantic poetry, and,
in fact, the whole of Russian literature anterior to about the year
1840, but he will not allow anything disrespectful to be said of
Gogol, who about that time founded the Russian realistic school.
"Gogol," he holds, "was a great and original genius. Gogol not
only created a new kind of literature; he at the same time
transformed the reading public, and inaugurated a new era in the
intellectual development of the nation. By his humorous, satirical
sketches he swept away the metaphysical dreaming and foolish
romantic affectation then in fashion, and taught men to see their
country as it was, in all its hideous ugliness. With his help the
young generation perceived the rottenness of the Administration,
and the meanness, stupidity, dishonesty, and worthlessness of the
landed proprietors, whom he made the special butt of his ridicule.
The recognition of defects produced a desire for reform. From
laughing at the proprietors there was but one step to despising
them, and when we learned to despise the proprietors we naturally
came to sympathise with the serfs. Thus the Emancipation was
prepared by the literature; and when the great question had to be
solved, it was the literature that discovered a satisfactory
solution."
This is a subject on which Alexander Ivan'itch feels very strongly,
and on which he always speaks with warmth. He knows a good deal
regarding the intellectual movement which began about 1840, and
culminated in the great reforms of the sixties. As a University
student he troubled himself very little with serious academic work,
but he read with intense interest all the leading periodicals, and
adopted the doctrine of Belinski that art should not be cultivated
for its own sake, but should be made subservient to social
progress. This belief was confirmed by a perusal of some of George
Sand's earlier works, which were for him a kind of revelation.
Social questions engrossed his thoughts, and all other subjects
seemed puny by comparison. When the Emancipation question was
raised he saw an opportunity of applying some of his theories, and
threw himself enthusiastically into the new movement as an ardent
abolitionist. When the law was passed he helped to put it into
execution by serving for three years as an Arbiter of the Peace.
Now he is an old man, but he has preserved some of his youthful
enthusiasm, attends regularly the annual assemblies of the Zemstvo,
and takes a lively interest in all public affairs.
As an ardent partisan of local self-government he habitually scoffs
at the centralised bureaucracy, which he proclaims to be the great
bane of his unhappy country. "These tchinovniks," he is wont to
say in moments of excitement, "who live in St. Petersburg and
govern the Empire, know about as much of Russia as they do of
China. They live in a world of official documents, and are
hopelessly ignorant of the real wants and interests of the people.
So long as all the required formalities are duly observed they are
perfectly satisfied. The people may be allowed to die of
starvation if only the fact do not appear in the official reports.
Powerless to do any good themselves, they are powerful enough to
prevent others from working for the public good, and are extremely
jealous of all private initiative. How have they acted, for
instance, towards the Zemstvo? The Zemstvo is really a good
institution, and might have done great things if it had been left
alone, but as soon as it began to show a little independent energy
the officials at once clipped its wings and then strangled it.
Towards the Press they have acted in the same way. They are afraid
of the Press, because they fear above all things a healthy public
opinion, which the Press alone can create. Everything that
disturbs the habitual routine alarms them. Russia cannot make any
real progress so long as she is ruled by these cursed tchinovniks."
Scarcely less pernicious than the tchinovnik, in the eyes of our
would-be reformer, is the baritch--that is to say, the pampered,
capricious, spoiled child of mature years, whose life is spent in
elegant indolence and fine talking. Our friend Victor
Alexandr'itch is commonly selected as a representative of this
type. "Look at him!" exclaims Alexander Ivan'itch. "What a
useless, contemptible member of society! In spite of his generous
aspirations he never succeeds in doing anything useful to himself
or to others. When the peasant question was raised and there was
work to be done, he went abroad and talked liberalism in Paris and
Baden-Baden. Though he reads, or at least professes to read, books
on agriculture, and is always ready to discourse on the best means
of preventing the exhaustion of the soil, he knows less of farming
than a peasant-boy of twelve, and when he goes into the fields he
can hardly distinguish rye from oats. Instead of babbling about
German and Italian music, he would do well to learn a little about
practical farming, and look after his estate."
Whilst Alexander Ivan'itch thus censures his neighbours, he is
himself not without detractors. Some staid old proprietors regard
him as a dangerous man, and quote expressions of his which seem to
indicate that his notions of property are somewhat loose. Many
consider that his liberalism is of a very violent kind, and that he
has strong republican sympathies. In his decisions as Justice he
often leaned, it is said, to the side of the peasants against the
proprietors. Then he was always trying to induce the peasants of
the neighbouring villages to found schools, and he had wonderful
ideas about the best method of teaching children. These and
similar facts make many people believe that he has very advanced
ideas, and one old gentleman habitually calls him--half in joke and
half in earnest--"our friend the communist."
In reality Alexander Ivan'itch has nothing of the communist about
him. Though he loudly denounces the tchinovnik spirit--or, as we
should say, red-tape in all its forms--and is an ardent partisan of
local self-government, he is one of the last men in the world to
take part in any revolutionary movement, he would like to see the
Central Government enlightened and controlled by public opinion and
by a national representation, but he believes that this can only be
effected by voluntary concessions on the part of the autocratic
power. He has, perhaps, a sentimental love of the peasantry, and
is always ready to advocate its interests; but he has come too much
in contact with individual peasants to accept those idealised
descriptions in which some popular writers indulge, and it may
safely be asserted that the accusation of his voluntarily favouring
peasants at the expense of the proprietors is wholly unfounded.
Alexander Ivan'itch is, in fact, a quiet, sensible man, who is
capable of generous enthusiasm, and is not at all satisfied with
the existing state of things; but he is not a dreamer and a
revolutionnaire, as some of his neighbours assert.
I am afraid I cannot say as much for his younger brother Nikolai,
who lives with him. Nikolai Ivan'itch is a tall, slender man,
about sixty years of age, with emaciated face, bilious complexion
and long black hair--evidently a person of excitable, nervous
temperament. When he speaks he articulates rapidly, and uses more
gesticulation than is common among his countrymen. His favourite
subject of conversation, or rather of discourse, for he more
frequently preaches than talks, is the lamentable state of the
country and the worthlessness of the Government. Against the
Government he has a great many causes for complaint, and one or two
of a personal kind. In 1861 he was a student in the University of
St. Petersburg. At that time there was a great deal of public
excitement all over Russia, and especially in the capital. The
serfs had just been emancipated, and other important reforms had
been undertaken. There was a general conviction among the young
generation--and it must be added among many older men--that the
autocratic, paternal system of government was at an end, and that
Russia was about to be reorganised according to the most advanced
principles of political and social science. The students, sharing
this conviction, wished to be freed from all academical authority,
and to organise a kind of academic self-government. They desired
especially the right of holding public meetings for the discussion
of their common affairs. The authorities would not allow this, and
issued a list of rules prohibiting meetings and raising the class-
fees, so as practically to exclude many of the poorer students.
This was felt to be a wanton insult to the spirit of the new era.
In spite of the prohibition, indignation meetings were held, and
fiery speeches made by male and female orators, first in the class-
rooms, and afterwards in the courtyard of the University. On one
occasion a long procession marched through the principal streets to
the house of the Curator. Never had such a spectacle been seen
before in St. Petersburg. Timid people feared that it was the
commencement of a revolution, and dreamed about barricades. At
last the authorities took energetic measures; about three hundred
students were arrested, and of these, thirty-two were expelled from
the University.
Among those who were expelled was Nicolai Ivan'itch. All his hopes
of becoming a professor, as he had intended, were thereby
shipwrecked, and he had to look out for some other profession. A
literary career now seemed the most promising, and certainly the
most congenial to his tastes. It would enable him to gratify his
ambition of being a public man, and give him opportunities of
attacking and annoying his persecutors. He had already written
occasionally for one of the leading periodicals, and now he became
a regular contributor. His stock of positive knowledge was not
very large, but he had the power of writing fluently and of making
his readers believe that he had an unlimited store of political
wisdom which the Press-censure prevented him from publishing.
Besides this, he had the talent of saying sharp, satirical things
about those in authority, in such a way that even a Press censor
could not easily raise objections. Articles written in this style
were sure at that time to be popular, and his had a very great
success. He became a known man in literary circles, and for a time
all went well. But gradually he became less cautious, whilst the
authorities became more vigilant. Some copies of a violent
seditious proclamation fell into the hands of the police, and it
was generally believed that the document proceeded from the coterie
to which he belonged. From that moment he was carefully watched,
till one night he was unexpectedly roused from his sleep by a
gendarme and conveyed to the fortress.
When a man is arrested in this way for a real or supposed political
offence, there are two modes of dealing with him. He may be tried
before a regular tribunal, or he may be dealt with "by
administrative procedure" (administrativnym poryadkom). In the
former case he will, if convicted, be condemned to imprisonment for
a certain term; or, if the offence be of a graver nature, he may be
transported to Siberia either for a fixed period or for life. By
the administrative procedure he is simply removed without a trial
to some distant town, and compelled to live there under police
supervision during his Majesty's pleasure. Nikolai Ivan'itch was
treated "administratively," because the authorities, though
convinced that he was a dangerous character, could not find
sufficient evidence to procure his conviction before a court of
justice. For five years he lived under police supervision in a
small town near the White Sea, and then one day he was informed,
without any explanation, that he might go and live anywhere he
pleased except in St. Petersburg and Moscow.
Since that time he has lived with his brother, and spends his time
in brooding over his grievances and bewailing his shattered
illusions. He has lost none of that fluency which gained him an
ephemeral literary reputation, and can speak by the hour on
political and social questions to any one who will listen to him.
It is extremely difficult, however, to follow his discourses, and
utterly impossible to retain them in the memory. They belong to
what may be called political metaphysics--for though he professes
to hold metaphysics in abhorrence, he is himself a thorough
metaphysician in his modes of thought. He lives, indeed, in a
world of abstract conceptions, in which he can scarcely perceive
concrete facts, and his arguments are always a kind of clever
juggling with such equivocal, conventional terms as aristocracy,
bourgeoisie, monarchy, and the like. At concrete facts he arrives,
not directly by observation, but by deductions from general
principles, so that his facts can never by any possibility
contradict his theories. Then he has certain axioms which he
tacitly assumes, and on which all his arguments are based; as, for
instance, that everything to which the term "liberal" can be
applied must necessarily be good at all times and under all
conditions.
Among a mass of vague conceptions which it is impossible to reduce
to any clearly defined form he has a few ideas which are perhaps
not strictly true, but which are at least intelligible. Among
these is his conviction that Russia has let slip a magnificent
opportunity of distancing all Europe on the road of progress. She
might, he thinks, at the time of the Emancipation, have boldly
accepted all the most advanced principles of political and social
science, and have completely reorganised the political and social
structure in accordance with them. Other nations could not take
such a step, because they are old and decrepit, filled with
stubborn, hereditary prejudices, and cursed with an aristocracy and
a bourgeoisie; but Russia is young, knows nothing of social castes,
and has no deep-rooted prejudices to contend with. The population
is like potter's clay, which can be made to assume any form that
science may recommend. Alexander II. began a magnificent
sociological experiment, but he stopped half-way.
Some day, he believes, the experiment will be completed, but not by
the autocratic power. In his opinion autocracy is "played out,"
and must give way to Parliamentary institutions. For him a
Constitution is a kind of omnipotent fetish. You may try to
explain to him that a Parliamentary regime, whatever its advantages
may be, necessarily produces political parties and political
conflicts, and is not nearly so suitable for grand sociological
experiments as a good paternal despotism. You may try to convince
him that, though it may be difficult to convert an autocrat, it is
infinitely more difficult to convert a House of Commons. But all
your efforts will be in vain. He will assure you that a Russian
Parliament would be something quite different from what Parliaments
commonly are. It would contain no parties, for Russia has no
social castes, and would be guided entirely by scientific
considerations--as free from prejudice and personal influences as a
philosopher speculating on the nature of the Infinite! In short,
he evidently imagines that a national Parliament would be composed
of himself and his friends, and that the nation would calmly submit
to their ukazes, as it has hitherto submitted to the ukazes of the
Tsars.
Pending the advent of this political Millennium, when unimpassioned
science is to reign supreme, Nikolai Ivan'itch allows himself the
luxury of indulging in some very decided political animosities, and
he hates with the fervour of a fanatic. Firstly and chiefly, he
hates what he calls the bourgeoisie--he is obliged to use the
French word, because his native language does not contain an
equivalent term--and especially capitalists of all sorts and
dimensions. Next, he hates aristocracy, especially a form of
aristocracy called Feudalism. To these abstract terms he does not
attach a very precise meaning, but he hates the entities which they
are supposed to represent quite as heartily as if they were
personal enemies. Among the things which he hates in his own
country, the Autocratic Power holds the first place. Next, as an
emanation from the Autocratic Power, come the tchinovniks, and
especially the gendarmes. Then come the landed proprietors.
Though he is himself a landed proprietor, he regards the class as
cumberers of the ground, and thinks that all their land should be
confiscated and distributed among the peasantry.
All proprietors have the misfortune to come under his sweeping
denunciations, because they are inconsistent with his ideal of a
peasant Empire, but he recognises amongst them degrees of
depravity. Some are simply obstructive, whilst others are actively
prejudicial to the public welfare. Among these latter a special
object of aversion is Prince S----, because he not only possesses
very large estates, but at the same time has aristocratic
pretensions, and calls himself Conservative.
Prince S---- is by far the most important man in the district. His
family is one of the oldest in the country, but he does not owe his
influence to his pedigree, for pedigree pure and simple does not
count for much in Russia. He is influential and respected because
he is a great land-holder with a high official position, and
belongs by birth to that group of families which forms the
permanent nucleus of the ever-changing Court society. His father
and grandfather were important personages in the Administration and
at Court, and his sons and grandsons will probably in this respect
follow in the footsteps of their ancestors. Though in the eye of
the law all nobles are equal, and, theoretically speaking,
promotion is gained exclusively by personal merit, yet, in reality,
those who have friends at Court rise more easily and more rapidly.
The Prince has had a prosperous but not very eventful life. He was
educated, first at home, under an English tutor, and afterwards in
the Corps des Pages. On leaving this institution he entered a
regiment of the Guards, and rose steadily to high military rank.
His activity, however, has been chiefly in the civil
administration, and he now has a seat in the Council of State.
Though he has always taken a certain interest in public affairs, he
did not play an important part in any of the great reforms. When
the peasant question was raised he sympathised with the idea of
Emancipation, but did not at all sympathise with the idea of giving
land to the emancipated serfs and preserving the Communal
institutions. What he desired was that the proprietors should
liberate their serfs without any pecuniary indemnity, and should
receive in return a certain share of political power. His scheme
was not adopted, but he has not relinquished the hope that the
great landed proprietors may somehow obtain a social and political
position similar to that of the great land-owners in England.
Official duties and social relations compel the Prince to live for
a large part of the year in the capital. He spends only a few
weeks yearly on his estate. The house is large, and fitted up in
the English style, with a view to combining elegance and comfort.
It contains several spacious apartments, a library, and a billiard-
room. There is an extensive park, an immense garden with hot
houses, numerous horses and carriages, and a legion of servants.
In the drawing-room is a plentiful supply of English and French
books, newspapers, and periodicals, including the Journal de St.
Petersbourg, which gives the news of the day.
The family have, in short, all the conveniences and comforts which
money and refinement can procure, but it cannot be said that they
greatly enjoy the time spent in the country. The Princess has no
decided objection to it. She is devoted to a little grandchild, is
fond of reading and correspondence, amuses herself with a school
and hospital which she has founded for the peasantry, and
occasionally drives over to see her friend, the Countess N----, who
lives about fifteen miles off.
The Prince, however, finds country life excessively dull. He does
not care for riding or shooting, and he finds nothing else to do.
He knows nothing about the management of his estate, and holds
consultations with the steward merely pro forma--this estate and
the others which he possesses in different provinces being ruled by
a head-steward in St. Petersburg, in whom he has the most complete
confidence. In the vicinity there is no one with whom he cares to
associate. Naturally he is not a sociable man, and he has acquired
a stiff, formal, reserved manner that is rarely met with in Russia.
This manner repels the neighbouring proprietors--a fact that he
does not at all regret, for they do not belong to his monde, and
they have in their manners and habits a free-and-easy rusticity
which is positively disagreeable to him. His relations with them
are therefore confined to formal calls. The greater part of the
day he spends in listless loitering, frequently yawning, regretting
the routine of St. Petersburg life--the pleasant chats with his
colleagues, the opera, the ballet, the French theatre, and the
quiet rubber at the Club Anglais. His spirits rise as the day of
his departure approaches, and when he drives off to the station he
looks bright and cheerful. If he consulted merely his own tastes
he would never visit his estates at all, and would spend his summer
holidays in Germany, France, or Switzerland, as he did in his
bachelor days; but as a large landowner he considers it right to
sacrifice his personal inclinations to the duties of his position.
There is, by the way, another princely magnate in the district, and
I ought perhaps to introduce him to my readers, because he
represents worthily a new type. Like Prince S----, of whom I have
just spoken, he is a great land-owner and a descendant of the half-
mythical Rurik; but he has no official rank, and does not possess a
single grand cordon. In that respect he has followed in the
footsteps of his father and grandfather, who had something of the
frondeur spirit, and preferred the position of a grand seigneur and
a country gentleman to that of a tchinovnik and a courtier. In the
Liberal camp he is regarded as a Conservative, but he has little in
common with the Krepostnik, who declares that the reforms of the
last half-century were a mistake, that everything is going to the
bad, that the emancipated serfs are all sluggards, drunkards, and
thieves, that the local self-government is an ingenious machine for
wasting money, and that the reformed law-courts have conferred
benefits only on the lawyers. On the contrary, he recognises the
necessity and beneficent results of the reforms, and with regard to
the future he has none of the despairing pessimism of the
incorrigible old Tory.
But in order that real progress should be made, he thinks that
certain current and fashionable errors must be avoided, and among
these errors he places, in the first rank, the views and principles
of the advanced Liberals, who have a blind admiration for Western
Europe, and for what they are pleased to call the results of
science. Like the Liberals of the West, these gentlemen assume
that the best form of government is constitutionalism, monarchical
or republican, on a broad democratic basis, and towards the
realisation of this ideal all their efforts are directed. Not so
our Conservative friend. While admitting that democratic
Parliamentary institutions may be the best form of government for
the more advanced nations of the West, he maintains that the only
firm foundation for the Russian Empire, and the only solid
guarantee of its future prosperity, is the Autocratic Power, which
is the sole genuine representative of the national spirit. Looking
at the past from this point of view, he perceives that the Tsars
have ever identified themselves with the nation, and have always
understood, in part instinctively and in part by reflection, what
the nation really required. Whenever the infiltration of Western
ideas threatened to swamp the national individuality, the
Autocratic Power intervened and averted the danger by timely
precautions. Something of the kind may be observed, he believes,
at present, when the Liberals are clamouring for a Parliament and a
Constitution; but the Autocratic Power is on the alert, and is
making itself acquainted with the needs of the people by means far
more effectual than could be supplied by oratorical politicians.
With the efforts of the Zemstvo in this direction, and with the
activity of the Zemstvo generally, the Prince has little sympathy,
partly because the institution is in the hands of the Liberals and
is guided by their unpractical ideas, and partly because it enables
some ambitious outsiders to acquire the influence in local affairs
which ought to be exercised by the old-established noble families
of the neighbourhood. What he would like to see is an enlightened,
influential gentry working in conjunction with the Autocratic Power
for the good of the country. If Russia could produce a few hundred
thousand men like himself, his ideal might perhaps be realised.
For the present, such men are extremely rare--I should have
difficulty in naming a dozen of them--and aristocratic ideas are
extremely unpopular among the great majority of the educated
classes. When a Russian indulges in political speculation, he is
pretty sure to show himself thoroughly democratic, with a strong
leaning to socialism.
The Prince belongs to the highest rank of the Russian Noblesse. If
we wish to get an idea of the lowest rank, we can find in the
neighbourhood a number of poor, uneducated men, who live in small,
squalid houses, and are not easily to be distinguished from
peasants. They are nobles, like his Highness; but, unlike him,
they enjoy no social consideration, and their landed property
consists of a few acres of land which barely supply them with the
first necessaries of life. If we went to other parts of the
country we might find men in this condition bearing the title of
Prince! This is the natural result of the Russian law of
inheritance, which does not recognise the principle of
primogeniture with regard to titles and estates. All the sons of a
Prince are Princes, and at his death his property, movable and
immovable, is divided amongst them.
CHAPTER XXIII
SOCIAL CLASSES
Do Social Classes or Castes Exist in Russia?--Well-marked Social
Types--Classes Recognised by the Legislation and the Official
Statistics--Origin and Gradual Formation of these Classes--
Peculiarity in the Historical Development of Russia--Political Life
and Political Parties.
In the preceding pages I have repeatedly used the expression
"social classes," and probably more than once the reader has felt
inclined to ask, What are social classes in the Russian sense of
the term? It may be well, therefore, before going farther, to
answer this question.
If the question were put to a Russian it is not at all unlikely
that he would reply somewhat in this fashion: "In Russia there are
no social classes, and there never have been any. That fact
constitutes one of the most striking peculiarities of her
historical development, and one of the surest foundations of her
future greatness. We know nothing, and have never known anything,
of those class distinctions and class enmities which in Western
Europe have often rudely shaken society in past times, and imperil
its existence in the future."
This statement will not be readily accepted by the traveller who
visits Russia with no preconceived ideas and forms his opinions
from his own observations. To him it seems that class distinctions
form one of the most prominent characteristics of Russian society.
In a few days he learns to distinguish the various classes by their
outward appearance. He easily recognises the French-speaking
nobles in West-European costume; the burly, bearded merchant in
black cloth cap and long, shiny, double-breasted coat; the priest
with his uncut hair and flowing robes; the peasant with his full,
fair beard and unsavoury, greasy sheepskin. Meeting everywhere
those well-marked types, he naturally assumes that Russian society
is composed of exclusive castes; and this first impression will be
fully confirmed by a glance at the Code. On examining that
monumental work, he finds that an entire volume--and by no means
the smallest--is devoted to the rights and obligations of the
various classes. From this he concludes that the classes have a
legal as well as an actual existence. To make assurance doubly
sure he turns to official statistics, and there he finds the
following table:
Hereditary nobles........652,887
Personal nobles..........374,367
Clerical classes.........695,905
Town classes...........7,196,005
Rural classes.........63,840,291
Military classes.......4,767,703
Foreigners...............153,185
----------
77,680,293*
* Livron: "Statistitcheskoe Obozrenie Rossiiskoi Imperii," St.
Petersburg, 1875. The above figures include the whole Empire. The
figures according to the latest census (1897) are not yet
available.
Armed with these materials, the traveller goes to his Russian
friends who have assured him that their country knows nothing of
class distinctions. He is confident of being able to convince them
that they have been labouring under a strange delusion, but he will
be disappointed. They will tell him that these laws and statistics
prove nothing, and that the categories therein mentioned are mere
administrative fictions.
This apparent contradiction is to be explained by the equivocal
meaning of the Russian terms Sosloviya and Sostoyaniya, which are
commonly translated "social classes." If by these terms are meant
"castes" in the Oriental sense, then it may be confidently asserted
that such do not exist in Russia. Between the nobles, the clergy,
the burghers, and the peasants there are no distinctions of race
and no impassable barriers. The peasant often becomes a merchant,
and there are many cases on record of peasants and sons of parish
priests becoming nobles. Until very recently the parish clergy
composed, as we have seen, a peculiar and exclusive class, with
many of the characteristics of a caste; but this has been changed,
and it may now be said that in Russia there are no castes in the
Oriental sense.
If the word Sosloviya be taken to mean an organised political unit
with an esprit de corps and a clearly conceived political aim, it
may likewise be admitted that there are none in Russia. As there
has been for centuries no political life among the subjects of the
Tsars, there have been no political parties.
On the other hand, to say that social classes have never existed in
Russia and that the categories which appear in the legislation and
in the official statistics are mere administrative fictions, is a
piece of gross exaggeration.
From the very beginning of Russian history we can detect
unmistakably the existence of social classes, such as the Princes,
the Boyars, the armed followers of the Princes, the peasantry, the
slaves, and various others; and one of the oldest legal documents
which we possess--the "Russian Right" (Russkaya Pravda) of the
Grand Prince Yaroslaff (1019-1054)--contains irrefragable proof, in
the penalties attached to various crimes, that these classes were
formally recognised by the legislation. Since that time they have
frequently changed their character, but they have never at any
period ceased to exist.
In ancient times, when there was very little administrative
regulation, the classes had perhaps no clearly defined boundaries,
and the peculiarities which distinguished them from each other were
actual rather than legal--lying in the mode of life and social
position rather than in peculiar obligations and privileges. But
as the autocratic power developed and strove to transform the
nation into a State with a highly centralised administration, the
legal element in the social distinctions became more and more
prominent. For financial and other purposes the people had to be
divided into various categories. The actual distinctions were of
course taken as the basis of the legal classification, but the
classifying had more than a merely formal significance. The
necessity of clearly defining the different groups entailed the
necessity of elevating and strengthening the barriers which already
existed between them, and the difficulty of passing from one group
to another was thereby increased.
In this work of classification Peter the Great especially
distinguished himself. With his insatiable passion for regulation,
he raised formidable barriers between the different categories, and
defined the obligations of each with microscopic minuteness. After
his death the work was carried on in the same spirit, and the
tendency reached its climax in the reign of Nicholas, when the
number of students to be received in the universities was
determined by Imperial ukaz!
In the reign of Catherine a new element was introduced into the
official conception of social classes. Down to her time the
Government had thought merely of class obligations; under the
influence of Western ideas she introduced the conception of class
rights. She wished, as we have seen, to have in her Empire a
Noblesse and tiers-etat like those which existed in France, and for
this purpose she granted, first to the Dvoryanstvo and afterwards
to the towns, an Imperial Charter, or Bill of Rights. Succeeding
sovereigns have acted in the same spirit, and the Code now confers
on each class numerous privileges as well as numerous obligations.
Thus, we see, the oft-repeated assertion that the Russian social
classes are simply artificial categories created by the legislature
is to a certain extent true, but is by no means accurate. The
social groups, such as peasants, landed proprietors, and the like,
came into existence in Russia, as in other countries, by the simple
force of circumstances. The legislature merely recognised and
developed the social distinctions which already existed. The legal
status, obligations, and rights of each group were minutely defined
and regulated, and legal barriers were added to the actual barriers
which separated the groups from each other.
What is peculiar in the historical development of Russia is this:
until lately she remained an almost exclusively agricultural Empire
with abundance of unoccupied land. Her history presents,
therefore, few of those conflicts which result from the variety of
social conditions and the intensified struggle for existence.
Certain social groups were, indeed, formed in the course of time,
but they were never allowed to fight out their own battles. The
irresistible autocratic power kept them always in check and
fashioned them into whatever form it thought proper, defining
minutely and carefully their obligations, their rights, their
mutual relations, and their respective positions in the political
organisation. Hence we find in the history of Russia almost no
trace of those class hatreds which appear so conspicuously in the
history of Western Europe.*
* This is, I believe, the true explanation of an important fact,
which the Slavophils endeavoured to explain by an ill-authenticated
legend (vide supra p.151).
The practical consequence of all this is that in Russia at the
present day there is very little caste spirit or caste prejudice.
Within half-a-dozen years after the emancipation of the serfs,
proprietors and peasants, forgetting apparently their old
relationship of master and serf, were working amicably together in
the new local administration, and not a few similar curious facts
might be cited. The confident anticipation of many Russians that
their country will one day enjoy political life without political
parties is, if not a contradiction in terms, at least a Utopian
absurdity; but we may be sure that when political parties do appear
they will be very different from those which exist in Germany,
France, and England.
Meanwhile, let us see how the country is governed without political
parties and without political life in the West-European sense of
the term. This will form the subject of our next chapter.
CHAPTER XXIV
THE IMPERIAL ADMINISTRATION AND THE OFFICIALS
The Officials in Norgorod Assist Me in My Studies--The Modern
Imperial Administration Created by Peter the Great, and Developed
by his Successors--A Slavophil's View of the Administration--The
Administration Briefly Described--The Tchinovniks, or Officials--
Official Titles, and Their Real Significance--What the
Administration Has Done for Russia in the Past--Its Character
Determined by the Peculiar Relation between the Government and the
People--Its Radical Vices--Bureaucratic Remedies--Complicated
Formal Procedure--The Gendarmerie: My Personal Relations with this
Branch of the Administration; Arrest and Release--A Strong, Healthy
Public Opinion the Only Effectual Remedy for Bad Administration.
My administrative studies were begun in Novgorod. One of my
reasons for spending a winter in that provincial capital was that I
might study the provincial administration, and as soon as I had
made the acquaintance of the leading officials I explained to them
the object I had in view. With the kindly bonhomie which
distinguishes the Russian educated classes, they all volunteered to
give me every assistance in their power, but some of them, on
mature reflection, evidently saw reason to check their first
generous impulse. Among these was the Vice-Governor, a gentleman
of German origin, and therefore more inclined to be pedantic than a
genuine Russian. When I called on him one evening and reminded him
of his friendly offer, I found to my surprise that he had in the
meantime changed his mind. Instead of answering my first simple
inquiry, he stared at me fixedly, as if for the purpose of
detecting some covert, malicious design, and then, putting on an
air of official dignity, informed me that as I had not been
authorised by the Minister to make these investigations, he could
not assist me, and would certainly not allow me to examine the
archives.
This was not encouraging, but it did not prevent me from applying
to the Governor, and I found him a man of a very different stamp.
Delighted to meet a foreigner who seemed anxious to study seriously
in an unbiassed frame of mind the institutions of his much-maligned
native country, he willingly explained to me the mechanism of the
administration which he directed and controlled, and kindly placed
at my disposal the books and documents in which I could find the
historical and practical information which I required.
This friendly attitude of his Excellency towards me soon became
generally known in the town, and from that moment my difficulties
were at an end. The minor officials no longer hesitated to
initiate me into the mysteries of their respective departments, and
at last even the Vice-Governor threw off his reserve and followed
the example of his colleagues. The elementary information thus
acquired I had afterwards abundant opportunities of completing by
observation and study in other parts of the Empire, and I now
propose to communicate to the reader a few of the more general
results.
The gigantic administrative machine which holds together all the
various parts of the vast Empire has been gradually created by
successive generations, but we may say roughly that it was first
designed and constructed by Peter the Great. Before his time the
country was governed in a rude, primitive fashion. The Grand
Princes of Moscow, in subduing their rivals and annexing the
surrounding principalities, merely cleared the ground for a great
homogeneous State. Wily, practical politicians, rather than
statesmen of the doctrinaire type, they never dreamed of
introducing uniformity and symmetry into the administration as a
whole. They developed the ancient institutions so far as these
were useful and consistent with the exercise of autocratic power,
and made only such alterations as practical necessity demanded.
And these necessary alterations were more frequently local than
general. Special decisions, instruction to particular officials,
and charters for particular communes of proprietors were much more
common than general legislative measures.
In short, the old Muscovite Tsars practised a hand-to-mouth policy,
destroying whatever caused temporary inconvenience, and giving
little heed to what did not force itself upon their attention.
Hence, under their rule the administration presented not only
territorial peculiarities, but also an ill-assorted combination of
different systems in the same district--a conglomeration of
institutions belonging to different epochs, like a fleet composed
of triremes, three-deckers, and iron-clads.
This irregular system, or rather want of system, seemed highly
unsatisfactory to the logical mind of Peter the Great, and he
conceived the grand design of sweeping it away, and putting in its
place a symmetrical bureaucratic machine. It is scarcely necessary
to say that this magnificent project, so foreign to the traditional
ideas and customs of the people, was not easily realised. Imagine
a man, without technical knowledge, without skilled workmen,
without good tools, and with no better material than soft,
crumbling sandstone, endeavouring to build a palace on a marsh!
The undertaking would seem to reasonable minds utterly absurd, and
yet it must be admitted that Peter's project was scarcely more
feasible. He had neither technical knowledge, nor the requisite
materials, nor a firm foundation to build on. With his usual
Titanic energy he demolished the old structure, but his attempts to
construct were little more than a series of failures. In his
numerous ukazes he has left us a graphic description of his
efforts, and it is at once instructive and pathetic to watch the
great worker toiling indefatigably at his self-imposed task. His
instruments are constantly breaking in his hands. The foundations
of the building are continually giving way, and the lower tiers
crumbling under the superincumbent weight. Now and then a whole
section is found to be unsuitable, and is ruthlessly pulled down,
or falls of its own accord. And yet the builder toils on, with a
perseverance and an energy of purpose that compel admiration,
frankly confessing his mistakes and failures, and patiently seeking
the means of remedying them, never allowing a word of despondency
to escape him, and never despairing of ultimate success. And at
length death comes, and the mighty builder is snatched away
suddenly in the midst of his unfinished labours, bequeathing to his
successors the task of carrying on the great work.
None of these successors possessed Peter's genius and energy--with
the exception perhaps of Catherine II.--but they were all compelled
by the force of circumstances to adopt his plans. A return to the
old rough-and-ready rule of time local Voyevods was impossible. As
the Autocratic Power became more and more imbued with Western
ideas, it felt more and more the need of new means for carrying
them out, and accordingly it strove to systematise and centralise
the administration.
In this change we may perceive a certain analogy with the history
of the French administration from the reign of Philippe le Bel to
that of Louis XIV. In both countries we see the central power
bringing the local administrative organs more and more under its
control, till at last it succeeds in creating a thoroughly
centralised bureaucratic organisation. But under this superficial
resemblance lie profound differences. The French kings had to
struggle with provincial sovereignties and feudal rights, and when
they had annihilated this opposition they easily found materials
with which to build up the bureaucratic structure. The Russian
sovereigns, on the contrary, met with no such opposition, but they
had great difficulty in finding bureaucratic material amongst their
uneducated, undisciplined subjects, notwithstanding the numerous
schools and colleges which were founded and maintained simply for
the purpose of preparing men for the public service.
The administration was thus brought much nearer to the West-
European ideal, but some people have grave doubts as to whether it
became thereby better adapted to the practical wants of the people
for whom it was created. On this point a well-known Slavophil once
made to me some remarks which are worthy of being recorded. "You
have observed," he said, "that till very recently there was in
Russia an enormous amount of official peculation, extortion, and
misgovernment of every kind, that the courts of law were dens of
iniquity, that the people often committed perjury, and much more of
the same sort, and it must be admitted that all this has not yet
entirely disappeared. But what does it prove? That the Russian
people are morally inferior to the German? Not at all. It simply
proves that the German system of administration, which was forced
upon them without their consent, was utterly unsuited to their
nature. If a young growing boy be compelled to wear very tight
boots, he will probably burst them, and the ugly rents will
doubtless produce an unfavourable impression on the passers-by; but
surely it is better that the boots should burst than that the feet
should be deformed. Now, the Russian people was compelled to put
on not only tight boots, but also a tight jacket, and, being young
and vigorous, it burst them. Narrow-minded, pedantic Germans can
neither understand nor provide for the wants of the broad Slavonic
nature."
In its present form the Russian administration seems at first sight
a very imposing edifice. At the top of the pyramid stands the
Emperor, "the autocratic monarch," as Peter the Great described
him, "who has to give an account of his acts to no one on earth,
but has power and authority to rule his States and lands as a
Christian sovereign according to his own will and judgment."
Immediately below the Emperor we see the Council of State, the
Committee of Ministers, and the Senate, which represent
respectively the legislative, the administrative, and the judicial
power. An Englishman glancing over the first volume of the great
Code of Laws might imagine that the Council of State is a kind of
Parliament, and the Committee of Ministers a cabinet in our sense
of the term, but in reality both institutions are simply
incarnations of the Autocratic Power. Though the Council is
entrusted by law with many important functions--such as discussing
Bills, criticising the annual budget, declaring war and concluding
peace--it has merely a consultative character, and the Emperor is
not in any way bound by its decisions. The Committee is not at all
a cabinet as we understand the word. The Ministers are directly
and individually responsible to the Emperor, and therefore the
Committee has no common responsibility or other cohesive force. As
to the Senate, it has descended from its high estate. It was
originally entrusted with the supreme power during the absence or
minority of the monarch, and was intended to exercise a controlling
influence in all sections of the administration, but now its
activity is restricted to judicial matters, and it is little more
than a supreme court of appeal.
Immediately below these three institutions stand the Ministries,
ten in number. They are the central points in which converge the
various kinds of territorial administration, and from which
radiates the Imperial will all over the Empire.
For the purpose of territorial administration Russia proper--that
is to say, European Russia, exclusive of Poland, the Baltic
Provinces, Finland and the Caucasus--is divided into forty-nine
provinces or "Governments" (gubernii), and each Government is
subdivided into Districts (uyezdi). The average area of a province
is about the size of Portugal, but some are as small as Belgium,
whilst one at least is twenty-five times as big. The population,
however, does not correspond to the amount of territory. In the
largest province, that of Archangel, there are only about 350,000
inhabitants, whilst in two of the smaller ones there are over three
millions. The districts likewise vary greatly in size. Some are
smaller than Oxfordshire or Buckingham, and others are bigger than
the whole of the United Kingdom.
Over each province is placed a Governor, who is assisted in his
duties by a Vice-Governor and a small council. According to the
legislation of Catherine II., which still appears in the Code and
has only been partially repealed, the Governor is termed "the
steward of the province," and is entrusted with so many and such
delicate duties, that in order to obtain qualified men for the post
it would be necessary to realise the great Empress's design of
creating, by education, "a new race of people." Down to the time
of the Crimean War the Governors understood the term "stewards" in
a very literal sense, and ruled in a most arbitrary, high-handed
style, often exercising an important influence on the civil and
criminal tribunals. These extensive and vaguely defined powers
have now been very much curtailed, partly by positive legislation,
and partly by increased publicity and improved means of
communication. All judicial matters have been placed theoretically
beyond the Governor's control, and many of his former functions are
now fulfilled by the Zemstvo--the new organ of local self-
government. Besides this, all ordinary current affairs are
regulated by an already big and ever-growing body of instructions,
in the form of Imperial orders and ministerial circulars, and as
soon as anything not provided for by the instructions happens to
occur, the minister is consulted through the post-office or by
telegraph.
Even within the sphere of their lawful authority the Governors have
now a certain respect for public opinion and occasionally a very
wholesome dread of casual newspaper correspondents. Thus the men
who were formerly described by the satirists as "little satraps"
have sunk to the level of subordinate officials. I can confidently
say that many (I believe the majority) of them are honest, upright
men, who are perhaps not endowed with any unusual administrative
capacities, but who perform their duties faithfully according to
their lights. If any representatives of the old "satraps" still
exist, they must be sought for in the outlying Asiatic provinces.
Independent of the Governor, who is the local representative of the
Ministry of the Interior, are a number of resident officials, who
represent the other ministries, and each of them has a bureau, with
the requisite number of assistants, secretaries, and scribes.
To keep this vast and complex bureaucratic machine in motion it is
necessary to have a large and well-drilled army of officials.
These are drawn chiefly from the ranks of the Noblesse and the
clergy, and form a peculiar social class called Tchinovniks, or men
with Tchins. As the Tchin plays an important part in Russia, not
only in the official world, but also to some extent in social life,
it may be well to explain its significance.
All offices, civil and military, are, according to a scheme
invented by Peter the Great, arranged in fourteen classes or ranks,
and to each class or rank a particular name is attached. As
promotion is supposed to be given according to personal merit, a
man who enters the public service for the first time must, whatever
be his social position, begin in the lower ranks, and work his way
upwards. Educational certificates may exempt him from the
necessity of passing through the lowest classes, and the Imperial
will may disregard the restrictions laid down by law; but as
general rule a man must begin at or near the bottom of the official
ladder, and he must remain on each step a certain specified time.
The step on which he is for the moment standing, or, in other
words, the official rank or tchin which he possesses determines
what offices he is competent to hold. Thus rank or tchin is a
necessary condition for receiving an appointment, but it does not
designate any actual office, and the names of the different ranks
are extremely apt to mislead a foreigner.
We must always bear this in mind when we meet with those imposing
titles which Russian tourists sometimes put on their visiting
cards, such as "Conseiller de Cour," "Conseiller d'Etat,"
"Conseiller prive de S. M. l'Empereur de toutes les Russies." It
would be uncharitable to suppose that these titles are used with
the intention of misleading, but that they do sometimes mislead
there cannot be the least doubt. I shall never forget the look of
intense disgust which I once saw on the face of an American who had
invited to dinner a "Conseiller de Cour," on the assumption that he
would have a Court dignitary as his guest, and who casually
discovered that the personage in question was simply an
insignificant official in one of the public offices. No doubt
other people have bad similar experiences. The unwary foreigner
who has heard that there is in Russia a very important institution
called the Conseil d'Etat," naturally supposes that a " Conseiller
d'Etat" is a member of that venerable body; and if he meets "Son
Excellence le Conseiller prive," he is pretty sure to assume--
especially if the word "actuel" has been affixed--that he sees
before him a real living member of the Russian Privy Council. When
to the title is added, "de S. M. l'Empereur de toutes les Russies,"
a boundless field is opened up to the non-Russian imagination. In
reality these titles are not nearly so important as they seem. The
soi-disant "Conseiller de Cour" has probably nothing to do with the
Court. The Conseiller d'Etat is so far from being a member of the
Conseil d'Etat that he cannot possibly become a member till he
receives a higher tchin.* As to the Privy Councillor, it is
sufficient to say that the Privy Council, which had a very odious
reputation in its lifetime, died more than a century ago, and has
not since been resuscitated. The explanation of these anomalies is
to be found in the fact that the Russian tchins, like the German
honorary titles--Hofrath, Staatsrath, Geheimrath--of which they are
a literal translation, indicate not actual office, but simply
official rank. Formerly the appointment to an office generally
depended on the tchin; now there is a tendency to reverse the old
order of things and make the tchin depend upon the office actually
held.
* In Russian the two words are quite different; the Council is
called Gosudarstvenny sovet, and the title Statski sovetnik.
The reader of practical mind who is in the habit of considering
results rather than forms and formalities desires probably no
further description of the Russian bureaucracy, but wishes to know
simply how it works in practice. What has it done for Russia in
the past, and what is it doing in the present?
At the present day, when faith in despotic civilisers and paternal
government has been rudely shaken, and the advantages of a free,
spontaneous national development are fully recognised, centralised
bureaucracies have everywhere fallen into bad odour. In Russia the
dislike to them is particularly strong, because it has there
something more than a purely theoretical basis. The recollection
of the reign of Nicholas I., with its stern military regime, and
minute, pedantic formalism, makes many Russians condemn in no
measured terms the administration under which they live, and most
Englishmen will feel inclined to endorse this condemnation. Before
passing sentence, however, we ought to know that the system has at
least an historical justification, and we must not allow our love
of constitutional liberty and local self-government to blind us to
the distinction between theoretical and historical possibility.
What seems to political philosophers abstractly the best possible
government may be utterly inapplicable in certain concrete cases.
We need not attempt to decide whether it is better for humanity
that Russia should exist as a nation, but we may boldly assert that
without a strongly centralised administration Russia would never
have become one of the great European Powers. Until comparatively
recent times the part of the world which is known as the Russian
Empire was a conglomeration of independent or semi-independent
political units, animated with centrifugal as well as centripetal
forces; and even at the present day it is far from being a compact
homogeneous State. It was the autocratic power, with the
centralised administration as its necessary complement, that first
created Russia, then saved her from dismemberment and political
annihilation, and ultimately secured for her a place among European
nations by introducing Western civilisation.
Whilst thus recognising clearly that autocracy and a strongly
centralised administration were necessary first for the creation
and afterwards for the preservation of national independence, we
must not shut our eyes to the evil consequences which resulted from
this unfortunate necessity. It was in the nature of things that
the Government, aiming at the realisation of designs which its
subjects neither sympathised with nor clearly understood, should
have become separated from the nation; and the reckless haste and
violence with which it attempted to carry out its schemes aroused a
spirit of positive opposition among the masses. A considerable
section of the people long looked on the reforming Tsars as
incarnations of the spirit of evil, and the Tsars in their turn
looked upon the people as raw material for the realisation of their
political designs. This peculiar relation between the nation and
the Government has given the key-note to the whole system of
administration. The Government has always treated the people as
minors, incapable of understanding its political aims, and only
very partially competent to look after their own local affairs.
The officials have naturally acted in the same spirit. Looking for
direction and approbation merely to their superiors, they have
systematically treated those over whom they were placed as a
conquered or inferior race. The State has thus come to be regarded
as an abstract entity, with interests entirely different from those
of the human beings composing it; and in all matters in which State
interests are supposed to be involved, the rights of individuals
are ruthlessly sacrificed.
If we remember that the difficulties of centralised administration
must be in direct proportion to the extent and territorial variety
of the country to be governed, we may readily understand how slowly
and imperfectly the administrative machine necessarily works in
Russia. The whole of the vast region stretching from the Polar
Ocean to the Caspian, and from the shores of the Baltic to the
confines of the Celestial Empire, is administered from St.
Petersburg. The genuine bureaucrat has a wholesome dread of formal
responsibility, and generally tries to avoid it by taking all
matters out of the hands of his subordinates, and passing them on
to the higher authorities. As soon, therefore, as affairs are
caught up by the administrative machine they begin to ascend, and
probably arrive some day at the cabinet of the minister. Thus the
ministries are flooded with papers--many of the most trivial
import--from all parts of the Empire; and the higher officials,
even if they had the eyes of an Argus and the hands of a Briareus,
could not possibly fulfil conscientiously the duties imposed on
them. In reality the Russian administrators of the higher ranks
recall neither Argus nor Briareus. They commonly show neither an
extensive nor a profound knowledge of the country which they are
supposed to govern, and seem always to have a fair amount of
leisure time at their disposal.
Besides the unavoidable evils of excessive centralisation, Russia
has had to suffer much from the jobbery, venality, and extortion of
the officials. When Peter the Great one day proposed to hang every
man who should steal as much as would buy a rope, his Procurator-
General frankly replied that if his Majesty put his project into
execution there would be no officials left. "We all steal," added
the worthy official; "the only difference is that some of us steal
larger amounts and more openly than others." Since these words
were spoken nearly two centuries have passed, and during all that
time Russia has been steadily making progress, but until the
accession of Alexander II. in 1855 little change took place in the
moral character of the administration. Some people still living
can remember the time when they could have repeated, without much
exaggeration, the confession of Peter's Procurator-General.
To appreciate aright this ugly phenomenon we must distinguish two
kinds of venality. On the one hand there was the habit of exacting
what are vulgarly termed "tips" for services performed, and on the
other there were the various kinds of positive dishonesty. Though
it might not be always easy to draw a clear line between the two
categories, the distinction was fully recognised in the moral
consciousness of the time, and many an official who regularly
received "sinless revenues" (bezgreshniye dokhodi), as the tips
were sometimes called, would have been very indignant had he been
stigmatised as a dishonest man. The practice was, in fact,
universal, and could be, to a certain extent, justified by the
smallness of the official salaries. In some departments there was
a recognised tariff. The "brandy farmers," for example, who worked
the State Monopoly for the manufacture and sale of alcoholic
liquors, paid regularly a fixed sum to every official, from the
Governor to the policeman, according to his rank. I knew of one
case where an official, on receiving a larger sum than was
customary, conscientiously handed back the change! The other and
more heinous offences were by no means so common, but were still
fearfully frequent. Many high officials and important dignitaries
were known to receive large revenues, to which the term "sinless"
could not by any means be applied, and yet they retained their
position, and were received in society with respectful deference.
The Sovereigns were well aware of the abuses, and strove more or
less to root them out, but the success which attended their efforts
does not give us a very exalted idea of the practical omnipotence
of autocracy. In a centralised bureaucratic administration, in
which each official is to a certain extent responsible for the sins
of his subordinates, it is always extremely difficult to bring an
official culprit to justice, for he is sure to be protected by his
superiors; and when the superiors are themselves habitually guilty
of malpractices, the culprit is quite safe from exposure and
punishment. The Tsar, indeed, might do much towards exposing and
punishing offenders if he could venture to call in public opinion
to his assistance, but in reality he is very apt to become a party
to the system of hushing up official delinquencies. He is himself
the first official in the realm, and he knows that the abuse of
power by a subordinate has a tendency to produce hostility towards
the fountain of all official power. Frequent punishment of
officials might, it is thought, diminish public respect for the
Government, and undermine that social discipline which is necessary
for the public tranquillity. It is therefore considered expedient
to give to official delinquencies as little publicity as possible.
Besides this, strange as it may seem, a Government which rests on
the arbitrary will of a single individual is, notwithstanding
occasional outbursts of severity, much less systematically severe
than authority founded on free public opinion. When delinquencies
occur in very high places the Tsar is almost sure to display a
leniency approaching to tenderness. If it be necessary to make a
sacrifice to justice, the sacrificial operation is made as painless
as may be, and illustrious scapegoats are not allowed to die of
starvation in the wilderness--the wilderness being generally Paris
or the Riviera. This fact may seem strange to those who are in the
habit of associating autocracy with Neapolitan dungeons and the
mines of Siberia, but it is not difficult to explain. No
individual, even though he be the Autocrat of all the Russias, can
so case himself in the armour of official dignity as to be
completely proof against personal influences. The severity of
autocrats is reserved for political offenders, against whom they
naturally harbour a feeling of personal resentment. It is so much
easier for us to be lenient and charitable towards a man who sins
against public morality than towards one who sins against
ourselves!
In justice to the bureaucratic reformers in Russia, it must be said
that they have preferred prevention to cure. Refraining from all
Draconian legislation, they have put their faith in a system of
ingenious checks and a complicated formal procedure. When we
examine the complicated formalities and labyrinthine procedure by
which the administration is controlled, our first impression is
that administrative abuses must be almost impossible. Every
possible act of every official seems to have been foreseen, and
every possible outlet from the narrow path of honesty seems to have
been carefully walled up. As the English reader has probably no
conception of formal procedure in a highly centralised bureaucracy,
let me give, by way of illustration, an instance which accidentally
came to my knowledge.
In the residence of a Governor-General one of the stoves is in need
of repairs. An ordinary mortal may assume that a man with the rank
of Governor-General may be trusted to expend a few shillings
conscientiously, and that consequently his Excellency will at once
order the repairs to be made and the payment to be put down among
the petty expenses. To the bureaucratic mind the case appears in a
very different light. All possible contingencies must be carefully
provided for. As a Governor-General may possibly be possessed with
a mania for making useless alterations, the necessity for the
repairs ought to be verified; and as wisdom and honesty are more
likely to reside in an assembly than in an individual, it is well
to entrust the verification to a council. A council of three or
four members accordingly certifies that the repairs are necessary.
This is pretty strong authority, but it is not enough. Councils
are composed of mere human beings, liable to error and subject to
be intimidated by a Governor-General. It is prudent, therefore, to
demand that the decision of the council be confirmed by the
Procureur, who is directly subordinated to the Minister of Justice.
When this double confirmation has been obtained, an architect
examines the stove, and makes an estimate. But it would be
dangerous to give carte blanche to an architect, and therefore the
estimate has to be confirmed, first by the aforesaid council and
afterwards by the Procureur. When all these formalities--which
require sixteen days and ten sheets of paper--have been duly
observed, his Excellency is informed that the contemplated repairs
will cost two roubles and forty kopecks, or about five shillings of
our money. Even here the formalities do not stop, for the
Government must have the assurance that the architect who made the
estimate and superintended the repairs has not been guilty of
negligence. A second architect is therefore sent to examine the
work, and his report, like the estimate, requires to be confirmed
by the council and the Procureur. The whole correspondence lasts
thirty days, and requires no less than thirty sheets of paper! Had
the person who desired the repairs been not a Governor-General, but
an ordinary mortal, it is impossible to say how long the procedure
might have lasted.*
* In fairness I feel constrained to add that incidents of this kind
occasionally occur--or at least occurred as late as 1886--in our
Indian Administration. I remember an instance of a pane of glass
being broken in the Viceroy's bedroom in the Viceregal Lodge at
Simla, and it would have required nearly a week, if the official
procedure had been scrupulously observed, to have it replaced by
the Public Works Department.
It might naturally be supposed that this circuitous and complicated
method, with its registers, ledgers, and minutes of proceedings,
must at least prevent pilfering; but this a priori conclusion has
been emphatically belied by experience. Every new ingenious device
had merely the effect of producing a still more ingenious means of
avoiding it. The system did not restrain those who wished to
pilfer, and it had a deleterious effect on honest officials by
making them feel that the Government reposed no confidence in them.
Besides this, it produced among all officials, honest and dishonest
alike, the habit of systematic falsification. As it was impossible
for even the most pedantic of men--and pedantry, be it remarked, is
a rare quality among Russians--to fulfil conscientiously all the
prescribed formalities, it became customary to observe the forms
merely on paper. Officials certified facts which they never
dreamed of examining, and secretaries gravely wrote the minutes of
meetings that had never been held! Thus, in the case above cited,
the repairs were in reality begun and ended long before the
architect was officially authorised to begin the work. The comedy
was nevertheless gravely played out to the end, so that any one
afterwards revising the documents would have found that everything
had been done in perfect order.
Perhaps the most ingenious means for preventing administrative
abuses was devised by the Emperor Nicholas I. Fully aware that he
was regularly and systematically deceived by the ordinary
officials, he formed a body of well-paid officers, called the
gendarmerie, who were scattered over the country, and ordered to
report directly to his Majesty whatever seemed to them worthy of
attention. Bureaucratic minds considered this an admirable
expedient; and the Tsar confidently expected that he would, by
means of these official observers who had no interest in concealing
the truth, be able to know everything, and to correct all official
abuses. In reality the institution produced few good results, and
in some respects had a very pernicious influence. Though picked
men and provided with good salaries, these officers were all more
or less permeated with the prevailing spirit. They could not but
feel that they were regarded as spies and informers--a humiliating
conviction, little calculated to develop that feeling of self-
respect which is the main foundation of uprightness--and that all
their efforts could do but little good. They were, in fact, in
pretty much the same position as Peter's Procurator-General, and,
with true Russian bonhomie, they disliked ruining individuals who
were no worse than the majority of their fellows. Besides this,
according to the received code of official morality insubordination
was a more heinous sin than dishonesty, and political offences were
regarded as the blackest of all. The gendarmerie officers shut
their eyes, therefore, to the prevailing abuses, which were
believed to be incurable, and directed their attention to real or
imaginary political delinquencies. Oppression and extortion
remained unnoticed, whilst an incautious word or a foolish joke at
the expense of the Government was too often magnified into an act
of high treason.
This force still exists under a slightly modified form. Towards
the close of the reign of Alexander II. (1880), when Count Loris
Melikof, with the sanction and approval of his august master, was
preparing to introduce a system of liberal political reforms, it
was intended to abolish the gendarmerie as an organ of political
espionage, and accordingly the direction of it was transferred from
the so-called Third Section of his Imperial Majesty's Chancery to
the Ministry of the Interior; but when the benevolent monarch was a
few months afterwards assassinated by revolutionists, the project
was naturally abandoned, and the Corps of Gendarmes, while
remaining nominally under the Minister of the Interior, was
practically reinstated in its former position. Now, as then, it
serves as a kind of supplement to the ordinary police, and is
generally employed for matters in which secrecy is required.
Unfortunately it is not bound by those legal restrictions which
protect the public against the arbitrary will of the ordinary
authorities. In addition to its regular duties it has a vaguely
defined roving commission to watch and arrest all persons who seem
to it in any way dangerous or suspectes, and it may keep such in
confinement for an indefinite time, or remove them to some distant
and inhospitable part of the Empire, without making them undergo a
regular trial. It is, in short, the ordinary instrument for
punishing political dreamers, suppressing secret societies,
counteracting political agitations, and in general executing the
extra-legal orders of the Government.
My relations with this anomalous branch of the administration were
somewhat peculiar. After my experience with the Vice-Governor of
Novgorod I determined to place myself above suspicion, and
accordingly applied to the "Chef des Gendarmes" for some kind of
official document which would prove to all officials with whom I
might come in contact that I had no illicit designs. My request
was granted, and I was furnished with the necessary documents; but
I soon found that in seeking to avoid Scylla I had fallen into
Charybdis. In calming official suspicions, I inadvertently aroused
suspicions of another kind. The documents proving that I enjoyed
the protection of the Government made many people suspect that I
was an emissary of the gendarmerie, and greatly impeded me in my
efforts to collect information from private sources. As the
private were for me more important than the official sources of
information, I refrained from asking for a renewal of the
protection, and wandered about the country as an ordinary
unprotected traveller. For some time I had no cause to regret this
decision. I knew that I was pretty closely watched, and that my
letters were occasionally opened in the post-office, but I was
subjected to no further inconvenience. At last, when I had nearly
forgotten all about Scylla and Charybdis, I one night unexpectedly
ran upon the former, and, to my astonishment, found myself formally
arrested! The incident happened in this wise.
I had been visiting Austria and Servia, and after a short absence
returned to Russia through Moldavia. On arriving at the Pruth,
which there forms the frontier, I found an officer of gendarmerie,
whose duty it was to examine the passports of all passers-by.
Though my passport was completely en regle, having been duly vise
by the British and Russian Consuls at Galatz, this gentleman
subjected me to a searching examination regarding my past life,
actual occupation, and intentions for the future. On learning that
I had been for more than two years travelling in Russia at my own
expense, for the simple purpose of collecting miscellaneous
information, he looked incredulous, and seemed to have some doubts
as to my being a genuine British subject; but when my statements
were confirmed by my travelling companion, a Russian friend who
carried awe-inspiring credentials, he countersigned my passport,
and allowed us to depart. The inspection of our luggage by the
custom-house officers was soon got over; and as we drove off to the
neighbouring village where we were to spend the night we
congratulated ourselves on having escaped for some time from all
contact with the official world. In this we were "reckoning
without the host." As the clock struck twelve that night I was
roused by a loud knocking at my door, and after a good deal of
parley, during which some one proposed to effect an entrance by
force, I drew the bolt. The officer who had signed my passport
entered, and said, in a stiff, official tone, "I must request you
to remain here for twenty-four hours."
Not a little astonished by this announcement, I ventured to inquire
the reason for this strange request.
"That is my business," was the laconic reply.
"Perhaps it is; still you must, on mature consideration, admit that
I too have some interest in the matter. To my extreme regret I
cannot comply with your request, and must leave at sunrise."
"You shall not leave. Give me your passport."
"Unless detained by force, I shall start at four o'clock; and as I
wish to get some sleep before that time, I must request you
instantly to retire. You had the right to stop me at the frontier,
but you have no right to come and disturb me in this fashion, and I
shall certainly report you. My passport I shall give to none but a
regular officer of police."
Here followed a long discussion on the rights, privileges, and
general character of the gendarmerie, during which my opponent
gradually laid aside his dictatorial tone, and endeavoured to
convince me that the honourable body to which he belonged was
merely an ordinary branch of the administration. Though evidently
irritated, he never, I must say, overstepped the bounds of
politeness, and seemed only half convinced that he was justified in
interfering with my movements. When he found that he could not
induce me to give up my passport, he withdrew, and I again lay down
to rest; but in about half an hour I was again disturbed. This
time an officer of regular police entered, and demanded my
"papers." To my inquiries as to the reason of all this
disturbance, he replied, in a very polite, apologetic way, that he
knew nothing about the reason, but he had received orders to arrest
me, and must obey. To him I delivered my passport, on condition
that I should receive a written receipt, and should be allowed to
telegraph to the British ambassador in St. Petersburg.
Early next morning I telegraphed to the ambassador, and waited
impatiently all day for a reply. I was allowed to walk about the
village and the immediate vicinity, but of this permission I did
not make much use. The village population was entirely Jewish, and
Jews in that part of the world have a wonderful capacity for
spreading intelligence. By the early morning there was probably
not a man, woman, or child in the place who had not heard of my
arrest, and many of them felt a not unnatural curiosity to see the
malefactor who had been caught by the police. To be stared at as a
malefactor is not very agreeable, so I preferred to remain in my
room, where, in the company of my friend, who kindly remained with
me and made small jokes about the boasted liberty of British
subjects, I spent the time pleasantly enough. The most
disagreeable part of the affair was the uncertainty as to how many
days, weeks, or months I might be detained, and on this point the
police-officer would not even hazard a conjecture.
The detention came to an end sooner than I expected. On the
following day--that is to say, about thirty-six hours after the
nocturnal visit--the police-officer brought me my passport, and at
the same time a telegram from the British Embassy informed me that
the central authorities had ordered my release. On my afterwards
pertinaciously requesting an explanation of the unceremonious
treatment to which I had been subjected, the Minister for Foreign
Affairs declared that the authorities expected a person of my name
to cross the frontier about that time with a quantity of false
bank-notes, and that I had been arrested by mistake. I must
confess that this explanation, though official, seemed to me more
ingenious than satisfactory, but I was obliged to accept it for
what it was worth. At a later period I had again the misfortune to
attract the attention of the secret police, but I reserve the
incident till I come to speak of my relations with the
revolutionists.
From all I have seen and heard of the gendarmerie I am disposed to
believe that the officers are for the most part polite, well-
educated men, who seek to fulfil their disagreeable duties in as
inoffensive a way as possible. It must, however, be admitted that
they are generally regarded with suspicion and dislike, even by
those people who fear the attempts at revolutionary propaganda
which it is the special duty of the gendarmerie to discover and
suppress. Nor need this surprise us. Though very many people
believe in the necessity of capital punishment, there are few who
do not feel a decided aversion to the public executioner.
The only effectual remedy for administrative abuses lies in placing
the administration under public control. This has been abundantly
proved in Russia. All the efforts of the Tsars during many
generations to check the evil by means of ingenious bureaucratic
devices proved utterly fruitless. Even the iron will and gigantic
energy of Nicholas I. were insufficient for the task. But when,
after the Crimean War, there was a great moral awakening, and the
Tsar called the people to his assistance, the stubborn, deep-rooted
evils immediately disappeared. For a time venality and extortion
were unknown, and since that period they have never been able to
regain their old force.
At the present moment it cannot be said that the administration is
immaculate, but it is incomparably purer than it was in old times.
Though public opinion is no longer so powerful as it was in the
early sixties, it is still strong enough to repress many
malpractices which in the time of Nicholas I. and his predecessors
were too frequent to attract attention. On this subject I shall
have more to say hereafter.
If administrative abuses are rife in the Empire of the Tsars, it is
not from any want of carefully prepared laws. In no country in the
world, perhaps, is the legislation more voluminous, and in theory,
not only the officials, but even the Tsar himself, must obey the
laws he has sanctioned, like the meanest of his subjects. This is
one of those cases, not infrequent in Russia, in which theory
differs somewhat from practice. In real life the Emperor may at
any moment override the law by means of what is called a Supreme
Command (vysotchaishiye povelenie), and a minister may "interpret"
a law in any way he pleases by means of a circular. This is a
frequent cause of complaint even among those who wish to uphold the
Autocratic Power. In their opinion law-respecting autocracy
wielded by a strong Tsar is an excellent institution for Russia; it
is arbitrary autocracy wielded by irresponsible ministers that they
object to.
As Englishmen may have some difficulty in imagining how laws can
come into being without a Parliament or Legislative Chamber of some
sort, I shall explain briefly how they are manufactured by the
Russian bureaucratic machine without the assistance of
representative institutions.
When a minister considers that some institution in his branch of
the service requires to be reformed, he begins by submitting to the
Emperor a formal report on the matter. If the Emperor agrees with
his minister as to the necessity for reform, he orders a Commission
to be appointed for the purpose of considering the subject and
preparing a definite legislative project. The Commission meets and
sets to work in what seems a very thorough way. It first studies
the history of the institution in Russia from the earliest times
downwards--or rather, it listens to an essay on the subject,
especially prepared for the occasion by some official who has a
taste for historical studies, and can write in a pleasant style.
The next step--to use a phrase which often occurs in the minutes of
such commissions--consists in "shedding the light of science on the
question" (prolit' na dyelo svet nauki). This important operation
is performed by preparing a memorial containing the history of
similar institutions in foreign countries, and an elaborate
exposition of numerous theories held by French and German
philosophical jurists. In these memorials it is often considered
necessary to include every European country except Turkey, and
sometimes the small German States and principal Swiss cantons are
treated separately.
To illustrate the character of these wonderful productions, let me
give an example. From a pile of such papers lying before me I take
one almost at random. It is a memorial relating to a proposed
reform of benevolent institutions. First I find a philosophical
disquisition on benevolence in general; next, some remarks on the
Talmud and the Koran; then a reference to the treatment of paupers
in Athens after the Peloponnesian War, and in Rome under the
emperors: then some vague observations on the Middle Ages, with a
quotation that was evidently intended to be Latin; lastly, comes an
account of the poor-laws of modern times, in which I meet with "the
Anglo-Saxon domination," King Egbert, King Ethelred, "a remarkable
book of Icelandic laws, called Hragas"; Sweden and Norway, France,
Holland, Belgium, Prussia, and nearly all the minor German States.
The most wonderful thing is that all this mass of historical
information, extending from the Talmud to the most recent
legislation of Hesse-Darmstadt, is compressed into twenty-one
octavo pages! The doctrinal part of the memorandum is not less
rich. Many respected names from the literature of Germany, France,
and England are forcibly dragged in; and the general conclusion
drawn from this mass of raw, undigested materials is believed to be
"the latest results of science."
Does the reader suspect that I have here chosen an extremely
exceptional case? If so, let us take the next paper in the file.
It refers to a project of law regarding imprisonment for debt. On
the first page I find references to "the Salic laws of the fifth
century," and the "Assises de Jerusalem, A.D 1099." That, I think,
will suffice. Let us pass, then, to the next step.
When the quintessence of human wisdom and experience has thus been
extracted, the commission considers how the valuable product may be
applied to Russia, so as to harmonise with the existing general
conditions and local peculiarities. For a man of practical mind
this is, of course, the most interesting and most important part of
the operation, but from Russian legislators it receives
comparatively little attention. Very often have I turned to this
section of official papers in order to obtain information regarding
the actual state of the country, and in every case I have been
grievously disappointed. Vague general phrases, founded on a
priori reasoning rather than on observation, together with a few
statistical tables--which the cautious investigator should avoid as
he would an ambuscade--are too often all that is to be found.
Through the thin veil of pseudo-erudition the real facts are clear
enough. These philosophical legislators, who have spent their
lives in the official atmosphere of St. Petersburg, know as much
about Russia as the genuine cockney knows about Great Britain, and
in this part of their work they derive no assistance from the
learned German treatises which supply an unlimited amount of
historical facts and philosophical speculation.
From the commission the project passes to the Council of State,
where it is certainly examined and criticised, and perhaps
modified, but it is not likely to be improved from the practical
point of view, because the members of the Council are merely ci-
devant members of similar commissions, hardened by a few additional
years of official routine. The Council is, in fact, an assembly of
tchinovniks who know little of the practical, everyday wants of the
unofficial classes. No merchant, manufacturer, or farmer ever
enters its sacred precincts, so that its bureaucratic serenity is
rarely disturbed by practical objections. It is not surprising,
therefore, that it has been known to pass laws which were found at
once to be absolutely unworkable.
From the Council of State the Bill is taken to the Emperor, and he
generally begins by examining the signatures. The "Ayes" are in
one column and the "Noes" in another. If his Majesty is not
specially acquainted with the matter--and he cannot possibly be
acquainted with all the matters submitted to him--he usually signs
with the majority, or on the side where he sees the names of
officials in whose judgment he has special confidence; but if he
has strong views of his own, he places his signature in whichever
column he thinks fit, and it outweighs the signatures of any number
of Councillors. Whatever side he supports, that side "has it," and
in this way a small minority may be transformed into a majority.
When the important question, for example, as to how far classics
should be taught in the ordinary schools was considered by the
Council, it is said that only two members signed in favour of
classical education, which was excessively unpopular at the moment,
but the Emperor Alexander III., disregarding public opinion and the
advice of his Councillors, threw his signature into the lighter
scale, and the classicists were victorious.
CHAPTER XXV
MOSCOW AND THE SLAVOPHILS
Two Ancient Cities--Kief Not a Good Point for Studying Old Russian
National Life--Great Russians and Little Russians--Moscow--Easter
Eve in the Kremlin--Curious Custom--Anecdote of the Emperor
Nicholas--Domiciliary Visits of the Iberian Madonna--The Streets of
Moscow--Recent Changes in the Character of the City--Vulgar
Conception of the Slavophils--Opinion Founded on Personal
Acquaintance--Slavophil Sentiment a Century Ago--Origin and
Development of the Slavophil Doctrine--Slavophilism Essentially
Muscovite--The Panslavist Element--The Slavophils and the
Emancipation.
In the last chapter, as in many of the preceding ones, the reader
must have observed that at one moment there was a sudden break,
almost a solution of continuity, in Russian national life. The
Tsardom of Muscovy, with its ancient Oriental costumes and
Byzantine traditions, unexpectedly disappears, and the Russian
Empire, clad in modern garb and animated with the spirit of modern
progress, steps forward uninvited into European history. Of the
older civilisation, if civilisation it can be called, very little
survived the political transformation, and that little is generally
supposed to hover ghostlike around Kief and Moscow. To one or
other of these towns, therefore, the student who desires to learn
something of genuine old Russian life, untainted by foreign
influences, naturally wends his way. For my part I thought first
of settling for a time in Kief, the oldest and most revered of
Russian cities, where missionaries from Byzantium first planted
Christianity on Russian soil, and where thousands of pilgrims still
assemble yearly from far and near to prostrate themselves before
the Holy Icons in the churches and to venerate the relics of the
blessed saints and martyrs in the catacombs of the great monastery.
I soon discovered, however, that Kief, though it represents in a
certain sense the Byzantine traditions so dear to the Russian
people, is not a good point of observation for studying the Russian
character. It was early exposed to the ravages of the nomadic
tribes of the Steppe, and when it was liberated from those
incursions it was seized by the Poles and Lithuanians, and remained
for centuries under their domination. Only in comparatively recent
times did it begin to recover its Russian character--a university
having been created there for that purpose after the Polish
insurrection of 1830. Even now the process of Russification is far
from complete, and the Russian elements in the population are far
from being pure in the nationalist sense. The city and the
surrounding country are, in fact, Little Russian rather than Great
Russian, and between these two sections of the population there are
profound differences--differences of language, costume, traditions,
popular songs, proverbs, folk-lore, domestic arrangements, mode of
life, and Communal organisation. In these and other respects the
Little Russians, South Russians, Ruthenes, or Khokhly, as they are
variously designated, differ from the Great Russians of the North,
who form the predominant factor in the Empire, and who have given
to that wonderful structure its essential characteristics. Indeed,
if I did not fear to ruffle unnecessarily the patriotic
susceptibilities of my Great Russian friends who have a pet theory
on this subject, I should say that we have here two distinct
nationalities, further apart from each other than the English and
the Scotch. The differences are due, I believe, partly to
ethnographical peculiarities and partly to historic conditions.
As it was the energetic Great Russian empire-builders and not the
half-dreamy, half-astute, sympathetic descendants of the Free
Cossacks that I wanted to study, I soon abandoned my idea of
settling in the Holy City on the Dnieper, and chose Moscow as my
point of observation; and here, during several years, I spent
regularly some of the winter months.
The first few weeks of my stay in the ancient capital of the Tsars
were spent in the ordinary manner of intelligent tourists. After
mastering the contents of a guide-book I carefully inspected all
the officially recognised objects of interest--the Kremlin, with
its picturesque towers and six centuries of historical
associations; the Cathedrals, containing the venerated tombs of
martyrs, saints, and Tsars; the old churches, with their quaint,
archaic, richly decorated Icons; the "Patriarchs' Treasury," rich
in jewelled ecclesiastical vestments and vessels of silver and
gold; the ancient and the modern palace; the Ethnological Museum,
showing the costumes and physiognomy of all the various races in
the Empire; the archaeological collections, containing many objects
that recall the barbaric splendour of old Muscovy; the picture-
gallery, with Ivanof's gigantic picture, in which patriotic Russian
critics discover occult merits which place it above anything that
Western Europe has yet produced! Of course I climbed up to the top
of the tall belfry which rejoices in the name of "Ivan the Great,"
and looked down on the "gilded domes"* of the churches, and bright
green roofs of the houses, and far away, beyond these, the gently
undulating country with the "Sparrow Hills," from which Napoleon is
said, in cicerone language, to have "gazed upon the doomed city."
Occasionally I walked about the bazaars in the hope of finding
interesting specimens of genuine native art-industry, and was
urgently invited to purchase every conceivable article which I did
not want. At midday or in the evening I visited the most noted
traktirs, and made the acquaintance of the caviar, sturgeons,
sterlets, and other native delicacies for which these institutions
are famous--deafened the while by the deep tones of the colossal
barrel-organ, out of all proportion to the size of the room; and in
order to see how the common people spent their evenings I looked in
at some of the more modest traktirs, and gazed with wonder, not
unmixed with fear, at the enormous quantity of weak tea which the
inmates consumed.
* Allowance must be made here for poetical licence. In reality,
very few of the domes are gilt. The great majority of them are
painted green, like the roofs of the houses.
Since these first weeks of my sojourn in Moscow more than thirty
years have passed, and many of my early impressions have been
blurred by time, but one scene remains deeply graven on my memory.
It was Easter Eve, and I had gone with a friend to the Kremlin to
witness the customary religious ceremonies. Though the rain was
falling heavily, an immense number of people had assembled in and
around the Cathedral of the Assumption. The crowd was of the most
mixed kind. There stood the patient bearded muzhik in his well-
worn sheepskin; the big, burly, self-satisfied merchant in his long
black glossy kaftan; the noble with fashionable great-coat and
umbrella; thinly clad old women shivering in the cold, and bright-
eyed young damsels with their warm cloaks drawn closely round them;
old men with long beard, wallet, and pilgrim's staff; and
mischievous urchins with faces for the moment preternaturally
demure. Each right hand, of old and young alike, held a lighted
taper, and these myriads of flickering little flames produced a
curious illumination, giving to the surrounding buildings a weird
picturesqueness which they do not possess in broad daylight. All
stood patiently waiting for the announcement of the glad tidings:
"He is risen!" As midnight approached, the hum of voices gradually
ceased, till, as the clock struck twelve, the deep-toned bell on
"Ivan the Great" began to toll, and in answer to this signal all
the bells in Moscow suddenly sent forth a merry peal. Each bell--
and their name is legion--seemed frantically desirous of drowning
its neighbour's voice, the solemn boom of the great one overhead
mingling curiously with the sharp, fussy "ting-a-ting-ting" of
diminutive rivals. If demons dwell in Moscow and dislike bell-
ringing, as is generally supposed, then there must have been at
that moment a general stampede of the powers of darkness such as is
described by Milton in his poem on the Nativity, and as if this
deafening din were not enough, big guns were fired in rapid
succession from a battery of artillery close at hand! The noise
seemed to stimulate the religious enthusiasm, and the general
excitement had a wonderful effect on a Russian friend who
accompanied me. When in his normal condition that gentleman was a
quiet, undemonstrative person, devoted to science, an ardent
adherent of Western civilisation in general and of Darwinism in
particular, and a thorough sceptic with regard to all forms of
religious belief; but the influence of the surroundings was too
much for his philosophical equanimity. For a moment his orthodox
Muscovite soul awoke from its sceptical, cosmopolitan lethargy.
After crossing himself repeatedly--an act of devotion which I had
never before seen him perform--he grasped my arm, and, pointing to
the crowd, said in an exultant tone of voice, "Look there! There
is a sight that you can see nowhere but in the 'White-stone City.'*
Are not the Russians a religious people?"
*Belokamenny, meaning "of white stone," is one of the popular names
of Moscow.
To this unexpected question I gave a monosyllabic assent, and
refrained from disturbing my friend's new-born enthusiasm by any
discordant note; but I must confess that this sudden outburst of
deafening noise and the dazzling light aroused in my heretical
breast feelings of a warlike rather than a religious kind. For a
moment I could imagine myself in ancient Moscow, and could fancy
the people being called out to repel a Tartar horde already
thundering at the gates!
The service lasted two or three hours, and terminated with the
curious ceremony of blessing the Easter cakes, which were ranged--
each one with a lighted taper stuck in it--in long rows outside of
the cathedral. A not less curious custom practised at this season
is that of exchanging kisses of fraternal love. Theoretically one
ought to embrace and be embraced by all present--indicating thereby
that all are brethren in Christ--but the refinements of modern life
have made innovations in the practice, and most people confine
their salutations to their friends and acquaintances. When two
friends meet during that night or on the following day, the one
says, "Christos voskres!" ("Christ hath risen!"); and the other
replies, "Vo istine voskres!" ("In truth he hath risen!"). They
then kiss each other three times on the right and left cheek
alternately. The custom is more or less observed in all classes of
society, and the Emperor himself conforms to it.
This reminds me of an anecdote which is related of the Emperor
Nicholas I., tending to show that he was not so devoid of kindly
human feelings as his imperial and imperious exterior suggested.
On coming out of his cabinet one Easter morning he addressed to the
soldier who was mounting guard at the door the ordinary words of
salutation, "Christ hath risen!" and received instead of the
ordinary reply, a flat contradiction--"Not at all, your Imperial
Majesty!" Astounded by such an unexpected answer--for no one
ventured to dissent from Nicholas even in the most guarded and
respectful terms--he instantly demanded an explanation. The
soldier, trembling at his own audacity, explained that he was a
Jew, and could not conscientiously admit the fact of the
Resurrection. This boldness for conscience' sake so pleased the
Tsar that he gave the man a handsome Easter present.
A quarter of a century after the Easter Eve above mentioned--or, to
be quite accurate, on the 26th of May, 1896--I again find myself in
the Kremlin on the occasion of a great religious ceremony--a
ceremony which shows that "the White-stone City" on the Moskva is
still in some respects the capital of Holy Russia. This time my
post of observation is inside the cathedral, which is artistically
draped with purple hangings and crowded with the most distinguished
personages of the Empire, all arrayed in gorgeous apparel--Grand
Dukes and Grand Duchesses, Imperial Highnesses and High
Excellencies, Metropolitans and Archbishops, Senators and
Councillors of State, Generals and Court dignitaries. In the
centre of the building, on a high, richly decorated platform, sits
the Emperor with his Imperial Consort, and his mother, the widowed
Consort of Alexander III. Though Nicholas II. has not the colossal
stature which has distinguished so many of the Romanofs, he is well
built, holds himself erect, and shows a quiet dignity in his
movements; while his face, which resembles that of his cousin, the
Prince of Wales, wears a kindly, sympathetic expression. The
Empress looks even more than usually beautiful, in a low dress cut
in the ancient fashion, her thick brown hair, dressed most simply
without jewellery or other ornaments, falling in two long ringlets
over her white shoulders. For the moment, her attire is much
simpler than that of the Empress Dowager, who wears a diamond crown
and a great mantle of gold brocade, lined and edged with ermine,
the long train displaying in bright-coloured embroidery the
heraldic double-headed eagle of the Imperial arms.
Each of these august personages sits on a throne of curious
workmanship, consecrated by ancient historic associations. That of
the Emperor, the gift of the Shah of Persia to Ivan the Terrible,
and commonly called the Throne of Tsar Michael, the founder of the
Romanof dynasty, is covered with gold plaques, and studded with
hundreds of big, roughly cut precious stones, mostly rubies,
emeralds, and turquoises. Of still older date is the throne of the
young Empress, for it was given by Pope Paul II. to Tsar Ivan III.,
grandfather of the Terrible, on the occasion of his marriage with a
niece of the last Byzantine Emperor. More recent but not less
curious is that of the Empress Dowager. It is the throne of Tsar
Alexis, the father of Peter the Great, covered with countless and
priceless diamonds, rubies, and pearls, and surmounted by an
Imperial eagle of solid gold, together with golden statuettes of
St. Peter and St. Nicholas, the miracle-worker. Over each throne
is a canopy of purple velvet fringed with gold, out of which rise
stately plumes representing the national colours.
Their Majesties have come hither, in accordance with time-honoured
custom, to be crowned in this old Cathedral of the Assumption, the
central point of the Kremlin, within a stone-throw of the Cathedral
of the Archangel Michael, in which lie the remains of the old Grand
Dukes and Tsars of Muscovy. Already the Emperor has read aloud, in
a clear, unfaltering voice, from a richly bound parchment folio,
held by the Metropolitan of St. Petersburg, the Orthodox creed; and
his Eminence, after invoking on his Majesty the blessing of the
Holy Spirit, has performed the mystic rite of placing his hands in
the form of a cross on the Imperial forehead. Thus all is ready
for the most important part of the solemn ceremony. Standing
erect, the Emperor doffs his small diadem and puts on with his own
hands the great diamond crown, offered respectfully by the
Metropolitan; then he reseats himself on his throne, holding in his
right hand the Sceptre and in his left the Orb of Dominion. After
sitting thus in state for a few minutes, he stands up and proceeds
to crown his august spouse, kneeling before him. First he touches
her forehead with his own crown, and then he places on her head a
smaller one, which is immediately attached to her hair by four
ladies-in-waiting, dressed in the old Muscovite Court-costume. At
the same time her Majesty is invested with a mantle of heavy gold
brocade, similar to those of the Emperor and Empress Dowager, lined
and bordered with ermine.
Thus crowned and robed their Majesties sit in state, while a proto-
deacon reads, in a loud stentorian voice, the long list of sonorous
hereditary titles belonging of right to the Imperator and Autocrat
of all the Russias, and the choir chants a prayer invoking long
life and happiness--"Many years! Many years! Many years!"--on the
high and mighty possessor of the titles aforesaid. And now begins
the Mass, celebrated with a pomp and magnificence that can be
witnessed only once or twice in a generation. Sixty gorgeously
robed ecclesiastical dignitaries of the highest orders fulfil their
various functions with due solemnity and unction; but the
magnificence of the vestments and the pomp of the ceremonial are
soon forgotten in the exquisite solemnising music, as the deep
double-bass tones of the adult singers in the background--carefully
selected for the occasion in all parts of the Empire--peal forth as
from a great organ, and blend marvellously with the clear, soft,
gentle notes of the red-robed chorister boys in front of the
Iconostase. Listening with intense emotion, I involuntarily recall
to mind Fra Angelico's pictures of angelic choirs, and cannot help
thinking that the pious old Florentine, whose soul was attuned to
all that was sacred and beautiful, must have heard in imagination
such music as this. So strong is the impression that the
subsequent details of the long ceremony, including the anointing
with the holy chrism, fail to engrave themselves on my memory. One
incident, however, remains; and if it had happened in an earlier
and more superstitious age it would doubtless have been chronicled
as an omen full of significance. As the Emperor is on the point of
descending from the dais, duly crowned and anointed, a staggering
ray of sunshine steals through one of the narrow upper windows and,
traversing the dimly lit edifice, falls full on the Imperial crown,
lighting up for a moment the great mass of diamonds with a
hundredfold brilliance.
In a detailed account of the Coronation which I wrote on leaving
the Kremlin, I find the following: "The magnificent ceremony is at
an end, and now Nicholas II. is the crowned Emperor and anointed
Autocrat of all the Russias. May the cares of Empire rest lightly
on him! That must be the earnest prayer of every loyal subject and
every sincere well-wisher, for of all living mortals he is perhaps
the one who has been entrusted by Providence with the greatest
power and the greatest responsibilities." In writing those words I
did not foresee how heavy his responsibilities would one day weigh
upon him, when his Empire would be sorely tried, by foreign war and
internal discontent.
One more of these old Moscow reminiscences, and I have done. A day
or two after the Coronation I saw the Khodinskoye Polye, a great
plain in the outskirts of Moscow, strewn with hundreds of corpses!
During the previous night enormous crowds from the city and the
surrounding districts had collected here in order to receive at
sunrise, by the Tsar's command, a little memento of the coronation
ceremony, in the form of a packet containing a metal cup and a few
eatables; and as day dawned, in their anxiety to get near the row
of booths from which the distribution was to be made, about two
thousand had been crushed to death. It was a sight more horrible
than a battlefield, because among the dead were a large proportion
of women and children, terribly mutilated in the struggle.
Altogether, "a sight to shudder at, not to see!"
To return to the remark of my friend in the Kremlin on Easter Eve,
the Russians in general, and the Muscovites in particular, as the
quintessence of all that is Russian, are certainly a religious
people, but their piety sometimes finds modes of expression which
rather shock the Protestant mind. As an instance of these, I may
mention the domiciliary visits of the Iberian Madonna. This
celebrated Icon, for reasons which I have never heard
satisfactorily explained, is held in peculiar veneration by the
Muscovites, and occupies in popular estimation a position analogous
to the tutelary deities of ancient pagan cities. Thus when
Napoleon was about to enter the city in 1812, the populace
clamorously called upon the Metropolitan to take the Madonna, and
lead them out armed with hatchets against the hosts of the infidel;
and when the Tsar visits Moscow he generally drives straight from
the railway-station to the little chapel where the Icon resides--
near one of the entrances to the Kremlin--and there offers up a
short prayer. Every Orthodox Russian, as he passes this chapel,
uncovers and crosses himself, and whenever a religious service is
performed in it there is always a considerable group of
worshippers. Some of the richer inhabitants, however, are not
content with thus performing their devotions in public before the
Icon. They like to have it from time to time in their houses, and
the ecclesiastical authorities think fit to humour this strange
fancy. Accordingly every morning the Iberian Madonna may be seen
driving about the city from one house to another in a carriage and
four! The carriage may be at once recognised, not from any
peculiarity in its structure, for it is an ordinary close carriage
such as may be obtained at livery stables, but by the fact that the
coachman sits bare-headed, and all the people in the street uncover
and cross themselves as it passes. Arrived at the house to which
it has been invited, the Icon is carried through all the rooms, and
in the principal apartment a short religious service is performed
before it. As it is being brought in or taken away, female
servants may sometimes be seen to kneel on the floor so that it may
be carried over them. During its absence from its chapel it is
replaced by a copy not easily distinguishable from the original,
and thus the devotions of the faithful and the flow of pecuniary
contributions do not suffer interruption. These contributions,
together with the sums paid for the domiciliary visits, amount to a
considerable yearly sum, and go--if I am rightly informed--to swell
the revenues of the Metropolitan.
A single drive or stroll through Moscow will suffice to convince
the traveller, even if he knows nothing of Russian history, that
the city is not, like its modern rival on the Neva, the artificial
creation of a far-seeing, self-willed autocrat, but rather a
natural product which has grown up slowly and been modified
according to the constantly changing wants of the population. A
few of the streets have been Europeanised--in all except the
paving, which is everywhere execrably Asiatic--to suit the tastes
of those who have adopted European culture, but the great majority
of them still retain much of their ancient character and primitive
irregularity. As soon as we diverge from the principal
thoroughfares, we find one-storied houses--some of them still of
wood--which appear to have been transported bodily from the
country, with courtyard, garden, stables, and other appurtenances.
The whole is no doubt a little compressed, for land has here a
certain value, but the character is in no way changed, and we have
some difficulty in believing that we are not in the suburbs but
near the centre of a great town. There is nothing that can by any
possibility be called street architecture. Though there is
unmistakable evidence of the streets having been laid out according
to a preconceived plan, many of them show clearly that in their
infancy they had a wayward will of their own, and bent to the right
or left without any topographical justification. The houses, too,
display considerable individuality of character, having evidently
during the course of their construction paid no attention to their
neighbours. Hence we find no regularly built terraces, crescents,
or squares. There is, it is true, a double circle of boulevards,
but the houses which flank them have none of that regularity which
we commonly associate with the term. Dilapidated buildings which
in West-European cities would hide themselves in some narrow lane
or back slum here stand composedly in the face of day by the side
of a palatial residence, without having the least consciousness of
the incongruity of their position, just as the unsophisticated
muzhik, in his unsavoury sheepskin, can stand in the midst of a
crowd of well-dressed people without feeling at all awkward or
uncomfortable.
All this incongruity, however, is speedily disappearing. Moscow
has become the centre of a great network of railways, and the
commercial and industrial capital of the Empire. Already her
rapidly increasing population has nearly reached a million.* The
value of land and property is being doubled and trebled, and
building speculations, with the aid of credit institutions of
various kinds, are being carried on with feverish rapidity. Well
may the men of the old school complain that the world is turned
upside down, and regret the old times of traditional somnolence and
comfortable routine! Those good old times are gone now, never to
return. The ancient capital, which long gloried in its past
historical associations, now glories in its present commercial
prosperity, and looks forward with confidence to the future. Even
the Slavophils, the obstinate champions of the ultra-Muscovite
spirit, have changed with the times, and descended to the level of
ordinary prosaic life. These men, who formerly spent years in
seeking to determine the place of Moscow in the past and future
history of humanity, have--to their honour be it said--become in
these latter days town-counsellors, and have devoted much of their
time to devising ways and means of improving the drainage and the
street-paving! But I am anticipating in a most unjustifiable way.
I ought first to tell the reader who these Slavophils were, and why
they sought to correct the commonly received conceptions of
universal history.
* According to the census of 1897 it was 988,610.
The reader may have heard of the Slavophils as a set of fanatics
who, about half a century ago, were wont to go about in what they
considered the ancient Russian costume, who wore beards in defiance
of Peter the Great's celebrated ukaz and Nicholas's clearly-
expressed wish anent shaving, who gloried in Muscovite barbarism,
and had solemnly "sworn a feud" against European civilisation and
enlightenment. By the tourists of the time who visited Moscow they
were regarded as among the most noteworthy lions of the place, and
were commonly depicted in not very flattering colours. At the
beginning of the Crimean War they were among the extreme
Chauvinists who urged the necessity of planting the Greek cross on
the desecrated dome of St. Sophia in Constantinople, and hoped to
see the Emperor proclaimed "Panslavonic Tsar"; and after the
termination of the war they were frequently accused of inventing
Turkish atrocities, stirring up discontent among the Slavonic
subjects of the Sultan, and secretly plotting for the overthrow of
the Ottoman Empire. All this was known to me before I went to
Russia, and I had consequently invested the Slavophils with a halo
of romance. Shortly after my arrival in St. Petersburg I heard
something more which tended to increase my interest in them--they
had caused, I was told, great trepidation among the highest
official circles by petitioning the Emperor to resuscitate a
certain ancient institution, called Zemskiye Sobory, which might be
made to serve the purposes of a parliament! This threw a new light
upon them--under the disguise of archaeological conservatives they
were evidently aiming at important liberal reforms.
As a foreigner and a heretic, I expected a very cold and distant
reception from these uncompromising champions of Russian
nationality and the Orthodox faith; but in this I was agreeably
disappointed. By all of them I was received in the most amiable
and friendly way, and I soon discovered that my preconceived ideas
of them were very far from the truth. Instead of wild fanatics I
found quiet, extremely intelligent, highly educated gentlemen,
speaking foreign languages with ease and elegance, and deeply
imbued with that Western culture which they were commonly supposed
to despise. And this first impression was amply confirmed by
subsequent experience during several years of friendly intercourse.
They always showed themselves men of earnest character and strong
convictions, but they never said or did anything that could justify
the appellation of fanatics. Like all philosophical theorists,
they often allowed their logic to blind them to facts, but their
reasonings were very plausible--so plausible, indeed, that, had I
been a Russian they would have almost persuaded me to be a
Slavophil, at least during the time they were talking to me.
To understand their doctrine we must know something of its origin
and development.
The origin of the Slavophil sentiment, which must not be confounded
with the Slavophil doctrine, is to be sought in the latter half of
the seventeenth century, when the Tsars of Muscovy were introducing
innovations in Church and State. These innovations were profoundly
displeasing to the people. A large portion of the lower classes,
as I have related in a previous chapter, sought refuge in Old
Ritualism or sectarianism, and imagined that Tsar Peter, who called
himself by the heretical title of "Imperator," was an emanation of
the Evil Principle. The nobles did not go quite so far. They
remained members of the official Church, and restricted themselves
to hinting that Peter was the son, not of Satan, but of a German
surgeon--a lineage which, according to the conceptions of the time,
was a little less objectionable; but most of them were very hostile
to the changes, and complained bitterly of the new burdens which
these changes entailed. Under Peter's immediate successors, when
not only the principles of administration but also many of the
administrators were German, this hostility greatly increased.
So long as the innovations appeared only in the official activity
of the Government, the patriotic, conservative spirit was obliged
to keep silence; but when the foreign influence spread to the
social life of the Court aristocracy, the opposition began to find
a literary expression. In the time of Catherine II., when
Gallomania was at its height in Court circles, comedies and
satirical journals ridiculed those who, "blinded by some externally
brilliant gifts of foreigners, not only prefer foreign countries to
their native land, but even despise their fellow-countrymen, and
think that a Russian ought to borrow all--even personal character.
As if nature arranging all things with such wisdom, and bestowing
on all regions the gifts and customs which are appropriate to the
climate, had been so unjust as to refuse to the Russians a
character of their own! As if she condemned them to wander over
all regions, and to adopt by bits the various customs of various
nations, in order to compose out of the mixture a new character
appropriate to no nation whatever!" Numerous passages of this kind
might be quoted, attacking the "monkeyism" and "parrotism" of those
who indiscriminately adopted foreign manners and customs--those who
"Sauntered Europe round,
And gathered ev'ry vice in ev'ry ground."
Sometimes the terms and metaphors employed were more forcible than
refined. One satirical journal, for instance, relates an amusing
story about certain little Russian pigs that went to foreign lands
to enlighten their understanding, and came back to their country
full-grown swine. The national pride was wounded by the thought
that Russians could be called "clever apes who feed on foreign
intelligence," and many writers, stung by such reproaches, fell
into the opposite extreme, discovering unheard-of excellences in
the Russian mind and character, and vociferously decrying
everything foreign in order to place these imagined excellences in
a stronger light by contrast. Even when they recognised that their
country was not quite so advanced in civilisation as certain other
nations, they congratulated themselves on the fact, and invented by
way of justification an ingenious theory, which was afterwards
developed by the Slavophils. "The nations of the West," they said,
"began to live before us, and are consequently more advanced than
we are; but we have on that account no reason to envy them, for we
can profit by their errors, and avoid those deep-rooted evils from
which they are suffering. He who has just been born is happier
than he who is dying."
Thus, we see, a patriotic reaction against the introduction of
foreign institutions and the inordinate admiration of foreign
culture already existed in Russia more than a century ago. It did
not, however, take the form of a philosophical theory till a much
later period, when a similar movement was going on in various
countries of Western Europe.
After the overthrow of the great Napoleonic Empire a reaction
against cosmopolitanism took place and a romantic enthusiasm for
nationality spread over Europe like an epidemic. Blind,
enthusiastic patriotism became the fashionable sentiment of the
time. Each nation took to admiring itself complacently, to
praising its own character and achievements, and to idealising its
historical and mythical past. National peculiarities, "local
colour," ancient customs, traditional superstitions--in short,
everything that a nation believed to be specially and exclusively
its own, now raised an enthusiasm similar to that which had been
formerly excited by cosmopolitan conceptions founded on the law of
nature. The movement produced good and evil results. In serious
minds it led to a deep and conscientious study of history, national
literature, popular mythology, and the like; whilst in frivolous,
inflammable spirits it gave birth merely to a torrent of patriotic
fervour and rhetorical exaggeration. The Slavophils were the
Russian representatives of this nationalistic reaction, and
displayed both its serious and its frivolous elements.
Among the most important products of this movement in Germany was
the Hegelian theory of universal history. According to Hegel's
views, which were generally accepted by those who occupied
themselves with philosophical questions, universal history was
described as "Progress in the consciousness of freedom"
(Fortschritt im Bewusstsein der Freiheit). In each period of the
world's history, it was explained, some one nation or race had been
intrusted with the high mission of enabling the Absolute Reason, or
Weltgeist, to express itself in objective existence, while the
other nations and races had for the time no metaphysical
justification for their existence, and no higher duty than to
imitate slavishly the favoured rival in which the Weltgeist had for
the moment chosen to incorporate itself. The incarnation had taken
place first in the Eastern Monarchies, then in Greece, next in
Rome, and lastly in the Germanic race; and it was generally
assumed, if not openly asserted, that this mystical Metempsychosis
of the Absolute was now at an end. The cycle of existence was
complete. In the Germanic peoples the Weltgeist had found its
highest and final expression.
Russians in general knew nothing about German philosophy, and were
consequently not in any way affected by these ideas, but there was
in Moscow a small group of young men who ardently studied German
literature and metaphysics, and they were much shocked by Hegel's
views. Ever since the brilliant reign of Catherine II., who had
defeated the Turks and had dreamed of resuscitating the Byzantine
Empire, and especially since the memorable events of 1812-15, when
Alexander I. appeared as the liberator of enthralled Europe and the
arbiter of her destinies, Russians were firmly convinced that their
country was destined to play a most important part in human
history. Already the great Russian historian Karamzin had declared
that henceforth Clio must be silent or accord to Russia a prominent
place in the history of the nations. Now, by the Hegelian theory,
the whole of the Slav race was left out in the cold, with no high
mission, with no new truths to divulge, with nothing better to do,
in fact, than to imitate the Germans.
The patriotic philosophers of Moscow could not, of course, adopt
this view. Whilst accepting the fundamental principles, they
declared the theory to be incomplete. The incompleteness lay in
the assumption that humanity had already entered on the final
stages of its development. The Teutonic nations were perhaps for
the moment the leaders in the march of civilisation, but there was
no reason to suppose that they would always retain that privileged
position. On the contrary, there were already symptoms that their
ascendency was drawing to a close. "Western Europe," it was said,
"presents a strange, saddening spectacle. Opinion struggles
against opinion, power against power, throne against throne.
Science, Art, and Religion, the three chief motors of social life,
have lost their force. We venture to make an assertion which to
many at present may seem strange, but which will be in a few years
only too evident: Western Europe is on the highroad to ruin! We
Russians, on the contrary, are young and fresh, and have taken no
part in the crimes of Europe. We have a great mission to fulfil.
Our name is already inscribed on the tablets of victory, and now we
have to inscribe our spirit in the history of the human mind. A
higher kind of victory--the victory of Science, Art and Faith--
awaits us on the ruins of tottering Europe!"*
* These words were written by Prince Odoefski.
This conclusion was supported by arguments drawn from history--or,
at least, what was believed to be history. The European world was
represented as being composed of two hemispheres--the Eastern or
Graeco-Slavonic on the one hand, and the Western, or Roman Catholic
and Protestant, on the other. These two hemispheres, it was said,
are distinguished from each other by many fundamental
characteristics. In both of them Christianity formed originally
the basis of civilisation, but in the West it became distorted and
gave a false direction to the intellectual development. By placing
the logical reason of the learned above the conscience of the whole
Church, Roman Catholicism produced Protestantism, which proclaimed
the right of private judgment and consequently became split up into
innumerable sects. The dry, logical spirit which was thus fostered
created a purely intellectual, one-sided philosophy, which must end
in pure scepticism, by blinding men to those great truths which lie
above the sphere of reasoning and logic. The Graeco-Slavonic
world, on the contrary, having accepted Christianity not from Rome,
but from Byzantium, received pure orthodoxy and true enlightenment,
and was thus saved alike from Papal tyranny and from Protestant
free-thinking. Hence the Eastern Christians have preserved
faithfully not only the ancient dogmas, but also the ancient spirit
of Christianity--that spirit of pious humility, resignation, and
brotherly love which Christ taught by precept and example. If they
have not yet a philosophy, they will create one, and it will far
surpass all previous systems; for in the writings of the Greek
Fathers are to be found the germs of a broader, a deeper, and a
truer philosophy than the dry, meagre rationalism of the West--a
philosophy founded not on the logical faculty alone, but on the
broader basis of human nature as a whole.
The fundamental characteristics of the Graeco-Slavonic world--so
runs the Slavophil theory--have been displayed in the history of
Russia. Throughout Western Christendom the principal of individual
judgment and reckless individual egotism have exhausted the social
forces and brought society to the verge of incurable anarchy and
inevitable dissolution, whereas the social and political history of
Russia has been harmonious and peaceful. It presents no struggles
between the different social classes, and no conflicts between
Church and State. All the factors have worked in unison, and the
development has been guided by the spirit of pure orthodoxy. But
in this harmonious picture there is one big, ugly black spot--
Peter, falsely styled "the Great," and his so-called reforms.
Instead of following the wise policy of his ancestors, Peter
rejected the national traditions and principles, and applied to his
country, which belonged to the Eastern world, the principles of
Western civilisation. His reforms, conceived in a foreign spirit,
and elaborated by men who did not possess the national instincts,
were forced upon the nation against its will, and the result was
precisely what might have been expected. The "broad Slavonic
nature" could not be controlled by institutions which had been
invented by narrow-minded, pedantic German bureaucrats, and, like
another Samson, it pulled down the building in which foreign
legislators sought to confine it. The attempt to introduce foreign
culture had a still worse effect. The upper classes, charmed and
dazzled by the glare and glitter of Western science, threw
themselves impulsively on the newly found treasures, and thereby
condemned themselves to moral slavery and intellectual sterility.
Fortunately--and herein lay one of the fundamental principles of
the Slavophil doctrine--the imported civilisation had not at all
infected the common people. Through all the changes which the
administration and the Noblesse underwent the peasantry preserved
religiously in their hearts "the living legacy of antiquity," the
essence of Russian nationality, "a clear spring welling up living
waters, hidden and unknown, but powerful."* To recover this lost
legacy by studying the character, customs, and institutions of the
peasantry, to lead the educated classes back to the path from which
they had strayed, and to re-establish that intellectual and moral
unity which had been disturbed by the foreign importations--such
was the task which the Slavophils proposed to themselves.
* This was one of the favourite themes of Khomiakof, the Slavophil
poet and theologian.
Deeply imbued with that romantic spirit which distorted all the
intellectual activity of the time, the Slavophils often indulged in
the wildest exaggerations, condemning everything foreign and
praising everything Russian. When in this mood they saw in the
history of the West nothing but violence, slavery, and egotism, and
in that of their own country free-will, liberty, and peace. The
fact that Russia did not possess free political institutions was
adduced as a precious fruit of that spirit of Christian resignation
and self-sacrifice which places the Russian at such an immeasurable
height above the proud, selfish European; and because Russia
possessed few of the comforts and conveniences of common life, the
West was accused of having made comfort its God! We need not,
however, dwell on these puerilities, which only gained for their
authors the reputation of being ignorant, narrow-minded men, imbued
with a hatred of enlightenment and desirous of leading their
country back to its primitive barbarism. What the Slavophils
really condemned, at least in their calmer moments, was not
European culture, but the uncritical, indiscriminate adoption of it
by their countrymen. Their tirades against foreign culture must
appear excusable when we remember that many Russians of the upper
ranks could speak and write French more correctly than their native
language, and that even the great national poet Pushkin was not
ashamed to confess--what was not true, and a mere piece of
affectation--that "the language of Europe" was more familiar to him
than his mother-tongue!
The Slavophil doctrine, though it made a great noise in the world,
never found many adherents. The society of St. Petersburg regarded
it as one of those harmless provincial eccentricities which are
always to be found in Moscow. In the modern capital, with its
foreign name, its streets and squares on the European model, its
palaces and churches in the Renaissance style, and its passionate
love of everything French, any attempt to resuscitate the old
Boyaric times would have been eminently ridiculous. Indeed,
hostility to St. Petersburg and to "the Petersburg period of
Russian history" is one of the characteristic traits of genuine
Slavophilism. In Moscow the doctrine found a more appropriate
home. There the ancient churches, with the tombs of Grand Princes
and holy martyrs, the palace in which the Tsars of Muscovy had
lived, the Kremlin which had resisted--not always successfully--the
attacks of savage Tartars and heretical Poles, the venerable Icons
that had many a time protected the people from danger, the block of
masonry from which, on solemn occasions, the Tsar and the Patriarch
had addressed the assembled multitude--these, and a hundred other
monuments sanctified by tradition, have kept alive in the popular
memory some vague remembrance of the olden time, and are still
capable of awakening antiquarian patriotism.
The inhabitants, too, have preserved something of the old Muscovite
character. Whilst successive sovereigns have been striving to make
the country a progressive European empire, Moscow has remained the
home of passive conservatism and an asylum for the discontented,
especially for the disappointed aspirants to Imperial favour.
Abandoned by the modern Emperors, she can glory in her ancient
Tsars. But even the Muscovites were not prepared to accept the
Slavophil doctrine in the extreme form which it assumed, and were
not a little perplexed by the eccentricities of those who professed
it. Plain, sensible people, though they might be proud of being
citizens of the ancient capital, and might thoroughly enjoy a joke
at the expense of St. Petersburg, could not understand a little
coterie of enthusiasts who sought neither official rank nor
decorations, who slighted many of the conventionalities of the
higher classes to which by birth and education they belonged, who
loved to fraternise with the common people, and who occasionally
dressed in the national costume which had been discarded by the
nobles since the time of Peter the Great.
The Slavophils thus remained merely a small literary party, which
probably did not count more than a dozen members, but their
influence was out of all proportion to their numbers. They
preached successfully the doctrine that the historical development
of Russia has been peculiar, that her present social and political
organisation is radically different from that of the countries of
Western Europe, and that consequently the social and political
evils from which she suffers are not to be cured by the remedies
which have proved efficacious in France and Germany. These truths,
which now appear commonplace, were formerly by no means generally
recognised, and the Slavophils deserve credit for directing
attention to them. Besides this, they helped to awaken in the
upper classes a lively sympathy with the poor, oppressed, and
despised peasantry. So long as the Emperor Nicholas lived they had
to confine themselves to a purely literary activity; but during the
great reforms initiated by his successor, Alexander II., they
descended into the arena of practical politics, and played a most
useful and honourable part in the emancipation of the serfs. In
the new local self-government, too--the Zemstvo and the new
municipal institutions--they laboured energetically and to good
purpose. Of all this I shall have occasion to speak more fully in
future chapters.
But what of their Panslavist aspirations? By their theory they
were constrained to pay attention to the Slav race as a whole, but
they were more Russian than Slav, and more Muscovite than Russian.
The Panslavist element consequently occupied a secondary place in
Slavophil doctrine. Though they did much to stimulate popular
sympathy with the Southern Slavs, and always cherished the hope
that the Serbs, Bulgarians, and cognate Slav nationalities would
one day throw off the bondage of the German and the Turk, they
never proposed any elaborate project for the solution of the
Eastern Question. So far as I was able to gather from their
conversation, they seemed to favour the idea of a grand Slavonic
Confederation, in which the hegemony would, of course, belong to
Russia. In ordinary times the only steps which they took for the
realisation of this idea consisted in contributing money for
schools and churches among the Slav population of Austria and
Turkey, and in educating young Bulgarians in Russia. During the
Cretan insurrection they sympathised warmly with the insurgents as
co-religionists, but afterwards--especially during the crisis of
the Eastern Question which culminated in the Treaty of San Stefano
and the Congress of Berlin (1878)--their Hellenic sympathies
cooled, because the Greeks showed that they had political
aspirations inconsistent with the designs of Russia, and that they
were likely to be the rivals rather than the allies of the Slavs in
the struggle for the Sick Man's inheritance.
Since the time when I was living in Moscow in constant intercourse
with the leading Slavophils more than a quarter of a century has
passed, and of those with whom I spent so many pleasant evenings
discussing the past history and future destinies of the Slav races,
not one remains alive. All the great prophets of the old Slavophil
doctrine--Jun Samarin, Prince Tcherkaski, Ivan Aksakof, Kosheleff--
have departed without leaving behind them any genuine disciples.
The present generation of Muscovite frondeurs, who continue to rail
against Western Europe and the pedantic officialism of St.
Petersburg, are of a more modern and less academic type. Their
philippics are directed not against Peter the Great and his
reforms, but rather against recent Ministers of Foreign Affairs who
are thought to have shown themselves too subservient to foreign
Powers, and against M. Witte, the late Minister of Finance, who is
accused of favouring the introduction of foreign capital and
enterprise, and of sacrificing to unhealthy industrial development
the interests of the agricultural classes. These laments and
diatribes are allowed free expression in private conversation and
in the Press, but they do not influence very deeply the policy of
the Government or the natural course of events; for the Ministry of
Foreign Affairs continues to cultivate friendly relations with the
Cabinets of the West, and Moscow is rapidly becoming, by the force
of economic conditions, the great industrial and commercial centre
of the Empire.
The administrative and bureaucratic centre--if anything on the
frontier of a country can be called its centre--has long been, and
is likely to remain, Peter's stately city at the mouth of the Neva,
to which I now invite the reader to accompany me.
CHAPTER XXVI
ST. PETERSBURG AND EUROPEAN INFLUENCE
St. Petersburg and Berlin--Big Houses--The "Lions"--Peter the
Great--His Aims and Policy--The German Regime--Nationalist
Reaction--French Influence--Consequent Intellectual Sterility--
Influence of the Sentimental School--Hostility to Foreign
Influences--A New Period of Literary Importation--Secret Societies--
The Catastrophe--The Age of Nicholas--A Terrible War on Parnassus--
Decline of Romanticism and Transcendentalism--Gogol--The
Revolutionary Agitation of 1848--New Reaction--Conclusion.
From whatever side the traveller approaches St. Petersburg, unless
he goes thither by sea, he must traverse several hundred miles of
forest and morass, presenting few traces of human habitation or
agriculture. This fact adds powerfully to the first impression
which the city makes on his mind. In the midst of a waste howling
wilderness, he suddenly comes on a magnificent artificial oasis.
Of all the great European cities, the one that most resembles the
capital of the Tsars is Berlin. Both are built on perfectly level
ground; both have wide, regularly arranged streets; in both there
is a general look of stiffness and symmetry which suggests military
discipline and German bureaucracy. But there is at least one
profound difference. Though Berlin is said by geographers to be
built on the Spree, we might live a long time in the city without
noticing the sluggish little stream on which the name of a river
has been undeservedly conferred. St. Petersburg, on the contrary,
is built on a magnificent river, which forms the main feature of
the place. By its breadth, and by the enormous volume of its
clear, blue, cold water, the Neva is certainly one of the noblest
rivers of Europe. A few miles before reaching the Gulf of Finland
it breaks up into several streams and forms a delta. It is here
that St. Petersburg stands.
Like the river, everything in St. Petersburg is on a colossal
scale. The streets, the squares, the palaces, the public
buildings, the churches, whatever may be their defects, have at
least the attribute of greatness, and seem to have been designed
for the countless generations to come, rather than for the
practical wants of the present inhabitants. In this respect the
city well represents the Empire of which it is the capital. Even
the private houses are built in enormous blocks and divided into
many separate apartments. Those built for the working classes
sometimes contain, I am assured, more than a thousand inhabitants.
How many cubic feet of air is allowed to each person, I do not
know; not so many, I fear, as is recommended by the most advanced
sanitary authorities.
For a detailed description of the city I must refer the reader to
the guide books. Among its numerous monuments, of which the
Russians are justly proud, I confess that the one which interested
me most was neither St. Isaac's Cathedral, with its majestic gilded
dome, its colossal monolithic columns of red granite, and its gaudy
interior; nor the Hermitage, with its magnificent collection of
Dutch pictures; nor the gloomy, frowning fortress of St. Peter and
St. Paul, containing the tombs of the Emperors. These and other
"sights" may deserve all the praise which enthusiastic tourists
have lavished upon them, but what made a far deeper impression on
me was the little wooden house in which Peter the Great lived
whilst his future capital was being built. In its style and
arrangement it looks more like the hut of a navvy than the
residence of a Tsar, but it was quite in keeping with the character
of the illustrious man who occupied it. Peter could and did
occasionally work like a navvy without feeling that his Imperial
dignity was thereby impaired. When he determined to build a new
capital on a Finnish marsh, inhabited chiefly by wildfowl, he did
not content himself with exercising his autocratic power in a
comfortable arm chair. Like the Greek gods, he went down from his
Olympus and took his place in the ranks of ordinary mortals,
superintending the work with his own eyes, and taking part in it
with his own hands. If he was as arbitrary and oppressive as any
of the pyramid-building Pharaohs, he could at least say in self-
justification that he did not spare himself any more than his
people, but exposed himself freely to the discomforts and dangers
under which thousands of his fellow-labourers succumbed.
In reading the account of Peter's life, written in part by his own
pen, we can easily understand how the piously Conservative section
of his subjects failed to recognise in him the legitimate successor
of the orthodox Tsars. The old Tsars had been men of grave,
pompous demeanour, deeply imbued with the consciousness of their
semi-religious dignity. Living habitually in Moscow or its
immediate neighbourhood, they spent their time in attending long
religious services, in consulting with their Boyars, in being
present at ceremonious hunting-parties, in visiting the
monasteries, and in holding edifying conversations with
ecclesiastical dignitaries or revered ascetics. If they undertook
a journey, it was probably to make a pilgrimage to some holy
shrine; and, whether in Moscow or elsewhere, they were always
protected from contact with ordinary humanity by a formidable
barricade of court ceremonial. In short, they combined the
characters of a Christian monk and of an Oriental potentate.
Peter was a man of an entirely different type, and played in the
calm, dignified, orthodox, ceremonious world of Moscow the part of
the bull in the china shop, outraging ruthlessly and wantonly all
the time-honored traditional conceptions of propriety and
etiquette. Utterly regardless of public opinion and popular
prejudices, he swept away the old formalities, avoided ceremonies
of all kinds, scoffed at ancient usage, preferred foreign secular
books to edifying conversations, chose profane heretics as his boon
companions, travelled in foreign countries, dressed in heretical
costume, defaced the image of God and put his soul in jeopardy by
shaving off his beard, compelled his nobles to dress and shave like
himself, rushed about the Empire as if goaded on by the demon of
unrest, employed his sacred hands in carpentering and other menial
occupations, took part openly in the uproarious orgies of his
foreign soldiery, and, in short, did everything that "the Lord's
anointed" might reasonably be expected not to do. No wonder the
Muscovites were scandalised by his conduct, and that some of them
suspected he was not the Tsar at all, but Antichrist in disguise.
And no wonder he felt the atmosphere of Moscow oppressive, and
preferred living in the new capital which he had himself created.
His avowed object in building St. Petersburg was to have "a window
by which the Russians might look into civilised Europe"; and well
has the city fulfilled its purpose. From its foundation may be
dated the European period of Russian history. Before Peter's time
Russia belonged to Asia rather than to Europe, and was doubtless
regarded by Englishmen and Frenchmen pretty much as we nowadays
regard Bokhara or Kashgar; since that time she has formed an
integral part of the European political system, and her
intellectual history has been but a reflection of the intellectual
history of Western Europe, modified and coloured by national
character and by peculiar local conditions.
When we speak of the intellectual history of a nation we generally
mean in reality the intellectual history of the upper classes.
With regard to Russia, more perhaps than with regard to any other
country, this distinction must always carefully be borne in mind.
Peter succeeded in forcing European civilisation on the nobles, but
the people remained unaffected. The nation was, as it were, cleft
in two, and with each succeeding generation the cleft has widened.
Whilst the masses clung obstinately to their time-honoured customs
and beliefs, the nobles came to look on the objects of popular
veneration as the relics of a barbarous past, of which a civilised
nation ought to be ashamed.
The intellectual movement inaugurated by Peter had a purely
practical character. He was himself a thorough utilitarian, and
perceived clearly that what his people needed was not theological
or philosophical enlightment, but plain, practical knowledge
suitable for the requirements of everyday life. He wanted neither
theologians nor philosophers, but military and naval officers,
administrators, artisans, miners, manufacturers, and merchants, and
for this purpose he introduced secular technical education. For
the young generation primary schools were founded, and for more
advanced pupils the best foreign works on fortification,
architecture, navigation, metallurgy, engineering and cognate
subjects were translated into the native tongue. Scientific men
and cunning artificers were brought into the country, and young
Russians were sent abroad to learn foreign languages and the useful
arts. In a word, everything was done that seemed likely to raise
the Russians to the level of material well-being already attained
by the more advanced nations.
We have here an important peculiarity in the intellectual
development of Russia. In Western Europe the modern scientific
spirit, being the natural offspring of numerous concomitant
historical causes, was born in the natural way, and Society had,
consequently, before giving birth to it, to endure the pains of
pregnancy and the throes of prolonged labour. In Russia, on the
contrary, this spirit appeared suddenly as an adult foreigner,
adopted by a despotic paterfamilias. Thus Russia made the
transition from mediaeval to modern times without any violent
struggle between the old and the new conceptions such as had taken
place in the West. The Church, effectually restrained from all
active opposition by the Imperial power, preserved unmodified her
ancient beliefs; whilst the nobles, casting their traditional
conceptions and beliefs to the winds, marched forward unfettered on
that path which their fathers and grandfathers had regarded as the
direct road to perdition.
During the first part of Peter's reign Russia was not subjected to
the exclusive influence of any one particular country. Thoroughly
cosmopolitan in his sympathies, the great reformer, like the
Japanese of the present day, was ready to borrow from any foreign
nation--German, Dutch, Danish, or French--whatever seemed to him to
suit his purpose. But soon the geographical proximity to Germany,
the annexation of the Baltic Provinces in which the civilisation
was German, and intermarriages between the Imperial family and
various German dynasties, gave to German influence a decided
preponderance. When the Empress Anne, Peter's niece, who had been
Duchess of Courland, entrusted the whole administration of the
country to her favourite Biron, the German influence became almost
exclusive, and the Court, the official world, and the schools were
Germanised.
The harsh, cruel, tyrannical rule of Biron produced a strong
reaction, ending in a revolution, which raised to the throne the
Princess Elizabeth, Peter's unmarried daughter, who had lived in
retirement and neglect during the German regime. She was expected
to rid the country of foreigners, and she did what she could to
fulfil the expectations that were entertained of her. With loud
protestations of patriotic feelings, she removed the Germans from
all important posts, demanded that in future the members of the
Academy should be chosen from among born Russians, and gave orders
that the Russian youth should be carefully prepared for all kinds
of official activity.
This attempt to throw off the German bondage did not lead to
intellectual independence. During Peter's violent reforms Russia
had ruthlessly thrown away her own historic past with whatever
germs it contained, and now she possessed none of the elements of a
genuine national culture. She was in the position of a fugitive
who has escaped from slavery, and, finding himself in danger of
starvation, looks about for a new master. The upper classes, who
had acquired a taste for foreign civilisation, no sooner threw off
everything German than they sought some other civilisation to put
in its place. And they could not long hesitate in making a choice,
for at that time all who thought of culture and refinement turned
their eyes to Paris and Versailles. All that was most brilliant
and refined was to be found at the Court of the French kings, under
whose patronage the art and literature of the Renaissance had
attained their highest development. Even Germany, which had
resisted the ambitious designs of Louis XIV., imitated the manners
of his Court. Every petty German potentate strove to ape the pomp
and dignity of the Grand Monarque; and the courtiers, affecting to
look on everything German as rude and barbarous, adopted French
fashions, and spoke a hybrid jargon which they considered much more
elegant than the plain mother tongue. In a word, Gallomania had
become the prevailing social epidemic of the time, and it could not
fail to attack and metamorphose such a class as the Russian
Noblesse, which possessed few stubborn deep-rooted national
convictions.
At first the French influence was manifested chiefly in external
forms--that is to say, in dress, manners, language, and upholstery--
but gradually, and very rapidly after the accession of Catherine
II., the friend of Voltaire and the Encyclopaedists, it sank
deeper. Every noble who had pretensions to being "civilised"
learned to speak French fluently, and gained some superficial
acquaintance with French literature. The tragedies of Corneille
and Racine and the comedies of Moliere were played regularly at the
Court theatre in presence of the Empress, and awakened a real or
affected enthusiasm among the audience. For those who preferred
reading in their native language, numerous translations were
published, a simple list of which would fill several pages. Among
them we find not only Voltaire, Rousseau, Lesage, Marmontel, and
other favourite French authors, but also all the masterpieces of
European literature, ancient and modern, which at that time enjoyed
a high reputation in the French literary world--Homer and
Demosthenes, Cicero and Virgil, Ariosto and Camoens, Milton and
Locke, Sterne and Fielding.
It is related of Byron that he never wrote a description whilst the
scene was actually before him; and this fact points to an important
psychological principle. The human mind, so long as it is
compelled to strain the receptive faculties, cannot engage in that
"poetic" activity--to use the term in its Greek sense--which is
commonly called "original creation." And as with individuals, so
with nations. By accepting in a lump a foreign culture a nation
inevitably condemns itself for a time to intellectual sterility.
So long as it is occupied in receiving and assimilating a flood of
new ideas, unfamiliar conceptions, and foreign modes of thought, it
will produce nothing original, and the result of its highest
efforts will be merely successful imitation. We need not be
surprised therefore to find that the Russians, in becoming
acquainted with foreign literature, became imitators and
plagiarists. In this kind of work their natural pliancy of mind
and powerful histrionic talent made them wonderfully successful.
Odes, pseudo-classical tragedies, satirical comedies, epic poems,
elegies, and all the other recognised forms of poetical
composition, appeared in great profusion, and many of the writers
acquired a remarkable command over their native language, which had
hitherto been regarded as uncouth and barbarous. But in all this
mass of imitative literature, which has since fallen into well-
merited oblivion, there are very few traces of genuine originality.
To obtain the title of the Russian Racine, the Russian Lafontaine,
the Russian Pindar, or the Russian Homer, was at that time the
highest aim of Russian literary ambition.
Together with the fashionable literature the Russian educated
classes adopted something of the fashionable philosophy. They were
peculiarly unfitted to resist that hurricane of "enlightenment"
which swept over Europe during the latter half of the eighteenth
century, first breaking or uprooting the received philosophical
systems, theological conceptions, and scientific theories, and then
shaking to their foundations the existing political and social
institutions. The Russian Noblesse had neither the traditional
conservative spirit, nor the firm, well-reasoned, logical beliefs
which in England and Germany formed a powerful barrier against the
spread of French influence. They had been too recently
metamorphosed, and were too eager to acquire a foreign
civilisation, to have even the germs of a conservative spirit. The
rapidity and violence with which Peter's reforms had been effected,
together with the peculiar spirit of Greek Orthodoxy and the low
intellectual level of the clergy, had prevented theology from
associating itself with the new order of things. The upper classes
had become estranged from the beliefs of their forefathers without
acquiring other beliefs to supply the place of those which had been
lost. The old religious conceptions were inseparably interwoven
with what was recognised as antiquated and barbarous, whilst the
new philosophical ideas were associated with all that was modern
and civilised. Besides this, the sovereign, Catherine II., who
enjoyed the unbounded admiration of the upper classes, openly
professed allegiance to the new philosophy, and sought the advice
and friendship of its high priests. If we bear in mind these facts
we shall not be surprised to find among the Russian nobles of that
time a considerable number of so-called "Voltaireans" and numerous
unquestioning believers in the infallibility of the Encyclopedie.
What is a little more surprising is, that the new philosophy
sometimes found its way into the ecclesiastical seminaries. The
famous Speranski relates that in the seminary of St. Petersburg one
of his professors, when not in a state of intoxication, was in the
habit of preaching the doctrines of Voltaire and Diderot!
The rise of the sentimental school in Western Europe produced an
important change in Russian literature, by undermining the
inordinate admiration for the French pseudo-classical school.
Florian, Richardson, Sterne, Rousseau, and Bernardin de St. Pierre
found first translators, and then imitators, and soon the loud-
sounding declamation and wordy ecstatic despair of the stage heroes
were drowned in the deep-drawn sighs and plaintive wailings of
amorous swains and peasant-maids forsaken. The mania seems to have
been in Russia even more severe than in the countries where it
originated. Full-grown, bearded men wept because they had not been
born in peaceful primitive times, "when all men were shepherds and
brothers." Hundreds of sighing youths and maidens visited the
scenes described by the sentimental writers, and wandered by the
rivers and ponds in which despairing heroines had drowned
themselves. People talked, wrote, and meditated about "the
sympathy of hearts created for each other," "the soft communion of
sympathetic souls," and much more of the same kind. Sentimental
journeys became a favourite amusement, and formed the subject of
very popular books, containing maudlin absurdities likely to
produce nowadays mirth rather than tears. One traveller, for
instance, throws himself on his knees before an old oak and makes a
speech to it; another weeps daily on the grave of a favourite dog,
and constantly longs to marry a peasant girl; a third talks love to
the moon, sends kisses to the stars, and wishes to press the
heavenly orbs to his bosom! For a time the public would read
nothing but absurd productions of this sort, and Karamzin, the
great literary authority of the time, expressly declared that the
true function of Art was "to disseminate agreeable impressions in
the region of the sentimental."
The love of French philosophy vanished as suddenly as the
inordinate admiration of the French pseudo-classical literature.
When the great Revolution broke out in Paris the fashionable
philosophic literature in St. Petersburg disappeared. Men who
talked about political freedom and the rights of man, without
thinking for a moment of limiting the autocratic power or of
emancipating their serfs, were naturally surprised and frightened
on discovering what the liberal principles could effect when
applied to real life. Horrified by the awful scenes of the Terror,
they hastened to divest themselves of the principles which led to
such results, and sank into a kind of optimistic conservatism that
harmonised well with the virtuous sentimentalism in vogue. In this
the Empress herself gave the example. The Imperial disciple and
friend of the Encyclopaedists became in the last years of her reign
a decided reactionnaire.
During the Napoleonic wars, when the patriotic feelings were
excited, there was a violent hostility to foreign intellectual
influence; and feeble intermittent attempts were made to throw off
the intellectual bondage. The invasion of the country in 1812 by
the Grande Armee, and the burning of Moscow, added abundant fuel to
this patriotic fire. For some time any one who ventured to express
even a moderate admiration for French culture incurred the risk of
being stigmatised as a traitor to his country and a renegade to the
national faith. But this patriotic fanaticism soon evaporated, and
exaggerations of the ultra-national party became the object of
satire and parody. When the political danger was past, and people
resumed their ordinary occupations, those who loved foreign
literature returned to their old favourites--or, as the ultra-
patriots called it, to their "wallowing in the mire"--simply
because the native literature did not supply them with what they
desired. "We are quite ready," they said to their upbraiders, "to
admire your great works as soon as they appear, but in the meantime
please allow us to enjoy what we possess." Thus in the last years
of the reign of Alexander I. the patriotic opposition to West
European literature gradually ceased, and a new period of
unrestricted intellectual importation began.
The intellectual merchandise now brought into the country was very
different from that which had been imported in the time of
Catherine. The French Revolution, the Napoleonic domination, the
patriotic wars, the restoration of the Bourbons, and the other
great events of that memorable epoch, had in the interval produced
profound changes in the intellectual as well as the political
condition of Western Europe. During the Napoleonic wars Russia had
become closely associated with Germany; and now the peculiar
intellectual fermentation which was going on among the German
educated classes was reflected in the society of St. Petersburg.
It did not appear, indeed, in the printed literature, for the
Press-censure had been recently organised on the principles laid
down by Metternich, but it was none the less violent on that
account. Whilst the periodicals were filled with commonplace
meditations on youth, spring, the love of Art, and similar innocent
topics, the young generation was discussing in the salons all the
burning questions which Metternich and his adherents were
endeavouring to extinguish.
These discussions, if discussions they might be called, were not of
a very serious kind. In true dilettante style the fashionable
young philosophers culled from the newest books the newest thoughts
and theories, and retailed them in the salon or the ballroom. And
they were always sure to find attentive listeners. The more
astounding the idea or dogma, the more likely was it to be
favourably received. No matter whether it came from the
Rationalists, the Mystics, the Freemasons, or the Methodists, it
was certain to find favour, provided it was novel and presented in
an elegant form. The eclectic minds of that curious time could
derive equal satisfaction from the brilliant discourses of the
reactionary jesuitical De Maistre, the revolutionary odes of
Pushkin, and the mysticism of Frau von Krudener. For the majority
the vague theosophic doctrines and the projects for a spiritual
union of governments and peoples had perhaps the greatest charm,
being specially commended by the fact that they enjoyed the
protection and sympathy of the Emperor. Pious souls discovered in
the mystical lucubrations of Jung-Stilling and Baader the final
solution of all existing difficulties--political, social, and
philosophical. Men of less dreamy temperament put their faith in
political economy and constitutional theories, and sought a
foundation for their favourite schemes in the past history of the
country and in the supposed fundamental peculiarities of the
national character. Like the young German democrats, who were then
talking enthusiastically about Teutons, Cheruskers, Skalds, the
shade of Arminius, and the heroes of the Niebelungen, these young
Russian savants recognised in early Russian history--when
reconstructed according to their own fancy--lofty political ideals,
and dreamed of resuscitating the ancient institutions in all their
pristine imaginary splendour.
Each age has its peculiar social and political panaceas. One
generation puts its trust in religion, another in philanthropy, a
third in written constitutions, a fourth in universal suffrage, a
fifth in popular education. In the Epoch of the Restoration, as it
is called, the favourite panacea all over the Continent was secret
political association. Very soon after the overthrow of Napoleon
the peoples who had risen in arms to obtain political independence
discovered that they had merely changed masters. The Princes
reconstructed Europe according to their own convenience, without
paying much attention to patriotic aspirations, and forgot their
promises of liberal institutions as soon as they were again firmly
seated on their thrones. This was naturally for many a bitter
deception. The young generation, excluded from all share in
political life and gagged by the stringent police supervision,
sought to realise its political aspirations by means of secret
societies, resembling more or less the Masonic brotherhoods. There
were the Burschenschaften in Germany; the Union, and the "Aide toi
et le ciel t'aidera," in France; the Order of the Hammer in Spain;
the Carbonari in Italy; and the Hetairai in Greece. In Russia the
young nobles followed the prevailing fashion. Secret societies
were formed, and in December, 1825, an attempt was made to raise a
military insurrection in St. Petersburg, for the purpose of
deposing the Imperial family and proclaiming a republic; but the
attempt failed, and the vague Utopian dreams of the romantic would-
be reformers were swept away by grape-shot.
This "December catastrophe," still vividly remembered, was for the
society of St. Petersburg like the giving way of the floor in a
crowded ball-room. But a moment before, all had been animated,
careless, and happy; now consternation was depicted on every face.
The salons, that but yesterday had been ringing with lively
discussions on morals, aesthetics, politics, and theology, were now
silent and deserted. Many of those who had been wont to lead the
causeries had been removed to the cells of the fortress, and those
who had not been arrested trembled for themselves or their friends;
for nearly all had of late dabbled more or less in the theory and
practice of revolution. The announcement that five of the
conspirators had been condemned to the gallows and the others
sentenced to transportation did not tend to calm the consternation.
Society was like a discomfited child, who, amidst the delight and
excitement of letting off fireworks, has had its fingers severely
burnt.
The sentimental, wavering Alexander I. had been succeeded by his
stern, energetic brother Nicholas, and the command went forth that
there should be no more fireworks, no more dilettante
philosophising or political aspirations. There was, however,
little need for such an order. Society had been, for the moment at
least, effectually cured of all tendencies to political dreaming.
It had discovered, to its astonishment and dismay, that these new
ideas, which were to bring temporal salvation to humanity, and to
make all men happy, virtuous, refined, and poetical, led in reality
to exile and the scaffold! The pleasant dream was at an end, and
the fashionable world, giving up its former habits, took to
harmless occupations--card-playing, dissipation, and the reading of
French light literature. "The French quadrille," as a writer of
the time tersely expresses it, "has taken the place of Adam Smith."
When the storm had passed, the life of the salons began anew, but
it was very different from what it had been. There was no longer
any talk about political economy, theology, popular education,
administrative abuses, social and political reforms. Everything
that had any relation to politics in the wider sense of the term
was by tacit consent avoided. Discussions there were as of old,
but they were now confined to literary topics, theories of art, and
similar innocent subjects.
This indifference or positive repugnance to philosophy and
political science, strengthened and prolonged by the repressive
system of administration adopted by Nicholas, was of course fatal
to the many-sided intellectual activity which had flourished during
the preceding reign, but it was by no means unfavourable to the
cultivation of imaginative literature. On the contrary, by
excluding those practical interests which tend to disturb artistic
production and to engross the attention of the public, it fostered
what was called in the phraseology of that time "the pure-hearted
worship of the Muses." We need not, therefore, be surprised to
find that the reign of Nicholas, which is commonly and not unjustly
described as an epoch of social and intellectual stagnation, may be
called in a certain sense the Golden Age of Russian literature.
Already in the preceding reign the struggle between the Classical
and the Romantic school--between the adherents of traditional
aesthetic principles and the partisans of untrammelled poetic
inspiration--which was being carried on in Western Europe, was
reflected in Russia. A group of young men belonging to the
aristocratic society of St. Petersburg embraced with enthusiasm the
new doctrines, and declared war against "classicism," under which
term they understood all that was antiquated, dry, and pedantic.
Discarding the stately, lumbering, unwieldy periods which had
hitherto been in fashion, they wrote a light, elastic, vigorous
style, and formed a literary society for the express purpose of
ridiculing the most approved classical writers. The new principles
found many adherents, and the new style many admirers, but this
only intensified the hostility of the literary Conservatives. The
staid, respectable leaders of the old school, who had all their
lives kept the fear of Boileau before their eyes and considered his
precepts as the infallible utterances of aesthetic wisdom,
thundered against the impious innovations as unmistakable symptoms
of literary decline and moral degeneracy--representing the
boisterous young iconoclasts as dissipated Don Juans and dangerous
freethinkers.
Thus for some time in Russia, as in Western Europe, "a terrible war
raged on Parnassus." At first the Government frowned at the
innovators, on account of certain revolutionary odes which one of
their number had written; but when the Romantic Muse, having turned
away from the present as essentially prosaic, went back into the
distant past and soared into the region of sublime abstractions,
the most keen-eyed Press Censors found no reason to condemn her
worship, and the authorities placed almost no restrictions on free
poetic inspiration. Romantic poetry acquired the protection of the
Government and the patronage of the Court, and the names of
Zhukofski, Pushkin, and Lermontof--the three chief representatives
of the Russian Romantic school--became household words in all ranks
of the educated classes.
These three great luminaries of the literary world were of course
attended by a host of satellites of various magnitudes, who did all
in their power to refute the romantic principles by reductiones ad
absurdum. Endowed for the most part with considerable facility of
composition, the poetasters poured forth their feelings with
torrential recklessness, demanding freedom for their inspiration,
and cursing the age that fettered them with its prosaic cares, its
cold reason, and its dry science. At the same time the dramatists
and novelists created heroes of immaculate character and angelic
purity, endowed with all the cardinal virtues in the superlative
degree; and, as a contrast to these, terrible Satanic personages
with savage passions, gleaming daggers, deadly poisons, and all
manner of aimless melodramatic villainy. These stilted
productions, interspersed with light satirical essays, historical
sketches, literary criticism, and amusing anecdotes, formed the
contents of the periodical literature, and completely satisfied the
wants of the reading public. Almost no one at that time took any
interest in public affairs or foreign politics. The acts of the
Government which were watched most attentively were the promotions
in the service and the conferring of decorations. The publication
of a new tale by Zagoskin or Marlinski--two writers now well-nigh
forgotten--seemed of much greater importance than any amount of
legislation, and such events as the French Revolution of 1830 paled
before the publication of a new poem by Pushkin.
The Transcendental philosophy, which in Germany went hand in hand
with the Romantic literature, found likewise a faint reflection in
Russia. A number of young professors and students in Moscow, who
had become ardent admirers of German literature, passed from the
works of Schiller, Goethe, and Hoffmann to the writing of Schelling
and Hegel. Trained in the Romantic school, these young
philosophers found at first a special charm in Schelling's mystical
system, teeming with hazy poetical metaphors, and presenting a
misty grandiose picture of the universe; but gradually they felt
the want of some logical basis for their speculations, and Hegel
became their favourite. Gallantly they struggled with the uncouth
terminology and epigrammatic paradoxes of the great thinker, and
strove to force their way through the intricate mazes of his
logical formulae. With the ardour of neophytes they looked at
every phenomenon--even the most trivial incident of common life--
from the philosophical point of view, talked day and night about
principles, ideas, subjectivity, Weltauffassung, and similar
abstract entities, and habitually attacked the "hydra of
unphilosophy" by analysing the phenomena presented and relegating
the ingredient elements to the recognised categories. In ordinary
life they were men of quiet, grave, contemplative demeanour, but
their faces could flush and their blood boil when they discussed
the all-important question, whether it is possible to pass
logically from Pure Being through Nonentity to the conception of
Development and Definite Existence!
We know how in Western Europe Romanticism and Transcendentalism, in
their various forms, sank into oblivion, and were replaced by a
literature which had a closer connection with ordinary prosaic
wants and plain everyday life. The educated public became weary of
the Romantic writers, who were always "sighing like a furnace,"
delighting in solitude, cold eternity, and moonshine, deluging the
world with their heart-gushings, and calling on the heavens and the
earth to stand aghast at their Promethean agonising or their
Wertherean despair. Healthy human nature revolted against the
poetical enthusiasts who had lost the faculty of seeing things in
their natural light, and who constantly indulged in that morbid
self-analysis which is fatal to genuine feeling and vigorous
action. And in this healthy reaction the philosophers fared no
better than the poets, with whom, indeed, they had much in common.
Shutting their eyes to the visible world around them, they had
busied themselves with burrowing in the mysterious depths of
Absolute Being, grappling with the ego and the non-ego,
constructing the great world, visible and invisible, out of their
own puny internal self-consciousness, endeavouring to appropriate
all departments of human thought, and imparting to every subject
they touched the dryness and rigidity of an algebraical formula.
Gradually men with real human sympathies began to perceive that
from all this philosophical turmoil little real advantage was to be
derived. It became only too evident that the philosophers were
perfectly reconciled with all the evil in the world, provided it
did not contradict their theories; that they were men of the same
type as the physician in Moliere's comedy, whose chief care was
that his patients should die selon les ordonnances de la medicine.
In Russia the reaction first appeared in the aesthetic literature.
Its first influential representative was Gogol (b. 1808, d. 1852),
who may be called, in a certain sense, the Russian Dickens. A
minute comparison of those two great humourists would perhaps show
as many points of contrast as of similarity, but there is a strong
superficial resemblance between them. They both possessed an
inexhaustible supply of broad humour and an imagination of singular
vividness. Both had the power of seeing the ridiculous side of
common things, and the talent of producing caricatures that had a
wonderful semblance of reality. A little calm reflection would
suffice to show that the characters presented are for the most part
psychological impossibilities; but on first making their
acquaintance we are so struck with one or two life-like
characteristics and various little details dexterously introduced,
and at the same time we are so carried away by the overflowing fun
of the narrative, that we have neither time nor inclination to use
our critical faculties. In a very short time Gogol's fame spread
throughout the length and breadth of the Empire, and many of his
characters became as familiar to his countrymen as Sam Weller and
Mrs. Gamp were to Englishmen. His descriptions were so graphic--so
like the world which everybody knew! The characters seemed to be
old acquaintances hit off to the life; and readers revelled in that
peculiar pleasure which most of us derive from seeing our friends
successfully mimicked. Even the Iron Tsar could not resist the fun
and humour of "The Inspector" (Revizor), and not only laughed
heartily, but also protected the author against the tyranny of the
literary censors, who considered that the piece was not written in
a sufficiently "well-intentioned" tone. In a word, the reading
public laughed as it had never laughed before, and this wholesome
genuine merriment did much to destroy the morbid appetite for
Byronic heroes and Romantic affectation.
The Romantic Muse did not at once abdicate, but with the spread of
Gogol's popularity her reign was practically at an end. In vain
some of the conservative critics decried the new favourite as
talentless, prosaic, and vulgar. The public were not to be robbed
of their amusement for the sake of any abstract aesthetic
considerations; and young authors, taking Gogol for their model,
chose their subjects from real life, and endeavoured to delineate
with minute truthfulness.
This new intellectual movement was at first purely literary, and
affected merely the manner of writing novels, tales, and poems.
The critics who had previously demanded beauty of form and elegance
of expression now demanded accuracy of description, condemned the
aspirations towards so-called high art, and praised loudly those
who produced the best literary photographs. But authors and
critics did not long remain on this purely aesthetic standpoint.
The authors, in describing reality, began to indicate moral
approval and condemnation, and the critics began to pass from the
criticism of the representations to the criticism of the realities
represented. A poem or a tale was often used as a peg on which to
hang a moral lecture, and the fictitious characters were soundly
rated for their sins of omission and commission. Much was said
about the defence of the oppressed, female emancipation, honour,
and humanitarianism; and ridicule was unsparingly launched against
all forms of ignorance, apathy, and the spirit of routine. The
ordinary refrain was that the public ought now to discard what was
formerly regarded as poetical and sublime, and to occupy itself
with practical concerns--with the real wants of social life.
The literary movement was thus becoming a movement in favour of
social and political reforms when it was suddenly arrested by
political events in the West. The February Revolution in Paris,
and the political fermentation which appeared during 1848-49 in
almost every country of Europe, alarmed the Emperor Nicholas and
his counsellors. A Russian army was sent into Austria to suppress
the Hungarian insurrection and save the Hapsburg dynasty, and the
most stringent measures were taken to prevent disorders at home.
One of the first precautions for the preservation of domestic
tranquillity was to muzzle the Press more firmly than before, and
to silence the aspirations towards reform and progress; thenceforth
nothing could be printed which was not in strict accordance with
the ultra-patriotic theory of Russian history, as expressed by a
leading official personage: "The past has been admirable, the
present is more than magnificent, and the future will surpass all
that the human imagination can conceive!" The alarm caused by the
revolutionary disorders spread to the non-official world, and gave
rise to much patriotic self-congratulation. "The nations of the
West," it was said, "envy us, and if they knew us better--if they
could see how happy and prosperous we are--they would envy us still
more. We ought not, however, to withdraw from Europe our
solicitude; its hostility should not deprive us of our high mission
of saving order and restoring rest to the nations; we ought to
teach them to obey authority as we do. It is for us to introduce
the saving principle of order into a world that has fallen a prey
to anarchy. Russia ought not to abandon that mission which has
been entrusted to her by the heavenly and by the earthly Tsar."*
* These words were written by Tchaadaef, who, a few years before,
had vigorously attacked the Slavophils for enouncing similar views.
Men who saw in the significant political eruption of 1848 nothing
but an outburst of meaningless, aimless anarchy, and who believed
that their country was destined to restore order throughout the
civilised world, had of course little time or inclination to think
of putting their own house in order. No one now spoke of the
necessity of social reorganisation: the recently awakened
aspirations and expectations seemed to be completely forgotten.
The critics returned to their old theory that art and literature
should be cultivated for their own sake and not used as a vehicle
for the propagation of ideas foreign to their nature. It seemed,
in short, as if all the prolific ideas which had for a time
occupied the public attention had been merely "writ in water," and
had now disappeared without leaving a trace behind them.
In reality the new movement was destined to reappear very soon with
tenfold force; but the account of its reappearance and development
belongs to a future chapter. Meanwhile I may formulate the general
conclusion to be drawn from the foregoing pages. Ever since the
time of Peter the Great there has been such a close connection
between Russia and Western Europe that every intellectual movement
which has appeared in France and Germany has been reflected--albeit
in an exaggerated, distorted form--in the educated society of St.
Petersburg and Moscow. Thus the window which Peter opened in order
to enable his subjects to look into Europe has well served its
purpose.
CHAPTER XXVII
THE CRIMEAN WAR AND ITS CONSEQUENCES
The Emperor Nicholas and his System--The Men with Aspirations and
the Apathetically Contented--National Humiliation--Popular
Discontent and the Manuscript Literature--Death of Nicholas--
Alexander II.--New Spirit--Reform Enthusiasm--Change in the
Periodical Literature--The Kolokol--The Conservatives--The
Tchinovniks--First Specific Proposals--Joint-Stock Companies--The
Serf Question Comes to the Front.
The Russians frankly admit that they were beaten in the Crimean
War, but they regard the heroic defence of Sebastopol as one of the
most glorious events in the military annals of their country. Nor
do they altogether regret the result of the struggle. Often in a
half-jocular, half-serious tone they say that they had reason to be
grateful to the Allies. And there is much truth in this
paradoxical statement. The Crimean War inaugurated a new epoch in
the national history. It gave the death-blow to the repressive
system of the Emperor Nicholas, and produced an intellectual
movement and a moral revival which led to gigantic results.
"The affair of December," 1825--I mean the abortive attempt at a
military insurrection in St. Petersburg, to which I have alluded in
the foregoing chapter--gave the key-note to Nicholas's reign. The
armed attempt to overthrow the Imperial power, ending in the
execution or exile of many young members of the first families,
struck terror into the Noblesse, and prepared the way for a period
of repressive police administration. Nicholas had none of the
moral limpness and vacillating character of his predecessor. His
was one of those simple, vigorous, tenacious, straightforward
natures--more frequently to be met with among the Teutonic than
among the Slav races--whose conceptions are all founded on a few
deep-rooted, semi-instinctive convictions, and who are utterly
incapable of accommodating themselves with histrionic cleverness to
the changes of external circumstances. From his early youth he had
shown a strong liking for military discipline and a decided
repugnance to the humanitarianism and liberal principles then in
fashion. With "the rights of man," "the spirit of the age," and
similar philosophical abstractions his strong, domineering nature
had no sympathy; and for the vague, loud-sounding phrases of
philosophic liberalism he had a most profound contempt. "Attend to
your military duties," he was wont to say to his officers before
his accession; "don't trouble your heads with philosophy. I cannot
bear philosophers!" The tragic event which formed the prelude to
his reign naturally confirmed and fortified his previous
convictions. The representatives of liberalism, who could talk so
eloquently about duty in the abstract, had, whilst wearing the
uniform of the Imperial Guard, openly disobeyed the repeated orders
of their superior officers and attempted to shake the allegiance of
the troops for the purpose of overthrowing the Imperial power! A
man who was at once soldier and autocrat, by nature as well as by
position, could of course admit no extenuating circumstances. The
incident stereotyped his character for life, and made him the sworn
enemy of liberalism and the fanatical defender of autocracy, not
only in his own country, but throughout Europe. In European
politics he saw two forces struggling for mastery--monarchy and
democracy, which were in his opinion identical with order and
anarchy; and he was always ready to assist his brother sovereigns
in putting down democratic movements. In his own Empire he
endeavoured by every means in his power to prevent the introduction
of the dangerous ideas. For this purpose a stringent intellectual
quarantine was established on the western frontier. All foreign
books and newspapers, except those of the most harmless kind, were
rigorously excluded. Native writers were placed under strict
supervision, and peremptorily silenced as soon as they departed
from what was considered a "well-intentioned" tone. The number of
university students was diminished, the chairs for political
science were suppressed, and the military schools multiplied.
Russians were prevented from travelling abroad, and foreigners who
visited the country were closely watched by the police. By these
and similar measures it was hoped that Russia would be preserved
from the dangers of revolutionary agitation.
Nicholas has been called the Don Quixote of Autocracy, and the
comparison which the term implies is true in many points. By
character and aims he belonged to a time that had passed away; but
failure and mishap could not shake his faith in his ideal, and made
no change in his honest, stubborn nature, which was as loyal and
chivalresque as that of the ill-fated Knight of La Mancha. In
spite of all evidence to the contrary, he believed in the practical
omnipotence of autocracy. He imagined that as his authority was
theoretically unlimited, so his power could work miracles. By
nature and training a soldier, he considered government a slightly
modified form of military discipline, and looked on the nation as
an army which might be made to perform any intellectual or economic
evolutions that he might see fit to command. All social ills
seemed to him the consequence of disobedience to his orders, and he
knew only one remedy--more discipline. Any expression of doubt as
to the wisdom of his policy, or any criticism of existing
regulations, he treated as an act of insubordination which a wise
sovereign ought not to tolerate. If he never said, "L'Etat--c'est
moi!" it was because he considered the fact so self-evident that it
did not need to be stated. Hence any attack on the administration,
even in the person of the most insignificant official, was an
attack on himself and on the monarchical principle which he
represented. The people must believe--and faith, as we know, comes
not by sight--that they lived under the best possible government.
To doubt this was political heresy. An incautious word or a
foolish joke against the Government was considered a serious crime,
and might be punished by a long exile in some distant and
inhospitable part of the Empire. Progress should by all means be
made, but it must be made by word of command, and in the way
ordered. Private initiative in any form was a thing on no account
to be tolerated. Nicholas never suspected that a ruler, however
well-intentioned, energetic, and legally autocratic he may be, can
do but little without the co-operation of his people. Experience
constantly showed him the fruitlessness of his efforts, but he paid
no attention to its teachings. He had formed once for all his
theory of government, and for thirty years he acted according to it
with all the blindness and obstinacy of a reckless, fanatical
doctrinaire. Even at the close of his reign, when the terrible
logic of facts had proved his system to be a mistake--when his
armies had been defeated, his best fleet destroyed, his ports
blockaded, and his treasury well-nigh emptied--he could not recant.
"My successor," he is reported to have said on his deathbed, "may
do as he pleases, but I cannot change."
Had Nicholas lived in the old patriarchal times, when kings were
the uncontrolled "shepherds of the people," he would perhaps have
been an admirable ruler; but in the nineteenth century he was a
flagrant anachronism. His system of administration completely
broke down. In vain he multiplied formalities and inspectors, and
punished severely the few delinquents who happened by some accident
to be brought to justice; the officials continued to pilfer,
extort, and misgovern in every possible way. Though the country
was reduced to what would be called in Europe "a state of siege,"
the inhabitants might still have said--as they are reported to have
declared a thousand years before--"Our land is great and fertile,
but there is no order in it."
In a nation accustomed to political life and to a certain amount of
self-government, any approach to the system of Nicholas would, of
course, have produced wide-spread dissatisfaction and violent
hatred against the ruling power. But in Russia at that time no
such feelings were awakened. The educated classes--and a fortiori
the uneducated--were profoundly indifferent not only to political
questions, but also to ordinary public affairs, whether local or
Imperial, and were quite content to leave them in the hands of
those who were paid for attending to them. In common with the
uneducated peasantry, the nobles had a boundless respect--one might
almost say a superstitious reverence--not only for the person, but
also for the will of the Tsar, and were ready to show unquestioning
obedience to his commands, so long as these did not interfere with
their accustomed mode of life. The Tsar desired them not to
trouble their heads with political questions, and to leave all
public matters to the care of the Administration; and in this
respect the Imperial will coincided so well with their personal
inclinations that they had no difficulty in complying with it.
When the Tsar ordered those of them who held office to refrain from
extortion and peculation, his orders were not so punctiliously
obeyed, but in this disobedience there was no open opposition--no
assertion of a right to pilfer and extort. As the disobedience
proceeded, not from a feeling of insubordination, but merely from
the weakness that official flesh is heir to, it was not regarded as
very heinous. In the aristocratic circles of St. Petersburg and
Moscow there was the same indifference to political questions and
public affairs. All strove to have the reputation of being "well-
intentioned," which was the first requisite for those who desired
Court favour or advancement in the public service; and those whose
attention was not entirely occupied with official duties, card-
playing, and the ordinary routine of everyday life, cultivated
belles-lettres or the fine arts. In short, the educated classes in
Russia at that time showed a complete indifference to political and
social questions, an apathetic acquiescence in the system of
administration adopted by the Government, and an unreasoning
contentment with the existing state of things.
About the year 1845, when the reaction against Romanticism was
awakening in the reading public an interest in the affairs of real
life,* began to appear what may be called "the men with
aspirations," a little band of generous enthusiasts, strongly
resembling the youth in Longfellow's poem who carries a banner with
the device "Excelsior," and strives ever to climb higher, without
having any clear notion of where he was going or of what he is to
do when he reaches the summit. At first they had little more than
a sentimental enthusiasm for the true, the beautiful, and the good,
and a certain Platonic love for free institutions, liberty,
enlightenment, progress, and everything that was generally
comprehended at that period under the term "liberal." Gradually,
under the influence of current French literature, their ideas
became a little clearer, and they began to look on reality around
them with a critical eye. They could perceive, without much
effort, the unrelenting tyranny of the Administration, the
notorious venality of the tribunals, the reckless squandering of
the public money, the miserable condition of the serfs, the
systematic strangulation of all independent opinion or private
initiative, and, above all, the profound apathy of the upper
classes, who seemed quite content with things as they were.
* Vide supra, p. 377 et seq.
With such ugly facts staring them in the face, and with the habit
of looking at things from the moral point of view, these men could
understand how hollow and false were the soothing or triumphant
phrases of official optimism. They did not, indeed, dare to
express their indignation publicly, for the authorities would allow
no public expression of dissatisfaction with the existing state of
things, but they disseminated their ideas among their friends and
acquaintances by means of conversation and manuscript literature,
and some of them, as university professors and writers in the
periodical Press, contrived to awaken in a certain section of the
young generation an ardent enthusiasm for enlightenment and
progress, and a vague hope that a brighter day was about to dawn.
Not a few sympathised with these new conceptions and aspirations,
but the great majority of the nobles regarded them--especially
after the French Revolution of 1848--as revolutionary and
dangerous. Thus the educated classes became divided into two
sections, which have sometimes been called the Liberals and the
Conservatives, but which might be more properly designated the men
with aspirations and the apathetically contented. These latter
doubtless felt occasionally the irksomeness of the existing
system, but they had always one consolation--if they were oppressed
at home they were feared abroad. The Tsar was at least a thorough
soldier, possessing an enormous and well-equipped army by which he
might at any moment impose his will on Europe. Ever since the
glorious days of 1812, when Napoleon was forced to make an
ignominious retreat from the ruins of Moscow, the belief that the
Russian soldiers were superior to all others, and that the Russian
army was invincible, had become an article of the popular creed;
and the respect which the voice of Nicholas commanded in Western
Europe seemed to prove that the fact was admitted by foreign
nations. In these and similar considerations the apathetically
contented found a justification for their lethargy.
When it became evident that Russia was about to engage in a trial
of strength with the Western Powers, this optimism became general.
"The heavy burdens," it was said, "which the people have had to
bear were necessary to make Russia the first military Power in
Europe, and now the nation will reap the fruits of its long-
suffering and patient resignation. The West will learn that her
boasted liberty and liberal institutions are of little service in
the hour of danger, and the Russians who admire such institutions
will be constrained to admit that a strong, all-directing autocracy
is the only means of preserving national greatness." As the
patriotic fervour and military enthusiasm increased, nothing was
heard but praises of Nicholas and his system. The war was regarded
by many as a kind of crusade--even the Emperor spoke about the
defence of "the native soil and the holy faith"--and the most
exaggerated expectations were entertained of its results. The old
Eastern Question was at last to be solved in accordance with
Russian aspirations, and Nicholas was about to realise Catherine
II.'s grand scheme of driving the Turks out of Europe. The date at
which the troops would arrive at Constantinople was actively
discussed, and a Slavophil poet called on the Emperor to lie down
in Constantinople, and rise up as Tsar of a Panslavonic Empire.
Some enthusiasts even expected the speedy liberation of Jerusalem
from the power of the Infidel. To the enemy, who might possibly
hinder the accomplishment of these schemes, very little attention
was paid. "We have only to throw our hats at them!" (Shapkami
zakidaem) became a favourite expression.
There were, however, a few men in whom the prospect of the coming
struggle awoke very different thoughts and feelings. They could
not share the sanguine expectations of those who were confident of
success. "What preparations have we made," they asked, "for the
struggle with civilisation, which now sends its forces against us?
With all our vast territory and countless population we are
incapable of coping with it. When we talk of the glorious campaign
against Napoleon, we forget that since that time Europe has been
steadily advancing on the road of progress while we have been
standing still. We march not to victory, but to defeat, and the
only grain of consolation which we have is that Russia will learn
by experience a lesson that will be of use to her in the future."*
* These are the words of Granovski.
These prophets of evil found, of course, few disciples, and were
generally regarded as unworthy sons of the Fatherland--almost as
traitors to their country. But their predictions were confirmed by
events. The Allies were victorious in the Crimea, and even the
despised Turks made a successful stand on the line of the Danube.
In spite of the efforts of the Government to suppress all
unpleasant intelligence, it soon became known that the military
organisation was little, if at all, better than the civil
administration--that the individual bravery of soldiers and
officers was neutralised by the incapacity of the generals, the
venality of the officials, and the shameless peculation of the
commissariat department. The Emperor, it was said, had drilled out
of the officers all energy, individuality, and moral force. Almost
the only men who showed judgment, decision, and energy were the
officers of the Black Sea fleet, which had been less subjected to
the prevailing system. As the struggle went on, it became evident
how weak the country really was--how deficient in the resources
necessary to sustain a prolonged conflict. "Another year of war,"
writes an eye-witness in 1855, "and the whole of Southern Russia
will be ruined." To meet the extraordinary demands on the
Treasury, recourse was had to an enormous issue of paper money; but
the rapid depreciation of the currency showed that this resource
would soon be exhausted. Militia regiments were everywhere raised
throughout the country, and many proprietors spent large sums in
equipping volunteer corps; but very soon this enthusiasm cooled
when it was found that the patriotic efforts enriched the jobbers
without inflicting any serious injury on the enemy.
Under the sting of the great national humiliation, the upper
classes awoke from their optimistic resignation. They had borne
patiently the oppression of a semi-military administration, and for
this! The system of Nicholas had been put to a crucial test, and
found wanting. The policy which had sacrificed all to increase the
military power of the Empire was seen to be a fatal error, and the
worthlessness of the drill-sergeant regime was proved by bitter
experience. Those administrative fetters which had for more than a
quarter of a century cramped every spontaneous movement had failed
to fulfil even the narrow purpose for which they had been forged.
They had, indeed, secured a certain external tranquillity during
those troublous times when Europe was convulsed by revolutionary
agitation; but this tranquillity was not that of healthy normal
action, but of death--and underneath the surface lay secret and
rapidly spreading corruption. The army still possessed that
dashing gallantry which it had displayed in the campaigns of
Suvorof, that dogged, stoical bravery which had checked the advance
of Napoleon on the field of Borodino, and that wondrous power of
endurance which had often redeemed the negligence of generals and
the defects of the commissariat; but the result was now not
victory, but defeat. How could this be explained except by the
radical defects of that system which had been long practised with
such inflexible perseverance? The Government had imagined that it
could do everything by its own wisdom and energy, and in reality it
had done nothing, or worse than nothing. The higher officers had
learned only too well to be mere automata; the ameliorations in the
military organisation, on which Nicholas had always bestowed
special attention, were found to exist for the most part only in
the official reports; the shameful exploits of the commissariat
department were such as to excite the indignation of those who had
long lived in an atmosphere of official jobbery and peculation; and
the finances, which people had generally supposed to be in a highly
satisfactory condition, had become seriously crippled by the first
great national effort.
This deep and wide-spread dissatisfaction was not allowed to appear
in the Press, but it found very free expression in the manuscript
literature and in conversation. In almost every house--I mean, of
course, among the educated classes--words were spoken which a few
months before would have seemed treasonable, if not blasphemous.
Philippics and satires in prose and verse were written by the
dozen, and circulated in hundreds of copies. A pasquil on the
Commander in Chief, or a tirade against the Government, was sure to
be eagerly read and warmly approved of. As a specimen of this kind
of literature, and an illustration of the public opinion of the
time, I may translate here one of those metrical tirades. Though
it was never printed, it obtained a wide circulation:
"'God has placed me over Russia,' said the Tsar to us, 'and you
must bow down before me, for my throne is His altar. Trouble not
yourselves with public affairs, for I think for you and watch over
you every hour. My watchful eye detects internal evils and the
machinations of foreign enemies; and I have no need of counsel, for
God inspires me with wisdom. Be proud, therefore, of being my
slaves, O Russians, and regard my will as your law.'
"We listened to these words with deep reverence, and gave a tacit
consent; and what was the result? Under mountains of official
papers real interests were forgotten. The letter of the law was
observed, but negligence and crime were allowed to go unpunished.
While grovelling in the dust before ministers and directors of
departments in the hope of receiving tchins and decorations, the
officials stole unblushingly; and theft became so common that he
who stole the most was the most respected. The merits of officers
were decided at reviews; and he who obtained the rank of General
was supposed capable of becoming at once an able governor, an
excellent engineer, or a most wise senator. Those who were
appointed governors were for the most part genuine satraps, the
scourges of the provinces entrusted to their care. The other
offices were filled up with as little attention to the merits of
the candidates. A stable-boy became Press censor! an Imperial
fool became admiral! Kleinmichel became a count! In a word, the
country was handed over to the tender mercies of a band of robbers.
"And what did we Russians do all this time?
"We Russians slept! With groans the peasant paid his yearly dues;
with groans the proprietor mortgaged the second half of his estate;
groaning, we all paid our heavy tribute to the officials.
Occasionally, with a grave shaking of the head, we remarked in a
whisper that it was a shame and a disgrace--that there was no
justice in the courts--that millions were squandered on Imperial
tours, kiosks, and pavilions--that everything was wrong; and then,
with an easy conscience, we sat down to our rubber, praised the
acting of Rachel, criticised the singing of Frezzolini, bowed low
to venal magnates, and squabbled with each other for advancement in
the very service which we so severely condemned. If we did not
obtain the place we wished we retired to our ancestral estates,
where we talked of the crops, fattened in indolence and gluttony,
and lived a genuine animal life. If any one, amidst the general
lethargy, suddenly called upon us to rise and fight for the truth
and for Russia, how ridiculous did he appear! How cleverly the
Pharisaical official ridiculed him, and how quickly the friends of
yesterday showed him the cold shoulder! Under the anathema of
public opinion, in some distant Siberian mine he recognised what a
heinous sin it was to disturb the heavy sleep of apathetic slaves.
Soon he was forgotten, or remembered as an unfortunate madman; and
the few who said, 'Perhaps after all he was right,' hastened to
add, 'but that is none of our business.'
"But amidst all this we had at least one consolation, one thing to
be proud of--the might of Russia in the assembly of kings. 'What
need we care,' we said, 'for the reproaches of foreign nations? We
are stronger than those who reproach us.' And when at great
reviews the stately regiments marched past with waving standards,
glittering helmets, and sparkling bayonets, when we heard the loud
hurrah with which the troops greeted the Emperor, then our hearts
swelled with patriotic pride, and we were ready to repeat the words
of the poet--
"Strong is our native country, and great the Russian Tsar."
Then British statesmen, in company with the crowned conspirator of
France, and with treacherous Austria, raised Western Europe against
us, but we laughed scornfully at the coming storm. 'Let the
nations rave,' we said; 'we have no cause to be afraid. The Tsar
doubtless foresaw all, and has long since made the necessary
preparations.' Boldly we went forth to fight, and confidently
awaited the moment of the struggle.
"And lo! after all our boasting we were taken by surprise, and
caught unawares, as by a robber in the dark. The sleep of innate
stupidity blinded our Ambassadors, and our Foreign Minister sold us
to our enemies.* Where were our millions of soldiers? Where was
the well-considered plan of defence? One courier brought the order
to advance; another brought the order to retreat; and the army
wandered about without definite aim or purpose. With loss and
shame we retreated from the forts of Silistria, and the pride of
Russia was humbled before the Hapsburg eagle. The soldiers fought
well, but the parade-admiral (Menshikof)--the amphibious hero of
lost battles--did not know the geography of his own country, and
sent his troops to certain destruction.
* Many people at that time imagined that Count Nesselrode, who was
then Minister for Foreign Affairs, was a traitor to his adopted
country.
"Awake, O Russia! Devoured by foreign enemies, crushed by slavery,
shamefully oppressed by stupid authorities and spies, awaken from
your long sleep of ignorance and apathy! You have been long enough
held in bondage by the successors of the Tartar Khan. Stand
forward calmly before the throne of the despot, and demand from him
an account of the national disaster. Say to him boldly that his
throne is not the altar of God, and that God did not condemn us to
be slaves. Russia entrusted to you, O Tsar, the supreme power, and
you were as a God upon earth. And what have you done? Blinded by
ignorance and passion, you have lusted after power and have
forgotten Russia. You have spent your life in reviewing troops, in
modifying uniforms, and in appending your signature to the
legislative projects of ignorant charlatans. You created the
despicable race of Press censors, in order to sleep in peace--in
order not to know the wants and not to hear the groans of the
people--in order not to listen to Truth. You buried Truth, rolled
a great stone to the door of the sepulchre, placed a strong guard
over it, and said in the pride of your heart: For her there is no
resurrection! But the third day has dawned, and Truth has arisen
from the dead.
"Stand forward, O Tsar, before the judgment-seat of history and of
God! You have mercilessly trampled Truth under foot, you have
denied Freedom, you have been the slave of your own passions. By
your pride and obstinacy you have exhausted Russia and raised the
world in arms against us. Bow down before your brethren and humble
yourself in the dust! Crave pardon and ask advice! Throw yourself
into the arms of the people! There is now no other salvation!"
The innumerable tirades of which the above is a fair specimen were
not very remarkable for literary merit or political wisdom. For
the most part they were simply bits of bombastic rhetoric couched
in doggerel rhyme, and they have consequently been long since
consigned to well-merited oblivion--so completely that it is now
difficult to obtain copies of them.* They have, however, an
historical interest, because they express in a more or less
exaggerated form the public opinion and prevalent ideas of the
educated classes at that moment. In order to comprehend their real
significance, we must remember that the writers and readers were
not a band of conspirators, but ordinary, respectable, well-
intentioned people, who never for a moment dreamed of embarking in
revolutionary designs. It was the same society that had been a few
months before so indifferent to all political questions, and even
now there was no clear conception as to how the loud-sounding
phrases could be translated into action. We can imagine the
comical discomfiture of those who read and listened to these
appeals, if the "despot" had obeyed their summons, and suddenly
appeared before them.
* I am indebted for the copies which I possess to friends who
copied and collected these pamphlets at the time.
Was the movement, then, merely an outburst of childish petulance?
Certainly not. The public were really and seriously convinced that
things were all wrong, and they were seriously and enthusiastically
desirous that a new and better order of things should be
introduced. It must be said to their honour that they did not
content themselves with accusing and lampooning the individuals who
were supposed to be the chief culprits. On the contrary, they
looked reality boldly in the face, made a public confession of
their past sins, sought conscientiously the causes which had
produced the recent disasters, and endeavoured to find means by
which such calamities might be prevented in the future. The public
feeling and aspirations were not strong enough to conquer the
traditional respect for the Imperial will and create an open
opposition to the Autocratic Power, but they were strong enough to
do great things by aiding the Government, if the Emperor
voluntarily undertook a series of radical reforms.
What Nicholas would have done, had he lived, in face of this
national awakening, it is difficult to say. He declared, indeed,
that he could not change, and we can readily believe that his proud
spirit would have scorned to make concessions to the principles
which he had always condemned; but he gave decided indications in
the last days of his life that his old faith in his system was
somewhat shaken, and he did not exhort his son to persevere in the
path along which he himself had forced his way with such obstinate
consistency. It is useless, however, to speculate on
possibilities. Whilst the Government had still to concentrate all
its energies on the defence of the country, the Iron Tsar died, and
was succeeded by his son, a man of a very different type.
Of a kind-hearted, humane disposition, sincerely desirous of
maintaining the national honour, but singularly free from military
ambition and imbued with no fanatical belief in the drill-sergeant
system of government, Alexander II. was by no means insensible to
the spirit of the time. He had, however, none of the sentimental
enthusiasm for liberal institutions which had characterised his
uncle, Alexander I. On the contrary, he had inherited from his
father a strong dislike to sentimentalism and rhetoric of all
kinds. This dislike, joined to a goodly portion of sober common-
sense, a limited confidence in his own judgment, and a
consciousness of enormous responsibility, prevented him from being
carried away by the prevailing excitement. With all that was
generous and humane in the movement he thoroughly sympathised, and
he allowed the popular ideas and aspirations to find free
utterance; but he did not at once commit himself to any definite
policy, and carefully refrained from all exaggerated expressions of
reforming zeal.
As soon, however, as peace had been concluded, there were
unmistakable symptoms that the rigorously repressive system of
Nicholas was about to be abandoned. In the manifesto announcing
the termination of hostilities the Emperor expressed his conviction
that by the combined efforts of the Government and the people, the
public administration would be improved, and that justice and mercy
would reign in the courts of law. Apparently as a preparation for
this great work, to be undertaken by the Tsar and his people in
common, the ministers began to take the public into their
confidence, and submitted to public criticism many official data
which had hitherto been regarded as State secrets. The Minister of
the Interior, for instance, in his annual report, spoke almost in
the tone of a penitent, and confessed openly that the morality of
the officials under his orders left much to be desired. He
declared that the Emperor now showed a paternal confidence in his
people, and as a proof of this he mentioned the significant fact
that 9,000 persons had been liberated from police supervision. The
other branches of the Administration underwent a similar
transformation. The haughty, dictatorial tone which had hitherto
been used by superiors to their subordinates, and by all ranks of
officials to the public, was replaced by one of considerate
politeness. About the same time those of the Decembrists who were
still alive were pardoned. The restrictions regarding the number
of students in each university were abolished, the difficulty of
obtaining foreign passports was removed, and the Press censors
became singularly indulgent. Though no decided change had been
made in the laws, it was universally felt that the spirit of
Nicholas was no more.
The public, anxiously seeking after a sign, readily took these
symptoms of change as a complete confirmation of their ardent
hopes, and leaped at once to the conclusion that a vast, all-
embracing system of radical reform was about to be undertaken--not
secretly by the Administration, as had been the custom in the
preceding reign when any little changes had to be made, but
publicly, by the Government and the people in common. "The heart
trembles with joy," said one of the leading organs of the Press,
"in expectation of the great social reforms that are about to be
effected--reforms that are thoroughly in accordance with the
spirit, the wishes, and the expectations of the public." "The old
harmony and community of feeling," said another, "which has always
existed between the government and the people, save during short
exceptional periods, has been fully re-established. The absence of
all sentiment of caste, and the feeling of common origin and
brotherhood which binds all classes of the Russian people into a
homogeneous whole, will enable Russia to accomplish peacefully and
without effort not only those great reforms which cost Europe
centuries of struggle and bloodshed, but also many which the
nations of the West are still unable to accomplish, in consequence
of feudal traditions and caste prejudices." The past was depicted
in the blackest colours, and the nation was called upon to begin a
new and glorious epoch of its history. "We have to struggle," it
was said, "in the name of the highest truth against egotism and the
puny interests of the moment; and we ought to prepare our children
from their infancy to take part in that struggle which awaits every
honest man. We have to thank the war for opening our eyes to the
dark sides of our political and social organisation, and it is now
our duty to profit by the lesson. But it must not be supposed that
the Government can, single-handed, remedy the defects. The
destinies of Russia are, as it were, a stranded vessel which the
captain and crew cannot move, and which nothing, indeed, but the
rising tide of the national life can raise and float."
Hearts beat quicker at the sound of these calls to action. Many
heard this new teaching, if we may believe a contemporary
authority, "with tears in their eyes"; then, "raising boldly their
heads, they made a solemn vow that they would act honourably,
perseveringly, fearlessly." Some of those who had formerly yielded
to the force of circumstances now confessed their misdemeanours
with bitterness of heart. "Tears of repentance," said a popular
poet, "give relief, and call us to new exploits." Russia was
compared to a strong giant who awakes from sleep, stretches his
brawny limbs, collects his thoughts, and prepares to atone for his
long inactivity by feats of untold prowess. All believed, or at
least assumed, that the recognition of defects would necessarily
entail their removal. When an actor in one of the St. Petersburg
theatres shouted from the stage, "Let us proclaim throughout all
Russia that the time has come for tearing up evil by the roots!"
the audience gave way to the most frantic enthusiasm. "Altogether
a joyful time," says one who took part in the excitement, "as when,
after the long winter, the genial breath of spring glides over the
cold, petrified earth, and nature awakens from her deathlike sleep.
Speech, long restrained by police and censorial regulations, now
flows smoothly, majestically, like a mighty river that has just
been freed from ice."
Under these influences a multitude of newspapers and periodicals
were founded, and the current literature entirely changed its
character. The purely literary and historical questions which had
hitherto engaged the attention of the reading public were thrown
aside and forgotten, unless they could be made to illustrate some
principle of political or social science. Criticisms on style and
diction, explanations of aesthetic principles, metaphysical
discussions--all this seemed miserable trifling to men who wished
to devote themselves to gigantic practical interests. "Science,"
it was said, "has now descended from the heights of philosophic
abstraction into the arena of real life." The periodicals were
accordingly filled with articles on railways, banks, free-trade,
education, agriculture, communal institutions, local self-
government, joint-stock companies, and with crushing philippics
against personal and national vanity, inordinate luxury,
administrative tyranny, and the habitual peculation of the
officials. This last-named subject received special attention.
During the preceding reign any attempt to criticise publicly the
character or acts of an official was regarded as a very heinous
offence; now there was a deluge of sketches, tales, comedies, and
monologues, describing the corruption of the Administration, and
explaining the ingenious devices by which the tchinovniks increased
their scanty salaries. The public would read nothing that had not
a direct or indirect bearing on the questions of the day, and
whatever had such a bearing was read with interest. It did not
seem at all strange that a drama should be written in defence of
free-trade, or a poem in advocacy of some peculiar mode of
taxation; that an author should expound his political ideas in a
tale, and his antagonist reply by a comedy. A few men of the old
school protested feebly against this "prostitution of art," but
they received little attention, and the doctrine that art should be
cultivated for its own sake was scouted as an invention of
aristocratic indolence. Here is an ipsa pinxit of the literature
of the time: "Literature has come to look at Russia with her own
eyes, and sees that the idyllic romantic personages which the poets
formerly loved to describe have no objective existence. Having
taken off her French glove, she offers her hand to the rude, hard-
working labourer, and observing lovingly Russian village life, she
feels herself in her native land. The writers of the present have
analysed the past, and, having separated themselves from
aristocratic litterateurs and aristocratic society, have demolished
their former idols."
By far the most influential periodical at the commencement of the
movement was the Kolokol, or Bell, a fortnightly journal published
in London by Herzen, who was at that time an important personage
among the political refugees. Herzen was a man of education and
culture, with ultra-radical opinions, and not averse to using
revolutionary methods of reform when he considered them necessary.
His intimate relations with many of the leading men in Russia
enabled him to obtain secret information of the most important and
varied kind, and his sparkling wit, biting satire, and clear,
terse, brilliant style secured him a large number of readers. He
seemed to know everything that was done in the ministries and even
in the Cabinet of the Emperor,* and he exposed most mercilessly
every abuse that came to his knowledge. We who are accustomed to
free political discussion can hardly form a conception of the
avidity with which his articles were read, and the effect which
they produced. Though strictly prohibited by the Press censure,
the Kolokol found its way across the frontier in thousands of
copies, and was eagerly perused and commented on by all ranks of
the educated classes. The Emperor himself received it regularly,
and high-priced delinquents examined it with fear and trembling.
In this way Herzen was for some years, though an exile, an
important political personage, and did much to awaken and keep up
the reform enthusiasm.
* As an illustration of this, the following anecdote is told: One
number of the Kolokol contained a violent attack on an important
personage of the court, and the accused, or some one of his
friends, considered it advisable to have a copy specially printed
for the Emperor without the objectionable article. The Emperor did
not at first discover the trick, but shortly afterwards he received
from London a polite note containing the article which had been
omitted, and informing him how he had been deceived.
But where were the Conservatives all this time? How came it that
for two or three years no voice was raised and no protest made even
against the rhetorical exaggerations of the new-born liberalism?
Where were the representatives of the old regime, who had been so
thoroughly imbued with the spirit of Nicholas? Where were those
ministers who had systematically extinguished the least indication
of private initiative, those "satraps" who had stamped out the
least symptom of insubordination or discontent, those Press censors
who had diligently suppressed the mildest expression of liberal
opinion, those thousands of well-intentioned proprietors who had
regarded as dangerous free-thinkers and treasonable republicans all
who ventured to express dissatisfaction with the existing state of
things? A short time before, the Conservatives composed at least
nine-tenths of the upper classes, and now they had suddenly and
mysteriously disappeared.
It is scarcely necessary to say that in a country accustomed to
political life, such a sudden, unopposed revolution in public
opinion could not possibly take place. The key to the mystery lies
in the fact that for centuries Russia had known nothing of
political life or political parties. Those who were sometimes
called Conservatives were in reality not at all Conservatives in
our sense of the term. If we say that they had a certain amount of
conservatism, we must add that it was of the latent, passive,
unreasoned kind--the fruit of indolence and apathy. Their
political creed had but one article: Thou shalt love the Tsar with
all thy might, and carefully abstain from all resistance to his
will--especially when it happens that the Tsar is a man of the
Nicholas type. So long as Nicholas lived they had passively
acquiesced in his system--active acquiescence had been neither
demanded nor desired--but when he died, the system of which he was
the soul died with him. What then could they seek to defend? They
were told that the system which they had been taught to regard as
the sheet-anchor of the State was in reality the chief cause of the
national disasters; and to this they could make no reply, because
they had no better explanation of their own to offer. They were
convinced that the Russian soldier was the best soldier in the
world, and they knew that in the recent war the army had not been
victorious; the system, therefore, must be to blame. They were
told that a series of gigantic reforms was necessary in order to
restore Russia to her proper place among the nations; and to this
they could make no answer, for they had never studied such abstract
questions. And one thing they did know: that those who hesitated
to admit the necessity of gigantic reforms were branded by the
Press as ignorant, narrow-minded, prejudiced, and egotistical, and
were held up to derision as men who did not know the most
elementary principles of political and economic science. Freely
expressed public opinion was such a new phenomenon in Russia that
the Press was able for some time to exercise a "Liberal" tyranny
scarcely less severe than the "Conservative" tyranny of the censors
in the preceding reign. Men who would have stood fire gallantly on
the field of battle quailed before the poisoned darts of Herzen in
the Kolokol. Under such circumstances, even the few who possessed
some vague Conservative convictions refrained from publicly
expressing them.
The men who had played a more or less active part during the
preceding reign, and who might therefore be expected to have
clearer and deeper convictions, were specially incapable of
offering opposition to the prevailing Liberal enthusiasm. Their
Conservatism was of quite as limp a kind as that of the landed
proprietors who were not in the public service, for under Nicholas
the higher a man was placed the less likely was he to have
political convictions of any kind outside the simple political
creed above referred to. Besides this, they belonged to that class
which was for the moment under the anathema of public opinion, and
they had drawn direct personal advantage from the system which was
now recognised as the chief cause of the national disasters.
For a time the name of tchinovnik became a term of reproach and
derision, and the position of those who bore it was comically
painful. They strove to prove that, though they held a post in the
public service, they were entirely free from the tchinovnik spirit--
that there was nothing of the genuine tchinovnik about them.
Those who had formerly paraded their tchin (official rank) on all
occasions, in season and out of season, became half ashamed to
admit that they had the rank of General; for the title no longer
commanded respect, and had become associated with all that was
antiquated, formal, and stupid. Among the young generation it was
used most disrespectfully as equivalent to "pompous blockhead."
Zealous officials who had lately regarded the acquisition of Stars
and Orders as among the chief ends of man, were fain to conceal
those hard-won trophies, lest some cynical "Liberal" might notice
them and make them the butt of his satire. "Look at the depth of
humiliation to which you have brought the country"--such was the
chorus of reproach that was ever ringing in their ears--"with your
red tape, your Chinese formalism, and your principle of lifeless,
unreasoning, mechanical obedience! You asserted constantly that
you were the only true patriots, and branded with the name of
traitor those who warned you of the insane folly of your conduct.
You see now what it has all come to. The men whom you helped to
send to the mines turn out to have been the true patriots."*
* It was a common saying at that time that nearly all the best men
in Russia had spent a part of their lives in Siberia, and it was
proposed to publish a biographical dictionary of remarkable men, in
which every article was to end thus: "Exiled to ---- in 18--." I
am not aware how far the project was seriously entertained, but, of
course, the book was never published.
And to these reproaches what could they reply? Like a child who
has in his frolics inadvertently set the house on fire, they could
only look contrite, and say they did not mean it. They had simply
accepted without criticism the existing order of things, and ranged
themselves among those who were officially recognised as "the well-
intentioned." If they had always avoided the Liberals, and perhaps
helped to persecute them, it was simply because all "well-
intentioned" people said that Liberals were "restless" and
dangerous to the State. Those who were not convinced of their
errors simply kept silence, but the great majority passed over to
the ranks of the Progressists, and many endeavoured to redeem their
past by showing extreme zeal for the Liberal cause.
In explanation of this extraordinary outburst of reform enthusiasm,
we must further remember that the Russian educated classes, in
spite of the severe northern climate which is supposed to make the
blood circulate slowly, are extremely impulsive. They are fettered
by no venerable historical prejudices, and are wonderfully
sensitive to the seductive influence of grandiose projects,
especially when these excite the patriotic feelings. Then there
was the simple force of reaction--the rebound which naturally
followed the terrific compression of the preceding reign. Without
disrespect, the Russians of that time may be compared to schoolboys
who have just escaped from the rigorous discipline of a severe
schoolmaster. In the first moments of freedom it was supposed that
there would be no more discipline or compulsion. The utmost
respect was to be shown to "human dignity," and every Russian was
to act spontaneously and zealously at the great work of national
regeneration. All thirsted for reforming activity. The men in
authority were inundated with projects of reform--some of them
anonymous, and others from obscure individuals; some of them
practical, and very many wildly fantastic. Even the grammarians
showed their sympathy with the spirit of the time by proposing to
expel summarily all redundant letters from the Russian alphabet!
The fact that very few people had clear, precise ideas as to what
was to be done did not prevent, but rather tended to increase, the
reform enthusiasm. All had at least one common feeling--dislike to
what had previously existed. It was only when it became necessary
to forsake pure negation, and to create something, that the
conceptions became clearer, and a variety of opinions appeared. At
the first moment there was merely unanimity in negation, and an
impulsive enthusiasm for beneficent reforms in general.
The first specific proposals were direct deductions from the
lessons taught by the war. The war had shown in a terrible way the
disastrous consequences of having merely primitive means of
communication; the Press and the public began, accordingly, to
speak about the necessity of constructing railways, roads and
river-steamers. The war had shown that a country which has not
developed its natural resources very soon becomes exhausted if it
has to make a great national effort; accordingly the public and the
Press talked about the necessity of developing the natural
resources, and about the means by which this desirable end might be
attained. It had been shown by the war that a system of education
which tends to make men mere apathetic automata cannot produce even
a good army; accordingly the public and the Press began to discuss
the different systems of education and the numerous questions of
pedagogical science. It had been shown by the war that the best
intentions of a Government will necessarily be frustrated if the
majority of the officials are dishonest or incapable; accordingly
the public and the Press began to speak about the paramount
necessity of reforming the Administration in all its branches.
It must not, however, be supposed that in thus laying to heart the
lessons taught by the war and endeavouring to profit by them, the
Russians were actuated by warlike feelings, and desired to avenge
themselves as soon as possible on their victorious enemies. On the
contrary, the whole movement and the spirit which animated it were
eminently pacific. Prince Gortchakof's saying, "La Russie ne boude
pas, elle se recueille," was more than a diplomatic repartee--it
was a true and graphic statement of the case. Though the Russians
are very inflammable, and can be very violent when their patriotic
feelings are aroused, they are, individually and as a nation,
singularly free from rancour and the spirit of revenge. After the
termination of hostilities they really bore little malice towards
the Western Powers, except towards Austria, which was believed to
have been treacherous and ungrateful to the country that had saved
her in 1849. Their patriotism now took the form, not of revenge,
but of a desire to raise their country to the level of the Western
nations. If they thought of military matters at all, they assumed
that military power would be obtained as a natural and inevitable
result of high civilisation and good government.
As a first step towards the realisation of the vast schemes
contemplated, voluntary associations began to be formed for
industrial and commercial purposes, and a law was issued for the
creation of limited liability companies. In the space of two years
forty-seven companies of this kind were founded, with a combined
capital of 358 millions of roubles. To understand the full
significance of these figures, we must know that from the founding
of the first joint-stock company in 1799 down to 1853 only twenty-
six companies had been formed, and their united capital amounted
only to thirty-two millions of roubles. Thus in the space of two
years (1857-58) eleven times as much capital was subscribed to
joint-stock companies as had been subscribed during half a century
previous to the war. The most exaggerated expectations were
entertained as to the national and private advantages which must
necessarily result from these undertakings, and it became a
patriotic duty to subscribe liberally. The periodical literature
depicted in glowing terms the marvellous results that had been
obtained in other countries by the principle of co-operation, and
sanguine readers believed that they had discovered a patriotic way
of speedily becoming rich.
These were, however, mere secondary matters, and the public were
anxiously waiting for the Government to begin the grand reforming
campaign. When the educated classes awoke to the necessity of
great reforms, there was no clear conception as to how the great
work should be undertaken. There was so much to be done that it
was no easy matter to decide what should be done first.
Administrative, judicial, social, economical, financial, and
political reforms seemed all equally pressing. Gradually, however,
it became evident that precedence must be given to the question of
serfage. It was absurd to speak about progress, humanitarianism,
education, self-government, equality in the eye of the law, and
similar matters, so long as one half of the population was excluded
from the enjoyment of ordinary civil rights. So long as serfage
existed it was mere mockery to talk about re-organising Russia
according to the latest results of political and social science.
How could a system of even-handed justice be introduced when twenty
millions of the peasantry were subject to the arbitrary will of the
landed proprietors? How could agricultural or industrial progress
be made without free labour? How could the Government take active
measures for the spread of national education when it had no direct
control over one-half of the peasantry? Above all, how could it be
hoped that a great moral regeneration could take place, so long as
the nation voluntarily retained the stigma of serfage and slavery?
All this was very generally felt by the educated classes, but no
one ventured to raise the question until it should be known what
were the views of the Emperor on the subject. How the question was
gradually raised, how it was treated by the nobles, and how it was
ultimately solved by the famous law of February 19th (March 3d),
1861,* I now propose to relate.
* February 19th according to the old style, which is still used in
Russia, and March 3d according to our method of reckoning.
CHAPTER XXVIII
THE SERFS
The Rural Population in Ancient Times--The Peasantry in the
Eighteenth Century--How Was This Change Effected?--The Common
Explanation Inaccurate--Serfage the Result of Permanent Economic
and Political Causes--Origin of the Adscriptio Glebae--Its
Consequences--Serf Insurrection--Turning-point in the History of
Serfage--Serfage in Russia and in Western Europe--State Peasants--
Numbers and Geographical Distribution of the Serf Population--Serf
Dues--Legal and Actual Power of the Proprietors--The Serfs' Means
of Defence--Fugitives--Domestic Serfs--Strange Advertisements in
the Moscow Gazette--Moral Influence of Serfage.
Before proceeding to describe the Emancipation, it may be well to
explain briefly how the Russian peasants became serfs, and what
serfage in Russia really was.
In the earliest period of Russian history the rural population was
composed of three distinct classes. At the bottom of the scale
stood the slaves, who were very numerous. Their numbers were
continually augmented by prisoners of war, by freemen who
voluntarily sold themselves as slaves, by insolvent debtors, and by
certain categories of criminals. Immediately above the slaves were
the free agricultural labourers, who had no permanent domicile, but
wandered about the country and settled temporarily where they
happened to find work and satisfactory remuneration. In the third
place, distinct from these two classes, and in some respects higher
in the social scale, were the peasants properly so called.*
* My chief authority for the early history of the peasantry has
been Belaef, "Krestyanye na Rusi," Moscow, 1860; a most able and
conscientious work.
These peasants proper, who may be roughly described as small
farmers or cottiers, were distinguished from the free agricultural
labourers in two respects: they were possessors of land in property
or usufruct, and they were members of a rural Commune. The
Communes were free primitive corporations which elected their
office-bearers from among the heads of families, and sent delegates
to act as judges or assessors in the Prince's Court. Some of the
Communes possessed land of their own, whilst others were settled on
the estates of the landed proprietors or on the extensive domains
of the monasteries. In the latter case the peasant paid a fixed
yearly rent in money, in produce, or in labour, according to the
terms of his contract with the proprietor or the monastery; but he
did not thereby sacrifice in any way his personal liberty. As soon
as he had fulfilled the engagements stipulated in the contract and
had settled accounts with the owner of the land, he was free to
change his domicile as he pleased.
If we turn now from these early times to the eighteenth century, we
find that the position of the rural population has entirely changed
in the interval. The distinction between slaves, agricultural
labourers, and peasants has completely disappeared. All three
categories have melted together into a common class, called serfs,
who are regarded as the property of the landed proprietors or of
the State. "The proprietors sell their peasants and domestic
servants not even in families, but one by one, like cattle, as is
done nowhere else in the whole world, from which practice there is
not a little wailing."* And yet the Government, whilst professing
to regret the existence of the practice, takes no energetic
measures to prevent it. On the contrary, it deprives the serfs of
all legal protection, and expressly commands that if any serf shall
dare to present a petition against his master, he shall be punished
with the knout and transported for life to the mines of Nertchinsk.
(Ukaz of August 22d, 1767.**)
* These words are taken from an Imperial ukaz of April 15th, 1721.
Polnoye Sobranye Zakonov, No. 3,770.
** This is an ukaz of the liberal and tolerant Catherine! How she
reconciled it with her respect and admiration for Beccaria's humane
views on criminal law she does not explain.
How did this important change take place, and how is it to be
explained?
If we ask any educated Russian who has never specially occupied
himself with historical investigations regarding the origin of
serfage in Russia, he will probably reply somewhat in this fashion:
"In Russia slavery has never existed (!), and even serfage in the
West-European sense has never been recognised by law! In ancient
times the rural population was completely free, and every peasant
might change his domicile on St. George's Day--that is to say, at
the end of the agricultural year. This right of migration was
abolished by Tsar Boris Godunof--who, by the way, was half a Tartar
and more than half a usurper--and herein lies the essence of
serfage in the Russian sense. The peasants have never been the
property of the landed proprietors, but have always been personally
free; and the only legal restriction on their liberty was that they
were not allowed to change their domicile without the permission of
the proprietor. If so-called serfs were sometimes sold, the
practice was simply an abuse not justified by legislation."
This simple explanation, in which may be detected a note of
patriotic pride, is almost universally accepted in Russia; but it
contains, like most popular conceptions of the distant past, a
curious mixture of fact and fiction. Serious historical
investigation tends to show that the power of the proprietors over
the peasants came into existence, not suddenly, as the result of an
ukaz, but gradually, as a consequence of permanent economic and
political causes, and that Boris Godunof was not more to blame than
many of his predecessors and successors.*
* See especially Pobedonostsef, in the Russki Vestnik, 1858, No.
11, and "Istoritcheskiya izsledovaniya i statyi" (St. Petersburg,
1876), by the same author; also Pogodin, in the Russkaya Beseda,
1858, No. 4.
Although the peasants in ancient Russia were free to wander about
as they chose, there appeared at a very early period--long before
the reign of Boris Godunof--a decided tendency in the Princes, in
the proprietors, and in the Communes, to prevent migration. This
tendency will be easily understood if we remember that land without
labourers is useless, and that in Russia at that time the
population was small in comparison with the amount of reclaimed and
easily reclaimable land. The Prince desired to have as many
inhabitants as possible in his principality, because the amount of
his regular revenues depended on the number of the population. The
landed proprietor desired to have as many peasants as possible on
his estate, to till for him the land which he reserved for his own
use, and to pay him for the remainder a yearly rent in money,
produce, or labour. The free Communes desired to have a number of
members sufficient to keep the whole of the Communal land under
cultivation, because each Commune had to pay yearly to the Prince a
fixed sum in money or agricultural produce, and the greater the
number of able-bodied members, the less each individual had to pay.
To use the language of political economy, the Princes, the landed
proprietors, and the free Communes all appeared as buyers in the
labour market; and the demand was far in excess of the supply.
Nowadays when young colonies or landed proprietors in an outlying
corner of the world are similarly in need of labour, they seek to
supply the want by organising a regular system of importing
labourers--using illegal violent means, such as kidnapping
expeditions, merely as an exceptional expedient. In old Russia any
such regularly organised system was impossible, and consequently
illegal or violent measures were not the exception, but the rule.
The chief practical advantage of the frequent military expeditions
for those who took part in them was the acquisition of prisoners of
war, who were commonly transformed into slaves by their captors.
If it be true, as some assert, that only unbaptised prisoners were
legally considered lawful booty, it is certain that in practice,
before the unification of the principalities under the Tsars of
Moscow, little distinction was made in this respect between
unbaptised foreigners and Orthodox Russians.* A similar method was
sometimes employed for the acquisition of free peasants: the more
powerful proprietors organised kidnapping expeditions, and carried
off by force the peasants settled on the land of their weaker
neighbours.
* On this subject see Tchitcherin, "Opyty po istorii Russkago
prava," Moscow, 1858, p. 162 et seq.; and Lokhvitski, "O plennykh
po drevnemu Russkomu pravu," Moscow, 1855.
Under these circumstances it was only natural that those who
possessed this valuable commodity should do all in their power to
keep it. Many, if not all, of the free Communes adopted the simple
measure of refusing to allow a member to depart until he had found
some one to take his place. The proprietors never, so far as we
know, laid down formally such a principle, but in practice they did
all in their power to retain the peasants actually settled on their
estates. For this purpose some simply employed force, whilst
others acted under cover of legal formalities. The peasant who
accepted land from a proprietor rarely brought with him the
necessary implements, cattle, and capital to begin at once his
occupations, and to feed himself and his family till the ensuing
harvest. He was obliged, therefore, to borrow from his landlord,
and the debt thus contracted was easily converted into a means of
preventing his departure if he wished to change his domicile. We
need not enter into further details. The proprietors were the
capitalists of the time. Frequent bad harvests, plagues, fires,
military raids, and similar misfortunes often reduced even
prosperous peasants to beggary. The muzhik was probably then, as
now, only too ready to accept a loan without taking the necessary
precautions for repaying it. The laws relating to debt were
terribly severe, and there was no powerful judicial organisation to
protect the weak. If we remember all this, we shall not be
surprised to learn that a considerable part of the peasantry were
practically serfs before serfage was recognised by law.
So long as the country was broken up into independent
principalities, and each land-owner was almost an independent
Prince on his estate, the peasants easily found a remedy for these
abuses in flight. They fled to a neighbouring proprietor who could
protect them from their former landlord and his claims, or they
took refuge in a neighbouring principality, where they were, of
course, still safer. All this was changed when the independent
principalities were transformed into the Tsardom of Muscovy. The
Tsars had new reasons for opposing the migration of the peasants
and new means for preventing it. The old Princes had simply given
grants of land to those who served them, and left the grantee to do
with his land what seemed good to him; the Tsars, on the contrary,
gave to those who served them merely the usufruct of a certain
quantity of land, and carefully proportioned the quantity to the
rank and the obligations of the receiver. In this change there was
plainly a new reason for fixing the peasants to the soil. The real
value of a grant depended not so much on the amount of land as on
the number of peasants settled on it, and hence any migration of
the population was tantamount to a removal of the ancient
landmarks--that is to say, to a disturbance of the arrangements
made by the Tsar. Suppose, for instance, that the Tsar granted to
a Boyar or some lesser dignitary an estate on which were settled
twenty peasant families, and that afterwards ten of these emigrated
to neighbouring proprietors. In this case the recipient might
justly complain that he had lost half of his estate--though the
amount of land was in no way diminished--and that he was
consequently unable to fulfil his obligations. Such complaints
would be rarely, if ever, made by the great dignitaries, for they
had the means of attracting peasants to their estates;* but the
small proprietors had good reason to complain, and the Tsar was
bound to remove their grievances. The attaching of the peasants to
the soil was, in fact, the natural consequence of feudal tenures--
an integral part of the Muscovite political system. The Tsar
compelled the nobles to serve him, and was unable to pay them in
money. He was obliged, therefore, to procure for them some other
means of livelihood. Evidently the simplest method of solving the
difficulty was to give them land, with a certain number of
labourers, and to prevent the labourers from migrating.
* There are plain indications in the documents of the time that the
great dignitaries were at first hostile to the adscriptio glebae.
We find a similar phenomenon at a much more recent date in Little
Russia. Long after serfage had been legalised in that region by
Catherine II., the great proprietors, such as Rumyantsef,
Razumofski, Bezborodko, continued to attract to their estates the
peasants of the smaller proprietors. See the article of Pogodin in
the Russkaya Beseda, 1858, No. 4, p. 154.
Towards the free Communes the Tsar had to act in the same way for
similar reasons. The Communes, like the nobles, had obligations to
the Sovereign, and could not fulfil them if the peasants were
allowed to migrate from one locality to another. They were, in a
certain sense, the property of the Tsar, and it was only natural
that the Tsar should do for himself what he had done for his
nobles.
With these new reasons for fixing the peasants to the soil came, as
has been said, new means of preventing migration. Formerly it was
an easy matter to flee to a neighbouring principality, but now all
the principalities were combined under one ruler, and the
foundations of a centralised administration were laid. Severe
fugitive laws were issued against those who attempted to change
their domicile and against the proprietors who should harbour the
runaways. Unless the peasant chose to face the difficulties of
"squatting" in the inhospitable northern forests, or resolved to
brave the dangers of the steppe, he could nowhere escape the heavy
hand of Moscow.*
* The above account of the origin of serfage in Russia is founded
on a careful examination of the evidence which we possess on the
subject, but I must not conceal the fact that some of the
statements are founded on inference rather than on direct,
unequivocal documentary evidence. The whole question is one of
great difficulty, and will in all probability not be satisfactorily
solved until a large number of the old local Land-Registers
(Pistsoviya Knigi) have been published and carefully studied.
The indirect consequences of thus attaching the peasants to the
soil did not at once become apparent. The serf retained all the
civil rights he had hitherto enjoyed, except that of changing his
domicile. He could still appear before the courts of law as a free
man, freely engage in trade or industry, enter into all manner of
contracts, and rent land for cultivation.
But as time wore on, the change in the legal relation between the
two classes became apparent in real life. In attaching the
peasantry to the soil, the Government had been so thoroughly
engrossed with the direct financial aim that it entirely
overlooked, or wilfully shut its eyes to, the ulterior consequences
which must necessarily flow from the policy it adopted. It was
evident that as soon as the relation between proprietor and peasant
was removed from the region of voluntary contract by being rendered
indissoluble, the weaker of the two parties legally tied together
must fall completely under the power of the stronger, unless
energetically protected by the law and the Administration. To this
inevitable consequence the Government paid no attention. So far
from endeavouring to protect the peasantry from the oppression of
the proprietors, it did not even determine by law the mutual
obligations which ought to exist between the two classes. Taking
advantage of this omission, the proprietors soon began to impose
whatever obligations they thought fit; and as they had no legal
means of enforcing fulfilment, they gradually introduced a
patriarchal jurisdiction similar to that which they exercised over
their slaves, with fines and corporal punishment as means of
coercion. From this they ere long proceeded a step further, and
began to sell their peasants without the land on which they were
settled. At first this was merely a flagrant abuse unsanctioned by
law, for the peasant had never been declared the private property
of the landed proprietor; but the Government tacitly sanctioned the
practice, and even exacted dues on such sales, as on the sale of
slaves. Finally the right to sell peasants without land was
formally recognised by various Imperial ukazes.*
* For instance, the ukazes of October 13th, 1675, and June 25th,
1682. See Belaef, pp. 203-209.
The old Communal organisation still existed on the estates of the
proprietors, and had never been legally deprived of its authority,
but it was now powerless to protect the members. The proprietor
could easily overcome any active resistance by selling or
converting into domestic servants the peasants who dared to oppose
his will.
The peasantry had thus sunk to the condition of serfs, practically
deprived of legal protection and subject to the arbitrary will of
the proprietors; but they were still in some respects legally and
actually distinguished from the slaves on the one hand and the
"free wandering people" on the other. These distinctions were
obliterated by Peter the Great and his immediate successors.
To effect his great civil and military reforms, Peter required an
annual revenue such as his predecessors had never dreamed of, and
he was consequently always on the look-out for some new object of
taxation. When looking about for this purpose, his eye naturally
fell on the slaves, the domestic servants, and the free
agricultural labourers. None of these classes paid taxes--a fact
which stood in flagrant contradiction with his fundamental
principle of polity, that every subject should in some way serve
the State. He caused, therefore, a national census to be taken, in
which all the various classes of the rural population--slaves,
domestic servants, agricultural labourers, peasants--should be
inscribed in one category; and he imposed equally on all the
members of this category a poll-tax, in lieu of the former land-
tax, which had lain exclusively on the peasants. To facilitate the
collection of this tax the proprietors were made responsible for
their serfs; and the "free wandering people" who did not wish to
enter the army were ordered, under pain of being sent to the
galleys, to inscribe themselves as members of a Commune or as serfs
to some proprietor.
These measures had a considerable influence, if not on the actual
position of the peasantry, at least on the legal conceptions
regarding them. By making the proprietor pay the poll-tax for his
serfs, as if they were slaves or cattle, the law seemed to sanction
the idea that they were part of his goods and chattels. Besides
this, it introduced the entirely new principle that any member of
the rural population not legally attached to the land or to a
proprietor should be regarded as a vagrant, and treated
accordingly. Thus the principle that every subject should in some
way serve the State had found its complete realisation. There was
no longer any room in Russia for free men.
The change in the position of the peasantry, together with the
hardships and oppression by which it was accompanied, naturally
increased fugitivism and vagrancy. Thousands of serfs ran away
from their masters and fled to the steppe or sought enrolment in
the army. To prevent this the Government considered it necessary
to take severe and energetic measures. The serfs were forbidden to
enlist without the permission of their masters, and those who
persisted in presenting themselves for enrolment were to be beaten
"cruelly" (zhestoko) with the knout, and sent to the mines.* The
proprietors, on the other hand, received the right to transport
without trial their unruly serfs to Siberia, and even to send them
to the mines for life.**
* Ukaz of June 2d, 1742.
** See ukaz of January 17th, 1765, and of January 28th, 1766.
If these stringent measures had any effect it was not of long
duration, for there soon appeared among the serfs a still stronger
spirit of discontent and insubordination, which threatened to
produce a general agrarian rising, and actually did create a
movement resembling in many respects the Jacquerie in France and
the Peasant War in Germany. A glance at the causes of this
movement will help us to understand the real nature of serfage in
Russia.
Up to this point serfage had, in spite of its flagrant abuses, a
certain theoretical justification. It was, as we have seen, merely
a part of a general political system in which obligatory service
was imposed on all classes of the population. The serfs served the
nobles in order that the nobles might serve the Tsar. In 1762 this
theory was entirely overturned by a manifesto of Peter III.
abolishing the obligatory service of the Noblesse. According to
strict justice this act ought to have been followed by the
liberation of the serfs, for if the nobles were no longer obliged
to serve the State they had no just claim to the service of the
peasants. The Government had so completely forgotten the original
meaning of serfage that it never thought of carrying out the
measure to its logical consequences, but the peasantry held
tenaciously to the ancient conceptions, and looked impatiently for
a second manifesto liberating them from the power of the
proprietors. Reports were spread that such a manifesto really
existed, and was being concealed by the nobles. A spirit of
insubordination accordingly appeared among the rural population,
and local insurrections broke out in several parts of the Empire.
At this critical moment Peter III. was dethroned and assassinated
by a Court conspiracy. The peasants, who, of course, knew nothing
of the real motives of the conspirators, supposed that the Tsar had
been assassinated by those who wished to preserve serfage, and
believed him to be a martyr in the cause of Emancipation. At the
news of the catastrophe their hopes of Emancipation fell, but soon
they were revived by new rumours. The Tsar, it was said, had
escaped from the conspirators and was in hiding. Soon he would
appear among his faithful peasants, and with their aid would regain
his throne and punish the wicked oppressors. Anxiously he was
awaited, and at last the glad tidings came that he had appeared in
the Don country, that thousands of Cossacks had joined his
standard, that he was everywhere putting the proprietors to death
without mercy, and that he would soon arrive in the ancient
capital!
Peter III. was in reality in his grave, but there was a terrible
element of truth in these reports. A pretender, a Cossack called
Pugatchef, had really appeared on the Don, and had assumed the role
which the peasants expected the late Tsar to play. Advancing
through the country of the Lower Volga, he took several places of
importance, put to death all the proprietors he could find,
defeated on more than one occasion the troops sent against him, and
threatened to advance into the heart of the Empire. It seemed as
if the old troublous times were about to be renewed--as if the
country was once more to be pillaged by those wild Cossacks of the
southern steppe. But the pretender showed himself incapable of
playing the part he had assumed. His inhuman cruelty estranged
many who would otherwise have followed him, and he was too
deficient in decision and energy to take advantage of favourable
circumstances. If it be true that he conceived the idea of
creating a peasant empire (muzhitskoe tsarstvo), he was not the man
to realise such a scheme. After a series of mistakes and defeats
he was taken prisoner, and the insurrection was quelled.*
*Whilst living among the Bashkirs of the province of Samara in 1872
I found some interesting traditions regarding this pretender.
Though nearly a century had elapsed since his death (1775), his
name, his personal appearance, and his exploits were well known
even to the younger generation. My informants firmly believed that
he was not an impostor, but the genuine Tsar, dethroned by his
ambitious consort, and that he never was taken prisoner, but "went
away into foreign lands." When I asked whether he was still alive,
and whether he might not one day return, they replied that they did
not know.
Meanwhile Peter III. had been succeeded by his consort, Catherine
II. As she had no legal right to the throne, and was by birth a
foreigner, she could not gain the affections of the people, and was
obliged to court the favour of the Noblesse. In such a difficult
position she could not venture to apply her humane principles to
the question of serfage. Even during the first years of her reign,
when she had no reason to fear agrarian disturbances, she increased
rather than diminished the power of the proprietors over their
serfs, and the Pugatchef affair confirmed her in this line of
policy. During her reign serfage may be said to have reached its
climax. The serfs were regarded by the law as part of the master's
immovable property*--as part of the working capital of the estate--
and as such they were bought, sold, and given as presents** in
hundreds and thousands, sometimes with the land, and sometimes
without it, sometimes in families, and sometimes individually. The
only legal restriction was that they should not be offered for sale
at the time of the conscription, and that they should at no time be
sold publicly by auction, because such a custom was considered as
"unbecoming in a European State." In all other respects the serfs
might be treated as private property; and this view is to be found
not only in the legislation, but also in the popular conceptions.
It became customary--a custom that continued down to the year 1861--
to compute a noble's fortune, not by his yearly revenue or the
extent of his estate, but by the number of his serfs. Instead of
saying that a man had so many hundreds or thousands a year, or so
many acres, it was commonly said that he had so many hundreds or
thousands of "souls." And over these "souls" he exercised the most
unlimited authority. The serfs had no legal means of self-defence.
The Government feared that the granting to them of judicial or
administrative protection would inevitably awaken in them a spirit
of insubordination, and hence it was ordered that those who
presented complaints should be punished with the knout and sent to
the mines.*** It was only in extreme cases, when some instance of
atrocious cruelty happened to reach the ears of the Sovereign, that
the authorities interfered with the proprietor's jurisdiction, and
these cases had not the slightest influence on the proprietors in
general.****
* See ukaz of October 7th, 1792.
** As an example of making presents of serfs, the following may be
cited. Count Panin presented some of his subordinates for an
Imperial recompense, and on receiving a refusal, made them a
present of 4000 serfs from his own estates.--Belaef, p. 320.
*** See the ukazes of August 22d, 1767, and March 30th, 1781.
**** Perhaps the most horrible case on record is that of a certain
lady called Saltykof, who was brought to justice in 1768.
According to the ukaz regarding her crimes, she had killed by
inhuman tortures in the course of ten or eleven years about a
hundred of her serfs, chiefly of the female sex, and among them
several young girls of eleven and twelve years of age. According
to popular belief her cruelty proceeded from cannibal propensities,
but this was not confirmed by the judicial investigation. Details
in the Russki Arkhiv, 1865, pp. 644-652. The atrocities practised
on the estate of Count Araktcheyef, the favourite of Alexander I.
at the commencement of last century, have been frequently
described, and are scarcely less revolting.
The last years of the eighteenth century may be regarded as the
turning-point in the history of serfage. Up till that time the
power of the proprietors had steadily increased, and the area of
serfage had rapidly expanded. Under the Emperor Paul (1796-1801)
we find the first decided symptoms of a reaction. He regarded the
proprietors as his most efficient officers of police, but he
desired to limit their authority, and for this purpose issued an
ukaz to the effect that the serfs should not be forced to work for
their masters more than three days in the week. With the accession
of Alexander I., in 1801, commenced a long series of abortive
projects for a general emancipation, and endless attempts to
correct the more glaring abuses; and during the reign of Nicholas
no less than six committees were formed at different times to
consider the question. But the practical result of these efforts
was extremely small. The custom of giving grants of land with
peasants was abolished; certain slight restrictions were placed on
the authority of the proprietors; a number of the worst specimens
of the class were removed from the administration of their estates;
a few who were convicted of atrocious cruelty were exiled to
Siberia;* and some thousands of serfs were actually emancipated;
but no decisive radical measures were attempted, and the serfs did
not receive even the right of making formal complaints. Serfage
had, in fact, come to be regarded as a vital part of the State
organisation, and the only sure basis for autocracy. It was
therefore treated tenderly, and the rights and protection accorded
by various ukazes were almost entirely illusory.
*Speranski, for instance, when Governor of the province of Penza,
brought to justice, among others, a proprietor who had caused one
of his serfs to be flogged to death, and a lady who had murdered a
serf boy by pricking him with a pen-knife because he had neglected
to take proper care of a tame rabbit committed to his charge!--
Korff, "Zhizn Speranskago," II., p. 127, note.
If we compare the development of serfage in Russia and in Western
Europe, we find very many points in common, but in Russia the
movement had certain peculiarities. One of the most important of
these was caused by the rapid development of the Autocratic Power.
In feudal Europe, where there was no strong central authority to
control the Noblesse, the free rural Communes entirely, or almost
entirely, disappeared. They were either appropriated by the nobles
or voluntarily submitted to powerful landed proprietors or to
monasteries, and in this way the whole of the reclaimed land, with
a few rare exceptions, became the property of the nobles or of the
Church. In Russia we find the same movement, but it was arrested
by the Imperial power before all the land had been appropriated.
The nobles could reduce to serfage the peasants settled on their
estates, but they could not take possession of the free Communes,
because such an appropriation would have infringed the rights and
diminished the revenues of the Tsar. Down to the commencement of
the last century, it is true, large grants of land with serfs were
made to favoured individuals among the Noblesse, and in the reign
of Paul (1796-1801) a considerable number of estates were affected
to the use of the Imperial family under the name of appanages
(Udyelniya imteniya); but on the other hand, the extensive Church
lands, when secularised by Catherine II., were not distributed
among the nobles, as in many other countries, but were transformed
into State Domains. Thus, at the date of the Emancipation (1861),
by far the greater part of the territory belonged to the State, and
one-half of the rural population were so-called State Peasants
(Gosudarstvenniye krestyanye).
Regarding the condition of these State Peasants, or Peasants of the
Domains, as they are sometimes called, I may say briefly that they
were, in a certain sense, serfs, being attached to the soil like
the others; but their condition was, as a rule, somewhat better
than the serfs in the narrower acceptation of the term. They had
to suffer much from the tyranny and extortion of the special
administration under which they lived, but they had more land and
more liberty than was commonly enjoyed on the estates of resident
proprietors, and their position was much less precarious. It is
often asserted that the officials of the Domains were worse than
the serf-owners, because they had not the same interest in the
prosperity of the peasantry; but this a priori reasoning does not
stand the test of experience.
It is not a little interesting to observe the numerical proportion
and geographical distribution of these two rural classes. In
European Russia, as a whole, about three-eighths of the population
were composed of serfs belonging to the nobles;* but if we take the
provinces separately we find great variations from this average.
In five provinces the serfs were less than three per cent., while
in others they formed more than seventy per cent. of the
population! This is not an accidental phenomenon. In the
geographical distribution of serfage we can see reflected the
origin and history of the institution.
* The exact numbers, according to official data, were--
Entire Population 60,909,309
Peasantry of all Classes 49,486,665
Of these latter there were--
State Peasants 23,138,191
Peasants on the Lands of Proprietors 23,022,390
Peasants of the Appanages and other Departments 3,326,084
----------
49,486,665
If we were to construct a map showing the geographical distribution
of the serf population, we should at once perceive that serfage
radiated from Moscow. Starting from that city as a centre and
travelling in any direction towards the confines of the Empire, we
find that, after making allowance for a few disturbing local
influences, the proportion of serfs regularly declines in the
successive provinces traversed. In the region representing the old
Muscovite Tsardom they form considerably more than a half of the
rural population. Immediately to the south and east of this, in
the territory that was gradually annexed during the seventeenth and
first half of the eighteenth century, the proportion varies from
twenty-five to fifty per cent., and in the more recently annexed
provinces it steadily decreases till it almost reaches zero.
We may perceive, too, that the percentage of serfs decreases
towards the north much more rapidly than towards the east and
south. This points to the essentially agricultural nature of
serfage in its infancy. In the south and east there was abundance
of rich "black earth" celebrated for its fertility, and the nobles
in quest of estates naturally preferred this region to the
inhospitable north, with its poor soil and severe climate.
A more careful examination of the supposed map* would bring out
other interesting facts. Let me notice one by way of illustration.
Had serfage been the result of conquest we should have found the
Slavonic race settled on the State Domains, and the Finnish and
Tartar tribes supplying the serfs of the nobles. In reality we
find quite the reverse; the Finns and Tartars were nearly all State
Peasants, and the serfs of the proprietors were nearly all of
Slavonic race. This is to be accounted for by the fact that the
Finnish and Tartar tribes inhabit chiefly the outlying regions, in
which serfage never attained such dimensions as in the centre of
the Empire.
* Such a map was actually constructed by Troinitski ("Krepostnoe
Naseleniye v Rossii," St. Petersburg, 1861), but it is not nearly
so graphic as is might have been.
The dues paid by the serfs were of three kinds: labour, money, and
farm produce. The last-named is so unimportant that it may be
dismissed in a few words. It consisted chiefly of eggs, chickens,
lambs, mushrooms, wild berries, and linen cloth. The amount of
these various products depended entirely on the will of the master.
The other two kinds of dues, as more important, we must examine
more closely.
When a proprietor had abundance of fertile land and wished to farm
on his own account, he commonly demanded from his serfs as much
labour as possible. Under such a master the serfs were probably
free from money dues, and fulfilled their obligations to him by
labouring in his fields in summer and transporting his grain to
market in winter. When, on the contrary, a land-owner had more
serf labour at his disposal than he required for the cultivation of
his fields, he put the superfluous serfs "on obrok,"--that is to
say, he allowed them to go and work where they pleased on condition
of paying him a fixed yearly sum. Sometimes the proprietor did not
farm at all on his own account, in which case he put all the serfs
"on obrok," and generally gave to the Commune in usufruct the whole
of the arable land and pasturage. In this way the Mir played the
part of a tenant.
We have here the basis for a simple and important classification of
estates in the time of serfage: (1) Estates on which the dues were
exclusively in labour; (2) estates on which the dues were partly in
labour and partly in money; and (3) estates on which the dues were
exclusively in money.
In the manner of exacting the labour dues there was considerable
variety. According to the famous manifesto of Paul I., the peasant
could not be compelled to work more than three days in the week;
but this law was by no means universally observed, and those who
did observe it had various methods of applying it. A few took it
literally and laid down a rule that the serfs should work for them
three definite days in the week--for example, every Monday,
Tuesday, and Wednesday--but this was an extremely inconvenient
method, for it prevented the field labour from being carried on
regularly. A much more rational system was that according to which
one-half of the serfs worked the first three days of the week, and
the other half the remaining three. In this way there was, without
any contravention of the law, a regular and constant supply of
labour. It seems, however, that the great majority of the
proprietors followed no strict method, and paid no attention
whatever to Paul's manifesto, which gave to the peasants no legal
means of making formal complaints. They simply summoned daily as
many labourers as they required. The evil consequences of this for
the peasants' crops were in part counteracted by making the
peasants sow their own grain a little later than that of the
proprietor, so that the master's harvest work was finished, or
nearly finished, before their grain was ripe. This combination did
not, however, always succeed, and in cases where there was a
conflict of interests, the serf was, of course, the losing party.
All that remained for him to do in such cases was to work a little
in his own fields before six o'clock in the morning and after nine
o'clock at night, and in order to render this possible he
economised his strength, and worked as little as possible in his
master's fields during the day.
It has frequently been remarked, and with much truth--though the
indiscriminate application of the principle has often led to
unjustifiable legislative inactivity--that the practical result of
institutions depends less on the intrinsic abstract nature of the
institutions themselves than on the character of those who work
them. So it was with serfage. When a proprietor habitually acted
towards his serfs in an enlightened, rational, humane way, they had
little reason to complain of their position, and their life was
much easier than that of many men who live in a state of complete
individual freedom and unlimited, unrestricted competition.
However paradoxical the statement may seem to those who are in the
habit of regarding all forms of slavery from the sentimental point
of view, it is unquestionable that the condition of serfs under
such a proprietor as I have supposed was more enviable than that of
the majority of English agricultural labourers. Each family had a
house of its own, with a cabbage-garden, one or more horses, one or
two cows, several sheep, poultry, agricultural implements, a share
of the Communal land, and everything else necessary for carrying on
its small farming operations; and in return for this it had to
supply the proprietor with an amount of labour which was by no
means oppressive. If, for instance, a serf had three adult sons--
and the households, as I have said, were at that time generally
numerous--two of them might work for the proprietor whilst he
himself and the remaining son could attend exclusively to the
family affairs. By the events which used to be called "the
visitations of God" he had no fear of being permanently ruined. If
his house was burnt, or his cattle died from the plague, or a
series of "bad years" left him without seed for his fields, he
could always count upon temporary assistance from his master. He
was protected, too, against all oppression and exactions on the
part of the officials; for the police, when there was any call for
its interference, applied to the proprietor, who was to a certain
extent responsible for his serfs. Thus the serf might live a
tranquil, contented life, and die at a ripe old age, without ever
having been conscious that serfage was a grievous burden.
If all the serfs had lived in this way we might, perhaps, regret
that the Emancipation was ever undertaken. In reality there was,
as the French say, le revers de la medaille, and serfage generally
appeared under a form very different from that which I have just
depicted. The proprietors were, unfortunately, not all of the
enlightened, humane type. Amongst them were many who demanded from
their serfs an inordinate amount of labour, and treated them in a
very inhuman fashion.
These oppressors of their serfs may be divided into four
categories. First, there were the proprietors who managed their
own estates, and oppressed simply for the purpose of increasing
their revenues. Secondly, there were a number of retired officers
who wished to establish a certain order and discipline on their
estates, and who employed for this purpose the barbarous measures
which were at that time used in the army, believing that merciless
corporal punishment was the only means of curing laziness,
disorderliness and other vices. Thirdly, there were the absentees
who lived beyond their means, and demanded from their steward,
under pain of giving him or his son as a recruit, a much greater
yearly sum than the estate could be reasonably expected to yield.
Lastly, in the latter years of serfage, there were a number of men
who bought estates as a mercantile speculation, and made as much
money out of them as they could in the shortest possible space of
time.
Of all hard masters, the last-named were the most terrible.
Utterly indifferent to the welfare of the serfs and the ultimate
fate of the property, they cut down the timber, sold the cattle,
exacted heavy money dues under threats of giving the serfs or their
children as recruits, presented to the military authorities a
number of conscripts greater than was required by law--selling the
conscription receipts (zatchetniya kvitantsii) to the merchants and
burghers who were liable to the conscription but did not wish to
serve--compelled some of the richer serfs to buy their liberty at
an enormous price, and, in a word, used every means, legal and
illegal, for extracting money. By this system of management they
ruined the estate completely in the course of a few years; but by
that time they had realised probably the whole sum paid, with a
very fair profit from the operation; and this profit could be
considerably augmented by selling a number of the peasant families
for transportation to another estate (na svoz), or by mortgaging
the property in the Opekunski Sovet--a Government institution which
lent money on landed property without examining carefully the
nature of the security.
As to the means which the proprietors possessed of oppressing their
peasants, we must distinguish between the legal and the actual.
The legal were almost as complete as any one could desire. "The
proprietor," it is said in the Laws (Vol. IX, p. 1045, ed. an.
1857), "may impose on his serfs every kind of labour, may take from
them money dues (obrok) and demand from them personal service, with
this one restriction, that they should not be thereby ruined, and
that the number of days fixed by law should be left to them for
their own work."* Besides this, he had the right to transform
peasants into domestic servants, and might, instead of employing
them in his own service, hire them out to others who had the rights
and privileges of Noblesse (pp. 1047-48). For all offences
committed against himself or against any one under his jurisdiction
he could subject the guilty ones to corporal punishment not
exceeding forty lashes with the birch or fifteen blows with the
stick (p. 1052); and if he considered any of his serfs as
incorrigible, he could present them to the authorities to be
drafted into the army or transported to Siberia as he might desire
(pp. 1053-55). In cases of insubordination, where the ordinary
domestic means of discipline did not suffice, he could call in the
police and the military to support his authority.
* I give here the references to the Code, because Russians commonly
believe and assert that the hiring out of serfs, the infliction of
corporal punishment, and similar practices were merely abuses
unauthorised by law.
Such were the legal means by which the proprietor might oppress his
peasants, and it will be readily understood that they were very
considerable and very elastic. By law he had the power to impose
any dues in labour or money which he might think fit, and in all
cases the serfs were ordered to be docile and obedient (p. 1027).
Corporal punishment, though restricted by law, he could in reality
apply to any extent. Certainly none of the serfs, and very few of
the proprietors, were aware that the law placed any restriction on
this right. All the proprietors were in the habit of using
corporal punishment as they thought proper, and unless a proprietor
became notorious for inhuman cruelty the authorities never thought
of interfering. But in the eyes of the peasants corporal
punishment was not the worst. What they feared infinitely more
than the birch or the stick was the proprietor's power of giving
them or their sons as recruits. The law assumed that this extreme
means would be employed only against those serfs who showed
themselves incorrigibly vicious or insubordinate; but the
authorities accepted those presented without making any
investigations, and consequently the proprietor might use this
power as an effective means of extortion.
Against these means of extortion and oppression the serfs had no
legal protection. The law provided them with no means of resisting
any injustice to which they might be subjected, or of bringing to
punishment the master who oppressed and ruined them. The
Government, notwithstanding its sincere desire to protect them from
inordinate burdens and cruel treatment, rarely interfered between
the master and his serfs, being afraid of thereby undermining the
authority of the proprietors, and awakening among the peasantry a
spirit of insubordination. The serfs were left, therefore, to
their own resources, and had to defend themselves as best they
could. The simplest way was open mutiny; but this was rarely
employed, for they knew by experience that any attempt of the kind
would be at once put down by the military and mercilessly punished.
Much more favourite and efficient methods were passive resistance,
flight, and fire-raising or murder.
We might naturally suppose that an unscrupulous proprietor, armed
with the enormous legal and actual power which I have just
described, could very easily extort from his peasants anything he
desired. In reality, however, the process of extortion, when it
exceeded a certain measure, was a very difficult operation. The
Russian peasant has a capacity of patient endurance that would do
honour to a martyr, and a power of continued, dogged, passive
resistance such as is possessed, I believe, by no other class of
men in Europe; and these qualities formed a very powerful barrier
against the rapacity of unconscientious proprietors. As soon as
the serfs remarked in their master a tendency to rapacity and
extortion, they at once took measures to defend themselves. Their
first step was to sell secretly the live stock they did not
actually require, and all their movable property except the few
articles necessary for everyday use; then the little capital
realised was carefully hidden.
When this had been effected, the proprietor might threaten and
punish as he liked, but he rarely succeeded in unearthing the
treasure. Many a peasant, under such circumstances, bore patiently
the most cruel punishment, and saw his sons taken away as recruits,
and yet he persisted in declaring that he had no money to ransom
himself and his children. A spectator in such a case would
probably have advised him to give up his little store of money, and
thereby liberate himself from persecution; but the peasants
reasoned otherwise. They were convinced, and not without reason,
that the sacrifice of their little capital would merely put off the
evil day, and that the persecution would very soon recommence. In
this way they would have to suffer as before, and have the
additional mortification of feeling that they had spent to no
purpose the little that they possessed. Their fatalistic belief in
the "perhaps" (avos') came here to their aid. Perhaps the
proprietor might become weary of his efforts when he saw that they
led to no result, or perhaps something might occur which would
remove the persecutor.
It always happened, however, that when a proprietor treated his
serfs with extreme injustice and cruelty, some of them lost
patience, and sought refuge in flight. As the estates lay
perfectly open on all sides, and it was utterly impossible to
exercise a strict supervision, nothing was easier than to run away,
and the fugitive might be a hundred miles off before his absence
was noticed. But the oppressed serf was reluctant to adopt such an
extreme measure. He had almost always a wife and family, and he
could not possibly take them with him; flight, therefore, was
expatriation for life in its most terrible form. Besides this, the
life of a fugitive was by no means enviable. He was liable at any
moment to fall into the hands of the police, and to be put into
prison or sent back to his master. So little charm, indeed, did
this life present that not infrequently after a few months or a few
years the fugitive returned of his own accord to his former
domicile.
Regarding fugitives or passportless wanderers in general, I may
here remark parenthetically that there were two kinds. In the
first place, there was the young, able-bodied peasant, who fled
from the oppression of his master or from the conscription. Such a
fugitive almost always sought out for himself a new domicile--
generally in the southern provinces, where there was a great
scarcity of labourers, and where many proprietors habitually
welcomed all peasants who presented themselves, without making any
inquiries as to passports. In the second place, there were those
who chose fugitivism as a permanent mode of life. These were, for
the most part, men or women of a certain age--widowers or widows--
who had no close family ties, and who were too infirm or too lazy
to work. The majority of these assumed the character of pilgrims.
As such they could always find enough to eat, and could generally
even collect a few roubles with which to grease the palm of any
zealous police-officer who should arrest them. For a life of this
kind Russia presented peculiar facilities. There was abundance of
monasteries, where all comers could live for three days without
questions being asked, and where those who were willing to do a
little work for the patron saint might live for a much longer
period. Then there were the towns, where the rich merchants
considered almsgiving as very profitable for salvation. And,
lastly, there were the villages, where a professing pilgrim was
sure to be hospitably received and entertained so long as he
refrained from stealing and other acts too grossly inconsistent
with his assumed character. For those who contented themselves
with simple fare, and did not seek to avoid the usual privations of
a wanderer's life, these ordinary means of subsistence were amply
sufficient. Those who were more ambitious and more cunning often
employed their talents with great success in the world of the Old
Ritualists and Sectarians.
The last and most desperate means of defense which the serfs
possessed were fire-raising and murder. With regard to the amount
of fire-raising there are no trustworthy statistics. With regard
to the number of agrarian murders I once obtained some interesting
statistical data, but unfortunately lost them. I may say, however,
that these cases were not very numerous. This is to be explained
in part by the patient, long-suffering character of the peasantry,
and in part by the fact that the great majority of the proprietors
were by no means such inhuman taskmasters as is sometimes supposed.
When a case did occur, the Administration always made a strict
investigation--punishing the guilty with exemplary severity, and
taking no account of the provocation to which they had been
subjected. The peasantry, on the contrary--at least, when the act
was not the result of mere personal vengeance--secretly sympathised
with "the unfortunates," and long cherished their memory as that of
men who had suffered for the Mir.
In speaking of the serfs I have hitherto confined my attention to
the members of the Mir, or rural Commune--that is to say, the
peasants in the narrower sense of the term; but besides these there
were the Dvorovuye, or domestic servants, and of these I must add a
word or two.
The Dvorovuye were domestic slaves rather than serfs in the proper
sense of the term. Let us, however, avoid wounding unnecessarily
Russian sensibilities by the use of the ill-sounding word. We may
call the class in question "domestics"--remembering, of course,
that they were not quite domestic servants in the ordinary sense.
They received no wages, were not at liberty to change masters,
possessed almost no legal rights, and might be punished, hired out,
or sold by their owners without any infraction of the written law.
These "domestics" were very numerous--out of all proportion to the
work to be performed--and could consequently lead a very lazy
life;* but the peasant considered it a great misfortune to be
transferred to their ranks, for he thereby lost his share of the
Communal land and the little independence which he enjoyed. It
very rarely happened, however, that the proprietor took an able-
bodied peasant as domestic. The class generally kept up its
numbers by the legitimate and illegitimate method of natural
increase; and involuntary additions were occasionally made when
orphans were left without near relatives, and no other family
wished to adopt them. To this class belonged the lackeys, servant-
girls, cooks, coachmen, stable-boys, gardeners, and a large number
of nondescript old men and women who had no very clearly defined
functions. If the proprietor had a private theatre or orchestra,
it was from this class that the actors and musicians were drawn.
Those of them who were married and had children occupied a position
intermediate between the ordinary domestic servant and the peasant.
On the one hand, they received from the master a monthly allowance
of food and a yearly allowance of clothes, and they were obliged to
live in the immediate vicinity of the mansion-house; but, on the
other hand, they had each a separate house or apartment, with a
little cabbage-garden, and commonly a small plot of flax. The
unmarried ones lived in all respects like ordinary domestic
servants.
* Those proprietors who kept orchestras, large packs of hounds,
&c., had sometimes several hundred domestic serfs.
The number of these domestic serfs being generally out of all
proportion to the amount of work they had to perform, they were
imbued with a hereditary spirit of indolence, and they performed
lazily and carelessly what they had to do. On the other hand, they
were often sincerely attached to the family they served, and
occasionally proved by acts their fidelity and attachment. Here is
an instance out of many for which I can vouch. An old nurse, whose
mistress was dangerously ill, vowed that, in the event of the
patient's recovery, she would make a pilgrimage, first to Kief, the
Holy City on the Dnieper, and afterwards to Solovetsk, a much
revered monastery on an island in the White Sea. The patient
recovered, and the old woman, in fulfilment of her vow, walked more
than two thousand miles!
This class of serfs might well be called domestic slaves, but I
must warn the reader that he ought not to use the expression when
speaking with Russians, because they are extremely sensitive on the
point. Serfage, they say, was something quite different from
slavery, and slavery never existed in Russia.
The first part of this assertion is perfectly true, and the second
part perfectly false. In old times, as I have said above, slavery
was a recognised institution in Russia as in other countries. One
can hardly read a few pages of the old chronicles without stumbling
on references to slaves; and I distinctly remember--though I cannot
at this moment give chapter and verse--that one of the old Russian
Princes was so valiant and so successful in his wars that during
his reign a slave might be bought for a few coppers. As late as
the beginning of last century the domestic serfs were sold very
much as domestic slaves used to be sold in countries where slavery
was recognised as a legal institution. Here is an example of the
customary advertisement; I take it almost at random from the Moscow
Gazette of 1801:--
"TO BE SOLD: three coachmen, well trained and handsome; and two
girls, the one eighteen, and the other fifteen years of age, both
of them good-looking, and well acquainted with various kinds of
handiwork. In the same house there are for sale two hairdressers;
the one, twenty-one years of age, can read, write, play on a
musical instrument, and act as huntsman; the other can dress
ladies' and gentlemen's hair. In the same house are sold pianos
and organs."
A little farther on in the same number of the paper, a first-rate
clerk, a carver, and a lackey are offered for sale, and the reason
assigned is a superabundance of the articles in question (za
izlishestvom). In some instances it seems as if the serfs and the
cattle were intentionally put in the same category, as in the
following announcement: "In this house one can buy a coachman and a
Dutch cow about to calve." The style of these advertisements, and
the frequent recurrence of the same addresses, show that there was
at this time in Moscow a regular class of slave-dealers. The
humane Alexander I. prohibited advertisements of this kind, but he
did not put down the custom which they represented, and his
successor, Nicholas I., took no effective measures for its
repression.
Of the whole number of serfs belonging to the proprietors, the
domestics formed, according to the census of 1857, no less than 6
3/4 per cent. (6.79), and their numbers were evidently rapidly
increasing, for in the preceding census they represented only 4.79
per cent. of the whole. This fact seems all the more significant
when we observe that during this period the number of peasant serfs
had diminished.
I must now bring this long chapter to an end. My aim has been to
represent serfage in its normal, ordinary forms rather than in its
occasional monstrous manifestations. Of these latter I have a
collection containing ample materials for a whole series of
sensation novels, but I refrain from quoting them, because I do not
believe that the criminal annals of a country give a fair
representation of its real condition. On the other hand, I do not
wish to whitewash serfage or attenuate its evil consequences. No
great body of men could long wield such enormous uncontrolled power
without abusing it,* and no large body of men could long live under
such power without suffering morally and materially from its
pernicious influence. If serfage did not create that moral apathy
and intellectual lethargy which formed, as it were, the atmosphere
of Russian provincial life, it did much at least to preserve it.
In short, serfage was the chief barrier to all material and moral
progress, and in a time of moral awakening such as that which I
have described in the preceding chapter, the question of
Emancipation naturally came at once to the front.
* The number of deposed proprietors--or rather the number of
estates placed under curators in consequence of the abuse of
authority on the part of their owners--amounted in 1859 to 215. So
at least I found in an official MS. document shown to me by the
late Nicholas Milutin.
CHAPTER XXIX
THE EMANCIPATION OF THE SERFS
The Question Raised--Chief Committee--The Nobles of the Lithuanian
Provinces--The Tsar's Broad Hint to the Noblesse--Enthusiasm in the
Press--The Proprietors--Political Aspirations--No Opposition--The
Government--Public Opinion--Fear of the Proletariat--The Provincial
Committees--The Elaboration Commission--The Question Ripens--
Provincial Deputies--Discontent and Demonstrations--The Manifesto--
Fundamental Principles of the Law--Illusions and Disappointment of
the Serfs--Arbiters of the Peace--A Characteristic Incident--
Redemption--Who Effected the Emancipation?
It is a fundamental principle of Russian political organisation
that all initiative in public affairs proceeds from the Autocratic
Power. The widespread desire, therefore, for the Emancipation of
the serfs did not find free expression so long as the Emperor kept
silence regarding his intentions. The educated classes watched
anxiously for some sign, and soon a sign was given to them. In
March, 1856--a few days after the publication of the manifesto
announcing the conclusion of peace with the Western Powers--his
Majesty said to the Marshals of Noblesse in Moscow: "For the
removal of certain unfounded reports I consider it necessary to
declare to you that I have not at present the intention of
annihilating serfage; but certainly, as you yourselves know, the
existing manner of possessing serfs cannot remain unchanged. It is
better to abolish serfage from above than to await the time when it
will begin to abolish itself from below. I request you, gentlemen,
to consider how this can be put into execution, and to submit my
words to the Noblesse for their consideration."
These words were intended to sound the Noblesse and induce them to
make a voluntary proposal, but they had not the desired effect.
Abolitionist enthusiasm was rare among the great nobles, and those
who really wished to see serfage abolished considered the Imperial
utterance too vague and oracular to justify them in taking the
initiative. As no further steps were taken for some time, the
excitement caused by the incident soon subsided, and many people
assumed that the consideration of the problem had been indefinitely
postponed. "The Government," it was said, "evidently intended to
raise the question, but on perceiving the indifference or hostility
of the landed proprietors, it became frightened and drew back."
The Emperor was in reality disappointed. He had expected that his
"faithful Moscow Noblesse," of which he was wont to say he was
himself a member, would at once respond to his call, and that the
ancient capital would have the honour of beginning the work. And
if the example were thus given by Moscow, he had no doubt that it
would soon be followed by the other provinces. He now perceived
that the fundamental principles on which the Emancipation should be
effected must be laid down by the Government, and for this purpose
he created a secret committee composed of several great officers of
State.
This "Chief Committee for Peasant Affairs," as it was afterwards
called, devoted six months to studying the history of the question.
Emancipation schemes were by no means a new phenomenon in Russia.
Ever since the time of Catherine II. the Government had thought of
improving the condition of the serfs, and on more than one occasion
a general emancipation had been contemplated. In this way the
question had slowly ripened, and certain fundamental principles had
come to be pretty generally recognised. Of these principles the
most important was that the State should not consent to any project
which would uproot the peasant from the soil and allow him to
wander about at will; for such a measure would render the
collection of the taxes impossible, and in all probability produce
the most frightful agrarian disorders. And to this general
principle there was an important corollary: if severe restrictions
were to be placed on free migration, it would be necessary to
provide the peasantry with land in the immediate vicinity of the
villages; otherwise they must inevitably fall back under the power
of the proprietors, and a new and worse kind of serfage would thus
be created. But in order to give land to the peasantry it would be
necessary to take it from the proprietors; and this expropriation
seemed to many a most unjustifiable infringement of the sacred
rights of property. It was this consideration that had restrained
Nicholas from taking any decisive measures with regard to serfage;
and it had now considerable weight with the members of the
committee, who were nearly all great land-owners.
Notwithstanding the strenuous exertions of the Grand Duke
Constantine, who had been appointed a member for the express
purpose of accelerating the proceedings, the committee did not show
as much zeal and energy as was desired, and orders were given to
take some decided step. At that moment a convenient opportunity
presented itself.
In the Lithuanian Provinces, where the nobles were Polish by origin
and sympathies, the miserable condition of the peasantry had
induced the Government in the preceding reign to limit the
arbitrary power of the serf-owners by so-called Inventories, in
which the mutual obligations of masters and serfs were regulated
and defined. These Inventories had caused great dissatisfaction,
and the proprietors now proposed that they should be revised. Of
this the Government determined to take advantage. On the somewhat
violent assumption that these proprietors wished to emancipate
their serfs, an Imperial rescript was prepared approving of their
supposed desire, and empowering them to form committees for the
preparation of definite projects.* In the rescript itself the word
emancipation was studiously avoided, but there could be no doubt as
to the implied meaning, for it was expressly stated in the
supplementary considerations that "the abolition of serfage must be
effected not suddenly, but gradually." Four days later the
Minister of the Interior, in accordance with a secret order from
the Emperor, sent a circular to the Governors and Marshals of
Noblesse all over Russia proper, informing them that the nobles of
the Lithuanian Provinces "had recognised the necessity of
liberating the peasants," and that "this noble intention" had
afforded peculiar satisfaction to his Majesty. A copy of the
rescript and the fundamental principles to be observed accompanied
the circular, "in case the nobles of other provinces should express
a similar desire."
* This celebrated document is known as "The Rescript to Nazimof."
More than once in the course of conversation I did all in my power,
within the limits of politeness and discretion, to extract from
General Nazimof a detailed account of this important episode, but
my efforts were unsuccessful.
This circular produced an immense sensation throughout the country.
No one could for a moment misunderstand the suggestion that the
nobles of other provinces MIGHT POSSIBLY express a desire to
liberate their serfs. Such vague words, when spoken by an
autocrat, have a very definite and unmistakable meaning, which
prudent loyal subjects have no difficulty in understanding. If any
doubted, their doubts were soon dispelled, for the Emperor, a few
weeks later, publicly expressed a hope that, with the help of God
and the co-operation of the nobles, the work would be successfully
accomplished.
The die was cast, and the Government looked anxiously to see the
result.
The periodical Press--which was at once the product and the
fomenter of the liberal aspirations--hailed the raising of the
question with boundless enthusiasm. The Emancipation, it was said,
would certainly open a new and glorious epoch in the national
history. Serfage was described as an ulcer that had long been
poisoning the national blood; as an enormous weight under which the
whole nation groaned; as an insurmountable obstacle, preventing all
material and moral progress; as a cumbrous load which rendered all
free, vigorous action impossible, and prevented Russia from rising
to the level of the Western nations. If Russia had succeeded in
stemming the flood of adverse fortune in spite of this millstone
round her neck, what might she not accomplish when free and
untrammelled? All sections of the literary world had arguments to
offer in support of the foregone conclusion. The moralists
declared that all the prevailing vices were the product of serfage,
and that moral progress was impossible in an atmosphere of slavery;
the lawyers held that the arbitrary authority of the proprietors
over the peasants had no legal basis; the economists explained that
free labour was an indispensable condition of industrial and
commercial prosperity; the philosophical historians showed that the
normal historical development of the country demanded the immediate
abolition of this superannuated remnant of barbarism; and the
writers of the sentimental, gushing type poured forth endless
effusions about brotherly love to the weak and the oppressed. In a
word, the Press was for the moment unanimous, and displayed a
feverish excitement which demanded a liberal use of superlatives.
This enthusiastic tone accorded perfectly with the feelings of a
large section of the nobles. Nearly the whole of the Noblesse was
more or less affected by the newborn enthusiasm for everything
just, humanitarian, and liberal. The aspirations found, of course,
their most ardent representatives among the educated youth; but
they were by no means confined to the younger men, who had passed
through the universities and had always regarded serfage as a stain
on the national honour. Many a Saul was found among the prophets.
Many an old man, with grey hairs and grandchildren, who had all his
life placidly enjoyed the fruits of serf labour, was now heard to
speak of serfage as an antiquated institution which could not be
reconciled with modern humanitarian ideas; and not a few of all
ages, who had formerly never thought of reading books or
newspapers, now perused assiduously the periodical literature, and
picked up the liberal and humanitarian phrases with which it was
filled.
This Abolitionist fervour was considerably augmented by certain
political aspirations which did not appear in the newspapers, but
which were at that time very generally entertained. In spite of
the Press-censure a large section of the educated classes had
become acquainted with the political literature of France and
Germany, and had imbibed therefrom an unbounded admiration for
Constitutional government. A Constitution, it was thought, would
necessarily remove all political evils and create something like a
political Millennium. And it was not to be a Constitution of the
ordinary sort--the fruit of compromise between hostile political
parties--but an institution designed calmly according to the latest
results of political science, and so constructed that all classes
would voluntarily contribute to the general welfare. The necessary
prelude to this happy era of political liberty was, of course, the
abolition of serfage. When the nobles had given up their power
over their serfs they would receive a Constitution as an
indemnification and reward.
There were, however, many nobles of the old school who remained
impervious to all these new feelings and ideas. On them the
raising of the Emancipation question had a very different effect.
They had no source of revenue but their estates, and they could not
conceive the possibility of working their estates without serf
labour. If the peasant was indolent and careless even under strict
supervision, what would he become when no longer under the
authority of a master? If the profits from farming were already
small, what would they be when no one would work without wages?
And this was not the worst, for it was quite evident from the
circular that the land question was to be raised, and that a
considerable portion of each estate would be transferred, at least
for a time, to the emancipated peasants.
To the proprietors who looked at the question in this way the
prospect of Emancipation was certainly not at all agreeable, but we
must not imagine that they felt as English land-owners would feel
if threatened by a similar danger. In England a hereditary estate
has for the family a value far beyond what it would bring in the
market. It is regarded as one and indivisible, and any
dismemberment of it would be looked upon as a grave family
misfortune. In Russia, on the contrary, estates have nothing of
this semi-sacred character, and may be at any time dismembered
without outraging family feeling or traditional associations.
Indeed, it is not uncommon that when a proprietor dies, leaving
only one estate and several children, the property is broken up
into fractions and divided among the heirs. Even the prospect of
pecuniary sacrifice did not alarm the Russians so much as it would
alarm Englishmen. Men who keep no accounts and take little thought
for the morrow are much less averse to making pecuniary sacrifices--
whether for a wise or a foolish purpose--than those who carefully
arrange their mode of life according to their income.
Still, after due allowance has been made for these peculiarities,
it must be admitted that the feeling of dissatisfaction and alarm
was very widespread. Even Russians do not like the prospect of
losing a part of their land and income. No protest, however, was
entered, and no opposition was made. Those who were hostile to the
measure were ashamed to show themselves selfish and unpatriotic.
At the same time they knew very well that the Emperor, if he
wished, could effect the Emancipation in spite of them, and that
resistance on their part would draw down upon them the Imperial
displeasure, without affording any compensating advantage. They
knew, too, that there was a danger from below, so that any useless
show of opposition would be like playing with matches in a powder-
magazine. The serfs would soon hear that the Tsar desired to set
them free, and they might, if they suspected that the proprietors
were trying to frustrate the Tsar's benevolent intentions, use
violent measures to get rid of the opposition. The idea of
agrarian massacres had already taken possession of many timid
minds. Besides this, all classes of the proprietors felt that if
the work was to be done, it should be done by the Noblesse and not
by the bureaucracy. If it were effected by the nobles the
interests of the land-owners would be duly considered, but if it
were effected by the Administration without their concurrence and
co-operation their interests would be neglected, and there would
inevitably be an enormous amount of jobbery and corruption. In
accordance with this view, the Noblesse corporations of the various
provinces successively requested permission to form committees for
the consideration of the question, and during the year 1858 a
committee was opened in almost every province in which serfage
existed.
In this way the question was apparently handed over for solution to
the nobles, but in reality the Noblesse was called upon merely to
advise, and not to legislate. The Government had not only laid
down the fundamental principles of the scheme; it continually
supervised the work of construction, and it reserved to itself the
right of modifying or rejecting the projects proposed by the
committees.
According to these fundamental principles the serfs should be
emancipated gradually, so that for some time they would remain
attached to the glebe and subject to the authority of the
proprietors. During this transition period they should redeem by
money payments or labour their houses and gardens, and enjoy in
usufruct a certain quantity of land, sufficient to enable them to
support themselves and to fulfil their obligations to the State as
well as to the proprietor. In return for this land they should pay
a yearly rent in money, produce or labour over and above the yearly
sum paid for the redemption of their houses and gardens. As to
what should be done after the expiry of the transition period, the
Government seems to have had no clearly conceived intentions.
Probably it hoped that by that time the proprietors and their
emancipated serfs would have invented some convenient modus
vivendi, and that nothing but a little legislative regulation would
be necessary. But radical legislation is like the letting-out of
water. These fundamental principles, adopted at first with a view
to mere immediate practical necessity, soon acquired a very
different significance. To understand this we must return to the
periodical literature.
Until the serf question came to be discussed, the reform
aspirations were very vague, and consequently there was a
remarkable unanimity among their representatives. The great
majority of the educated classes were unanimously of opinion that
Russia should at once adopt from the West all those liberal
principles and institutions the exclusion of which had prevented
the country from rising to the level of the Western nations. But
very soon symptoms of a schism became apparent. Whilst the
literature in general was still preaching the doctrine that Russia
should adopt everything that was "liberal," a few voices began to
be heard warning the unwary that much which bore the name of
liberal was in reality already antiquated and worthless--that
Russia ought not to follow blindly in the footsteps of other
nations, but ought rather to profit by their experience, and avoid
the errors into which they had fallen. The chief of these errors
was, according to these new teachers, the abnormal development of
individualism--the adoption of that principle of laissez faire
which forms the basis of what may be called the Orthodox School of
Political Economists. Individualism and unrestricted competition,
it was said, have now reached in the West an abnormal and monstrous
development. Supported by the laissez faire principle, they have
led--and must always lead--to the oppression of the weak, the
tyranny of capital, the impoverishment of the masses for the
benefit of the few, and the formation of a hungry, dangerous
Proletariat! This has already been recognised by the most advanced
thinkers of France and Germany. If the older countries cannot at
once cure those evils, that is no reason for Russia to inoculate
herself with them. She is still at the commencement of her career,
and it would be folly for her to wander voluntarily for ages in the
Desert, when a direct route to the Promised Land has been already
discovered.
In order to convey some idea of the influence which this teaching
exercised, I must here recall, at the risk of repeating myself,
what I said in a former chapter. The Russians, as I have there
pointed out, have a peculiar way of treating political and social
questions. Having received their political education from books,
they naturally attribute to theoretical considerations an
importance which seems to us exaggerated. When any important or
trivial question arises, they at once launch into a sea of
philosophical principles, and pay less attention to the little
objects close at hand than to the big ones that appear on the
distant horizon of the future. And when they set to work at any
political reform they begin ab ovo. As they have no traditional
prejudices to fetter them, and no traditional principles to lead
them, they naturally take for their guidance the latest conclusions
of political philosophy.
Bearing this in mind, let us see how it affected the Emancipation
question. The Proletariat--described as a dangerous monster which
was about to swallow up society in Western Europe, and which might
at any moment cross the frontier unless kept out by vigorous
measures--took possession of the popular imagination, and aroused
the fears of the reading public. To many it seemed that the best
means of preventing the formation of a Proletariat in Russia was
the securing of land for the emancipated serfs and the careful
preservation of the rural Commune. "Now is the moment," it was
said, "for deciding the important question whether Russia is to
fall a prey, like the Western nations, to this terrible evil, or
whether she is to protect herself for ever against it. In the
decision of this question lies the future destiny of the country.
If the peasants be emancipated without land, or if those Communal
institutions which give to every man a share of the soil and secure
this inestimable boon for the generations still unborn be now
abolished, a Proletariat will be rapidly formed, and the peasantry
will become a disorganised mass of homeless wanderers like the
English agricultural labourers. If, on the contrary, a fair share
of land be granted to them, and if the Commune be made proprietor
of the land ceded, the danger of a Proletariat is for ever removed,
and Russia will thereby set an example to the civilised world!
Never has a nation had such an opportunity of making an enormous
leap forward on the road of progress, and never again will the
opportunity occur. The Western nations have discovered their error
when it is too late--when the peasantry have been already deprived
of their land, and the labouring classes of the towns have already
fallen a prey to the insatiable cupidity of the capitalists. In
vain their most eminent thinkers warn and exhort. Ordinary
remedies are no longer of any avail. But Russia may avoid these
dangers, if she but act wisely and prudently in this great matter.
The peasants are still in actual, if not legal, possession of the
land, and there is as yet no Proletariat in the towns. All that is
necessary, therefore, is to abolish the arbitrary authority of the
proprietors without expropriating the peasants, and without
disturbing the existing Communal institutions, which form the best
barrier against pauperism."
These ideas were warmly espoused by many proprietors, and exercised
a very great influence on the deliberations of the Provincial
Committees. In these committees there were generally two groups.
The majorities, whilst making large concessions to the claims of
justice and expediency, endeavoured to defend, as far as possible,
the interests of their class; the minorities, though by no means
indifferent to the interests of the class to which they belonged,
allowed the more abstract theoretical considerations to be
predominant. At first the majorities did all in their power to
evade the fundamental principles laid down by the Government as
much too favourable to the peasantry; but when they perceived that
public opinion, as represented by the Press, went much further than
the Government, they clung to these fundamental principles--which
secured at least the fee simple of the estate to the landlord--as
their anchor of safety. Between the two parties arose naturally a
strong spirit of hostility, and the Government, which wished to
have the support of the minorities, found it advisable that both
should present their projects for consideration.
As the Provincial Committees worked independently, there was
considerable diversity in the conclusions at which they arrived.
The task of codifying these conclusions, and elaborating out of
them a general scheme of Emancipation, was entrusted to a special
Imperial Commission, composed partly of officials and partly of
landed proprietors named by the Emperor.* Those who believed that
the question had really been handed over to the Noblesse assumed
that this Commission would merely arrange the materials presented
by the Provincial Committees, and that the Emancipation Law would
thereafter be elaborated by a National Assembly of deputies elected
by the nobles. In reality the Commission, working in St.
Petersburg under the direct guidance and control of the Government,
fulfilled a very different and much more important function. Using
the combined projects merely as a storehouse from which it could
draw the proposals it desired, it formed a new project of its own,
which ultimately received, after undergoing modification in detail,
the Imperial assent. Instead of being a mere chancellerie, as many
expected, it became in a certain sense the author of the
Emancipation Law.
* Known as the Redaktsionnaya Komissiya, or Elaboration Commission.
Strictly speaking, there were two, but they are commonly spoken of
as one.
There was, as we have seen, in nearly all the Provincial Committees
a majority and a minority, the former of which strove to defend the
interests of the proprietors, whilst the latter paid more attention
to theoretical considerations, and endeavoured to secure for the
peasantry a large amount of land and Communal self-government. In
the Commission there were the same two parties, but their relative
strength was very different. Here the men of theory, instead of
forming a minority, were more numerous than their opponents, and
enjoyed the support of the Government, which regulated the
proceedings. In its instructions we see how much the question had
ripened under the influence of the theoretical considerations.
There is no longer any trace of the idea that the Emancipation
should be gradual; on the contrary, it is expressly declared that
the immediate effect of the law should be the complete abolition of
the proprietor's authority. There is even evidence of a clear
intention of preventing the proprietor as far as possible from
exercising any influence over his former serfs. The sharp
distinction between the land occupied by the village and the arable
land to be ceded in usufruct likewise disappears, and it is merely
said that efforts should be made to enable the peasants to become
proprietors of the land they required.
The aim of the Government had thus become clear and well defined.
The task to be performed was to transform the serfs at once, and
with the least possible disturbance of the existing economic
conditions, into a class of small Communal proprietors--that is to
say, a class of free peasants possessing a house and garden and a
share of the Communal land. To effect this it was merely necessary
to declare the serf personally free, to draw a clear line of
demarcation between the Communal land and the rest of the estate,
and to determine the price or rent which should be paid for this
Communal property, inclusive of the land on which the village was
built.
The law was prepared in strict accordance with these principles.
As to the amount of land to be ceded, it was decided that the
existing arrangements, founded on experience, should, as a general
rule, be preserved--in other words, the land actually enjoyed by
the peasants should be retained by them; and in order to prevent
extreme cases of injustice, a maximum and a minimum were fixed for
each district. In like manner, as to the dues, it was decided that
the existing arrangements should be taken as the basis of the
calculation, but that the sum should be modified according to the
amount of land ceded. At the same time facilities were to be given
for the transforming of the labour dues into yearly money payments,
and for enabling the peasants to redeem them, with the assistance
of the Government, in the form of credit.
This idea of redemption created, at first, a feeling of alarm among
the proprietors. It was bad enough to be obliged to cede a large
part of the estates in usufruct, but it seemed to be much worse to
have to sell it. Redemption appeared to be a species of wholesale
confiscation. But very soon it became evident that the redeeming
of the land was profitable for both parties. Cession in perpetual
usufruct was felt to be in reality tantamount to alienation of the
land, whilst the immediate redemption would enable the proprietors,
who had generally little or no ready money to pay their debts, to
clear their estates from mortgages, and to make the outlays
necessary for the transition to free labour. The majority of the
proprietors, therefore, said openly: "Let the Government give us a
suitable compensation in money for the land that is taken from us,
so that we may be at once freed from all further trouble and
annoyance."
When it became known that the Commission was not merely arranging
and codifying the materials, but elaborating a law of its own and
regularly submitting its decisions for Imperial confirmation, a
feeling of dissatisfaction appeared all over the country. The
nobles perceived that the question was being taken out of their
hands, and was being solved by a small body composed of bureaucrats
and nominees of the Government. After having made a voluntary
sacrifice of their rights, they were being unceremoniously pushed
aside. They had still, however, the means of correcting this. The
Emperor had publicly promised that before the project should become
law deputies from the Provincial Committees should be summoned to
St. Petersburg to make objections and propose amendments.
The Commission and the Government would have willingly dispensed
with all further advice from the nobles, but it was necessary to
redeem the Imperial promise. Deputies were therefore summoned to
the capital, but they were not allowed to form, as they hoped, a
public assembly for the discussion of the question. All their
efforts to hold meetings were frustrated, and they were required
merely to answer in writing a list of printed questions regarding
matters of detail. The fundamental principles, they were told, had
already received the Imperial sanction, and were consequently
removed from discussion. Those who desired to discuss details were
invited individually to attend meetings of the Commission, where
they found one or two members ready to engage with them in a little
dialectical fencing. This, of course, did not give much
satisfaction. Indeed, the ironical tone in which the fencing was
too often conducted served to increase the existing irritation. It
was only too evident that the Commission had triumphed, and some of
the members could justly boast that they had drowned the deputies
in ink and buried them under reams of paper.
Believing, or at least professing to believe, that the Emperor was
being deceived in this matter by the Administration, several groups
of deputies presented petitions to his Majesty containing a
respectful protest against the manner in which they had been
treated. But by this act they simply laid themselves open to "the
most unkindest cut of all." Those who had signed the petitions
received a formal reprimand through the police.
This treatment of the deputies, and, above all, this gratuitous
insult, produced among the nobles a storm of indignation. They
felt that they had been entrapped. The Government had artfully
induced them to form projects for the emancipation of their serfs,
and now, after having been used as a cat's-paw in the work of their
own spoliation, they were being unceremoniously pushed aside as no
longer necessary. Those who had indulged in the hope of gaining
political rights felt the blow most keenly. A first gentle and
respectful attempt at remonstrance had been answered by a
dictatorial reprimand through the police! Instead of being called
to take an active part in home and foreign politics, they were
being treated as naughty schoolboys. In view of this insult all
differences of opinion were for the moment forgotten, and all
parties resolved to join in a vigorous protest against the
insolence and arbitrary conduct of the bureaucracy.
A convenient opportunity of making this protest in a legal way was
offered by the triennial Provincial Assemblies of the Noblesse
about to be held in several provinces. So at least it was thought,
but here again the Noblesse was checkmated by the Administration.
Before the opening of the Assemblies a circular was issued
excluding the Emancipation question from their deliberations. Some
Assemblies evaded this order, and succeeded in making a little
demonstration by submitting to his Majesty that the time had
arrived for other reforms, such as the separation of the
administrative and judicial powers, and the creation of local self-
government, public judicial procedure, and trial by jury.
All these reforms were voluntarily effected by the Emperor a few
years later, but the manner in which they were suggested seemed to
savour of insubordination, and was a flagrant infraction of the
principle that all initiative in public affairs should proceed from
the central Government. New measures of repression were
accordingly used. Some Marshals of Noblesse were reprimanded and
others deposed. Of the conspicuous leaders, two were exiled to
distant provinces and others placed under the supervision of the
police. Worst of all, the whole agitation strengthened the
Commission by convincing the Emperor that the majority of the
nobles were hostile to his benevolent plans.*
* This was a misinterpretation of the facts. Very many of those
who joined in the protest sincerely sympathised with the idea of
Emancipation, and were ready to be even more "liberal" than the
Government.
When the Commission had finished its labours, its proposals passed
to the two higher instances--the Committee for Peasant Affairs and
the Council of State--and in both of these the Emperor declared
plainly that he could allow no fundamental changes. From all the
members he demanded a complete forgetfulness of former differences
and a conscientious execution of his orders; "For you must
remember," he significantly added, "that in Russia laws are made by
the Autocratic Power." From an historical review of the question
he drew the conclusion that "the Autocratic Power created serfage,
and the Autocratic Power ought to abolish it." On March 3d
(February 19th, old style), 1861, the law was signed, and by that
act more than twenty millions of serfs were liberated.* A
Manifesto containing the fundamental principles of the law was at
once sent all over the country, and an order was given that it
should be read in all the churches.
* It is sometimes said that forty millions of serfs have been
emancipated. The statement is true, if we regard the State
peasants as serfs. They held, as I have already explained, an
intermediate position between serfage and freedom. The peculiar
administration under which they lived was partly abolished by
Imperial Orders of September 7th, 1859, and October 23d, 1861. In
1866 they were placed, as regards administration, on a level with
the emancipated serfs of the proprietors. As a general rule, they
received rather more land and had to pay somewhat lighter dues than
the emancipated serfs in the narrower sense of the term.
The three fundamental principles laid down by the law were:--
1. That the serfs should at once receive the civil rights of the
free rural classes, and that the authority of the proprietor should
be replaced by Communal self-government.
2. That the rural Communes should as far as possible retain the
land they actually held, and should in return pay to the proprietor
certain yearly dues in money or labour.
3. That the Government should by means of credit assist the
Communes to redeem these dues, or, in other words, to purchase the
lands ceded to them in usufruct.
With regard to the domestic serfs, it was enacted that they should
continue to serve their masters during two years, and that
thereafter they should be completely free, but they should have no
claim to a share of the land.
It might be reasonably supposed that the serfs received with
boundless gratitude and delight the Manifesto proclaiming these
principles. Here at last was the realisation of their long-
cherished hopes. Liberty was accorded to them; and not only
liberty, but a goodly portion of the soil--about half of all the
arable land possessed by the proprietors.
In reality the Manifesto created among the peasantry a feeling of
disappointment rather than delight. To understand this strange
fact we must endeavour to place ourselves at the peasant's point of
view.
In the first place it must be remarked that all vague, rhetorical
phrases about free labour, human dignity, national progress, and
the like, which may readily produce among educated men a certain
amount of temporary enthusiasm, fall on the ears of the Russian
peasant like drops of rain on a granite rock. The fashionable
rhetoric of philosophical liberalism is as incomprehensible to him
as the flowery circumlocutionary style of an Oriental scribe would
be to a keen city merchant. The idea of liberty in the abstract
and the mention of rights which lie beyond the sphere of his
ordinary everyday life awaken no enthusiasm in his breast. And for
mere names he has a profound indifference. What matters it to him
that he is officially called, not a "serf," but a "free village-
inhabitant," if the change in official terminology is not
accompanied by some immediate material advantage? What he wants is
a house to live in, food to eat, and raiment wherewithal to be
clothed, and to gain these first necessaries of life with as little
labour as possible. He looked at the question exclusively from two
points of view--that of historical right and that of material
advantage; and from both of these the Emancipation Law seemed to
him very unsatisfactory.
On the subject of historical right the peasantry had their own
traditional conceptions, which were completely at variance with the
written law. According to the positive legislation the Communal
land formed part of the estate, and consequently belonged to the
proprietor; but according to the conceptions of the peasantry it
belonged to the Commune, and the right of the proprietor consisted
merely in that personal authority over the serfs which had been
conferred on him by the Tsar. The peasants could not, of course,
put these conceptions into a strict legal form, but they often
expressed them in their own homely laconic way by saying to their
master, "Mui vashi no zemlya nasha"--that is to say. "We are
yours, but the land is ours." And it must be admitted that this
view, though legally untenable, had a certain historical
justification.*
* See preceding chapter.
In olden times the Noblesse had held their land by feudal tenure,
and were liable to be ejected as soon as they did not fulfil their
obligations to the State. These obligations had been long since
abolished, and the feudal tenure transformed into an unconditional
right of property, but the peasants clung to the old ideas in a way
that strikingly illustrates the vitality of deep-rooted popular
conceptions. In their minds the proprietors were merely temporary
occupants, who were allowed by the Tsar to exact labour and dues
from the serfs. What, then, was Emancipation? Certainly the
abolition of all obligatory labour and money dues, and perhaps the
complete ejectment of the proprietors. On this latter point there
was a difference of opinion. All assumed, as a matter of course,
that the Communal land would remain the property of the Commune,
but it was not so clear what would be done with the rest of the
estate. Some thought that it would be retained by the proprietor,
but very many believed that all the land would be given to the
Communes. In this way the Emancipation would be in accordance with
historical right and with the material advantage of the peasantry,
for whose exclusive benefit, it was assumed, the reform had been
undertaken.
Instead of this the peasants found that they were still to pay
dues, even for the Communal land which they regarded as
unquestionably their own. So at least said the expounders of the
law. But the thing was incredible. Either the proprietors must be
concealing or misinterpreting the law, or this was merely a
preparatory measure, which would be followed by the real
Emancipation. Thus were awakened among the peasantry a spirit of
mistrust and suspicion and a widespread belief that there would be
a second Imperial Manifesto, by which all the land would be divided
and all the dues abolished.
On the nobles the Manifesto made a very different impression. The
fact that they were to be entrusted with the putting of the law
into execution, and the flattering allusions made to the spirit of
generous self-sacrifice which they had exhibited, kindled amongst
them enthusiasm enough to make them forget for a time their just
grievances and their hostility towards the bureaucracy. They found
that the conditions on which the Emancipation was effected were by
no means so ruinous as they had anticipated; and the Emperor's
appeal to their generosity and patriotism made many of them throw
themselves with ardour into the important task confided to them.
Unfortunately they could not at once begin the work. The law had
been so hurried through the last stages that the preparations for
putting it into execution were by no means complete when the
Manifesto was published. The task of regulating the future
relations between the proprietors and the peasantry was entrusted
to local proprietors in each district, who were to be called
Arbiters of the Peace (Mirovuiye Posredniki); but three months
elapsed before these Arbiters could be appointed. During that time
there was no one to explain the law to the peasants and settle the
disputes between them and the proprietors; and the consequence of
this was that many cases of insubordination and disorder occurred.
The muzhik naturally imagined that, as soon as the Tsar said he was
free, he was no longer obliged to work for his old master--that all
obligatory labour ceased as soon as the Manifesto was read. In
vain the proprietor endeavoured to convince him that, in regard to
labour, the old relations must continue, as the law enjoined, until
a new arrangement had been made. To all explanations and
exhortations he turned a deaf ear, and to the efforts of the rural
police he too often opposed a dogged, passive resistance.
In many cases the simple appearance of the higher authorities
sufficed to restore order, for the presence of one of the Tsar's
servants convinced many that the order to work for the present as
formerly was not a mere invention of the proprietors. But not
infrequently the birch had to be applied. Indeed, I am inclined to
believe, from the numerous descriptions of this time which I
received from eye-witnesses, that rarely, if ever, had the serfs
seen and experienced so much flogging as during these first three
months after their liberation. Sometimes even the troops had to be
called out, and on three occasions they fired on the peasants with
ball cartridge. In the most serious case, where a young peasant
had set up for a prophet and declared that the Emancipation Law was
a forgery, fifty-one peasants were killed and seventy-seven were
more or less seriously wounded. In spite of these lamentable
incidents, there was nothing which even the most violent alarmist
could dignify with the name of an insurrection. Nowhere was there
anything that could be called organised resistance. Even in the
case above alluded to, the three thousand peasants on whom the
troops fired were entirely unarmed, made no attempt to resist, and
dispersed in the utmost haste as soon as they discovered that they
were being shot down. Had the military authorities shown a little
more judgment, tact, and patience, the history of the Emancipation
would not have been stained even with those three solitary cases of
unnecessary bloodshed.
This interregnum between the eras of serfage and liberty was
brought to an end by the appointment of the Arbiters of the Peace.
Their first duty was to explain the law, and to organise the new
peasant self-government. The lowest instance, or primary organ of
this self-government, the rural Commune, already existed, and at
once recovered much of its ancient vitality as soon as the
authority and interference of the proprietors were removed. The
second instance, the Volost--a territorial administrative unit
comprising several contiguous Communes--had to be created, for
nothing of the kind had previously existed on the estates of the
nobles. It had existed, however, for nearly a quarter of a century
among the peasants of the Domains, and it was therefore necessary
merely to copy an existing model.
As soon as all the Volosts in his district had been thus organised
the Arbiter had to undertake the much more arduous task of
regulating the agrarian relations between the proprietors and the
Communes--with the individual peasants, be it remembered, the
proprietors had no direct relations whatever. It had been enacted
by the law that the future agrarian relations between the two
parties should be left, as far as possible, to voluntary contract;
and accordingly each proprietor was invited to come to an agreement
with the Commune or Communes on his estate. On the ground of this
agreement a statute-charter (ustavnaya gramota) was prepared,
specifying the number of male serfs, the quantity of land actually
enjoyed by them, any proposed changes in this amount, the dues
proposed to be levied, and other details. If the Arbiter found
that the conditions were in accordance with the law and clearly
understood by the peasants, he confirmed the charter, and the
arrangement was complete. When the two parties could not come to
an agreement within a year, he prepared a charter according to his
own judgment, and presented it for confirmation to the higher
authorities.
The dissolution of partnership, if it be allowable to use such a
term, between the proprietor and his serfs was sometimes very easy
and sometimes very difficult. On many estates the charter did
little more than legalise the existing arrangements, but in many
instances it was necessary to add to, or subtract from, the amount
of Communal land, and sometimes it was even necessary to remove the
village to another part of the estate. In all cases there were, of
course, conflicting interests and complicated questions, so that
the Arbiter had always abundance of difficult work. Besides this,
he had to act as mediator in those differences which naturally
arose during the transition period, when the authority of the
proprietor had been abolished but the separation of the two classes
had not yet been effected. The unlimited patriarchal authority
which had been formerly wielded by the proprietor or his steward
now passed with certain restriction into the hands of the Arbiter,
and these peacemakers had to spend a great part of their time in
driving about from one estate to another to put an end to alleged
cases of insubordination--some of which, it must be admitted,
existed only in the imagination of the proprietors.
At first the work of amicable settlement proceeded slowly. The
proprietors generally showed a conciliatory spirit, and some of
them generously proposed conditions much more favourable to the
peasants than the law demanded; but the peasants were filled with
vague suspicions, and feared to commit themselves by "putting pen
to paper." Even the highly respected proprietors, who imagined
that they possessed the unbounded confidence of the peasantry, were
suspected like the others, and their generous offers were regarded
as well-baited traps. Often I have heard old men, sometimes with
tears in their eyes, describe the distrust and ingratitude of the
muzhik at this time. Many peasants still believed that the
proprietors were hiding the real Emancipation Law, and imaginative
or ill-intentioned persons fostered this belief by professing to
know what the real law contained. The most absurd rumours were
afloat, and whole villages sometimes acted upon them.
In the province of Moscow, for instance, one Commune sent a
deputation to the proprietor to inform him that, as he had always
been a good master, the Mir would allow him to retain his house and
garden during his lifetime. In another locality it was rumoured
that the Tsar sat daily on a golden throne in the Crimea, receiving
all peasants who came to him, and giving them as much land as they
desired; and in order to take advantage of the Imperial liberality
a large body of peasants set out for the place indicated, and had
to he stopped by the military.
As an illustration of the illusions in which the peasantry indulged
at this time, I may mention here one of the many characteristic
incidents related to me by gentlemen who had served as Arbiters of
the Peace.
In the province of Riazan there was one Commune which had acquired
a certain local notoriety for the obstinacy with which it refused
all arrangements with the proprietor. My informant, who was
Arbiter for the locality, was at last obliged to make a statute-
charter for it without its consent. He wished, however, that the
peasants should voluntarily accept the arrangement he proposed, and
accordingly called them together to talk with them on the subject.
After explaining fully the part of the law which related to their
case, he asked them what objection they had to make a fair contract
with their old master. For some time he received no answer, but
gradually by questioning individuals he discovered the cause of
their obstinacy: they were firmly convinced that not only the
Communal land, but also the rest of the estate, belonged to them.
To eradicate this false idea he set himself to reason with them,
and the following characteristic dialogue ensued:--
Arbiter: "If the Tsar gave all the land to the peasantry, what
compensation could he give to the proprietors to whom the land
belongs?"
Peasant: "The Tsar will give them salaries according to their
service."
Arbiter: "In order to pay these salaries he would require a great
deal more money. Where could he get that money? He would have to
increase the taxes, and in that way you would have to pay all the
same."
Peasant: "The Tsar can make as much money as he likes."
Arbiter: "If the Tsar can make as much money as he likes, why does
he make you pay the poll-tax every year?"
Peasant: "It is not the Tsar that receives the taxes we pay."
Arbiter: "Who, then, receives them?"
Peasant (after a little hesitation, and with a knowing smite): "The
officials, of course!"
Gradually, through the efforts of the Arbiters, the peasants came
to know better their real position, and the work began to advance
more rapidly. But soon it was checked by another influence. By
the end of the first year the "liberal," patriotic enthusiasm of
the nobles had cooled. The sentimental, idyllic tendencies had
melted away at the first touch of reality, and those who had
imagined that liberty would have an immediately salutary effect on
the moral character of the serfs confessed themselves disappointed.
Many complained that the peasants showed themselves greedy and
obstinate, stole wood from the forest, allowed their cattle to
wander on the proprietor's fields, failed to fulfil their legal
obligations, and broke their voluntary engagements. At the same
time the fears of an agrarian rising subsided, so that even the
timid were tranquillised. From these causes the conciliatory
spirit of the proprietors decreased.
The work of conciliating and regulating became consequently more
difficult, but the great majority of the Arbiters showed themselves
equal to the task, and displayed an impartiality, tact and patience
beyond all praise. To them Russia is in great part indebted for
the peaceful character of the Emancipation. Had they sacrificed
the general good to the interests of their class, or had they
habitually acted in that stern, administrative, military spirit
which caused the instances of bloodshed above referred to, the
prophecies of the alarmists would, in all probability, have been
realised, and the historian of the Emancipation would have had a
terrible list of judicial massacres to record. Fortunately they
played the part of mediators, as their name signified, rather than
that of administrators in the bureaucratic sense of the term, and
they were animated with a just and humane rather than a merely
legal spirit. Instead of simply laying down the law, and ordering
their decisions to be immediately executed, they were ever ready to
spend hours in trying to conquer, by patient and laborious
reasoning, the unjust claims of proprietors or the false
conceptions and ignorant obstinacy of the peasants. It was a new
spectacle for Russia to see a public function fulfilled by
conscientious men who had their heart in their work, who sought
neither promotion nor decorations, and who paid less attention to
the punctilious observance of prescribed formalities than to the
real objects in view.
There were, it is true, a few men to whom this description does not
apply. Some of these were unduly under the influence of the
feelings and conceptions created by serfage. Some, on the
contrary, erred on the other side. Desirous of securing the future
welfare of the peasantry and of gaining for themselves a certain
kind of popularity, and at the same time animated with a violent
spirit of pseudo-liberalism, these latter occasionally forgot that
their duty was to be, not generous, but just, and that they had no
right to practise generosity at other people's expense. All this I
am quite aware of--I could even name one or two Arbiters who were
guilty of positive dishonesty--but I hold that these were rare
exceptions. The great majority did their duty faithfully and well.
The work of concluding contracts for the redemption of the dues,
or, in other words, for the purchase of the land ceded in perpetual
usufruct, proceeded slowly. The arrangement was as follows:--
The dues were capitalised at six per cent., and the Government paid
at once to the proprietors four-fifths of the whole sum. The
peasants were to pay to the proprietor the remaining fifth, either
at once or in installments, and to the Government six per cent. for
forty-nine years on the sum advanced. The proprietors willingly
adopted this arrangement, for it provided them with a sum of ready
money, and freed them from the difficult task of collecting the
dues. But the peasants did not show much desire to undertake the
operation. Some of them still expected a second Emancipation, and
those who did not take this possibility into their calculations
were little disposed to make present sacrifices for distant
prospective advantages which would not be realised for half a
century. In most cases the proprietor was obliged to remit, in
whole or in part, the fifth to be paid by the peasants. Many
Communes refused to undertake the operation on any conditions and
in consequence of this not a few proprietors demanded the so-called
obligatory redemption, according to which they accepted the four-
fifths from the Government as full payment, and the operation was
thus effected without the peasants being consulted. The total
number of male serfs emancipated was about nine millions and three-
quarters,* and of these, only about seven millions and a quarter
had, at the beginning of 1875, made redemption contracts. Of the
contracts signed at that time, about sixty-three per cent, were
"obligatory." In 1887 the redemption was made obligatory for both
parties, so that all Communes are now proprietors of the land
previously held in perpetual usufruct; and in 1932 the debt will
have been extinguished by the sinking fund, and all redemption
payments will have ceased.
* This does not include the domestic serfs who did not receive
land.
The serfs were thus not only liberated, but also made possessors of
land and put on the road to becoming Communal proprietors, and the
old Communal institutions were preserved and developed. In answer
to the question, Who effected this gigantic reform? we may say that
the chief merit undoubtedly belongs to Alexander II. Had he not
possessed a very great amount of courage he would neither have
raised the question nor allowed it to be raised by others, and had
he not shown a great deal more decision and energy than was
expected, the solution would have been indefinitely postponed.
Among the members of his own family he found an able and energetic
assistant in his brother, the Grand Duke Constantine, and a warm
sympathiser with the cause in the Grand Duchess Helena, a German
Princess thoroughly devoted to the welfare of her adopted country.
But we must not overlook the important part played by the nobles.
Their conduct was very characteristic. As soon as the question was
raised a large number of them adopted the liberal ideas with
enthusiasm; and as soon as it became evident that Emancipation was
inevitable, all made a holocaust of their ancient rights and
demanded to be liberated at once from all relations with their
serfs. Moreover, when the law was passed it was the proprietors
who faithfully put it into execution. Lastly, we should remember
that praise is due to the peasantry for their patience under
disappointment and for their orderly conduct as soon as they
understood the law and recognised it to be the will of the Tsar.
Thus it may justly be said that the Emancipation was not the work
of one man, or one party, or one class, but of the nation as a
whole.*
* The names most commonly associated with the Emancipation are
General Rostoftsef, Lanskoi (Minister of the Interior), Nicholas
Milutin, Prince Tchererkassky, G. Samarin, Koshelef. Many others,
such as I. A. Solovief, Zhukofski, Domontovitch, Giers--brother of
M. Giers, afterwards Minister for Foreign Affairs--are less known,
but did valuable work. To all of these, with the exception of the
first two, who died before my arrival in Russia, I have to confess
my obligations. The late Nicholas Milutin rendered me special
service by putting at my disposal not only all the official papers
in his possession, but also many documents of a more private kind.
By his early and lamented death Russia lost one of the greatest
statesmen she has yet produced.
CHAPTER XXX
THE LANDED PROPRIETORS SINCE THE EMANCIPATION
Two Opposite Opinions--Difficulties of Investigation--The Problem
Simplified--Direct and Indirect Compensation--The Direct
Compensation Inadequate--What the Proprietors Have Done with the
Remainder of Their Estates--Immediate Moral Effect of the Abolition
of Serfage--The Economic Problem--The Ideal Solution and the
Difficulty of Realising It--More Primitive Arrangements--The
Northern Agricultural Zone--The Black-earth Zone--The Labour
Difficulty--The Impoverishment of the Noblesse Not a New
Phenomenon--Mortgaging of Estates--Gradual Expropriation of the
Noblesse-Rapid Increase in the Production and Export of Grain--How
Far this Has Benefited the Landed Proprietors.
When the Emancipation question was raised there was a considerable
diversity of opinion as to the effect which the abolition of
serfage would have on the material interests of the two classes
directly concerned. The Press and "the young generation" took an
optimistic view, and endeavoured to prove that the proposed change
would be beneficial alike to proprietors and to peasants. Science,
it was said, has long since decided that free labour is immensely
more productive than slavery or serfage, and the principle has been
already proved to demonstration in the countries of Western Europe.
In all those countries modern agricultural progress began with the
emancipation of the serfs, and increased productivity was
everywhere the immediate result of improvements in the method of
culture. Thus the poor light soils of Germany, France, and Holland
have been made to produce more than the vaunted "black earth" of
Russia. And from these ameliorations the land-owning class has
everywhere derived the chief advantages. Are not the landed
proprietors of England--the country in which serfage was first
abolished--the richest in the world? And is not the proprietor of
a few hundred morgen in Germany often richer than the Russian noble
who has thousands of dessyatins? By these and similar plausible
arguments the Press endeavoured to prove to the proprietors that
they ought, even in their own interest, to undertake the
emancipation of the serfs. Many proprietors, however, showed
little faith in the abstract principles of political economy and
the vague teachings of history as interpreted by the contemporary
periodical literature. They could not always refute the ingenious
arguments adduced by the men of more sanguine temperament, but they
felt convinced that their prospects were not nearly so bright as
these men represented them to be. They believed that Russia was a
peculiar country, and the Russians a peculiar people. The lower
classes in England, France, Holland, and Germany were well known to
be laborious and enterprising, while the Russian peasant was
notoriously lazy, and would certainly, if left to himself, not do
more work than was absolutely necessary to keep him from starving.
Free labour might be more profitable than serfage in countries
where the upper classes possessed traditional practical knowledge
and abundance of capital, but in Russia the proprietors had neither
the practical knowledge nor the ready money necessary to make the
proposed ameliorations in the system of agriculture. To all this
it was added that a system of emancipation by which the peasants
should receive land and be made completely independent of the
landed proprietors had nowhere been tried on such a large scale.
There were thus two diametrically opposite opinions regarding the
economic results of the abolition of serfage, and we have now to
examine which of these two opinions has been confirmed by
experience.
Let us look at the question first from the point of view of the
land-owners.
The reader who has never attempted to make investigations of this
kind may naturally imagine that the question can be easily decided
by simply consulting a large number of individual proprietors, and
drawing a general conclusion from their evidence. In reality I
found the task much more difficult. After roaming about the
country for five years (1870-75), collecting information from the
best available sources, I hesitated to draw any sweeping
conclusions, and my state of mind at that time was naturally
reflected in the early editions of this work. As a rule the
proprietors could not state clearly how much they had lost or
gained, and when definite information was obtained from them it was
not always trustworthy. In the time of serfage very few of them
had been in the habit of keeping accurate accounts, or accounts of
any kind, and when they lived on their estates there were a very
large number of items which could not possibly be reduced to
figures. Of course, each proprietor had a general idea as to
whether his position was better or worse than it had been in the
old times, but the vague statements made by individuals regarding
their former and their actual revenues had little or no scientific
value. So many considerations which had nothing to do with purely
agrarian relations entered into the calculations that the
conclusions did not help me much to estimate the economic results
of the Emancipation as a whole. Nor, it must be confessed, was the
testimony by any means always unbiassed. Not a few spoke of the
great reform in an epic or dithyrambic tone, and among these I
easily distinguished two categories: the one desired to prove that
the measure was a complete success in every way, and that all
classes were benefited by it, not only morally, but also
materially; whilst the others strove to represent the proprietors
in general, and themselves in particular, as the self-sacrificing
victims of a great and necessary patriotic reform--as martyrs in
the cause of liberty and progress. I do not for a moment suppose
that these two groups of witnesses had a clearly conceived
intention of deceiving or misleading, but as a cautious
investigator I had to make allowance for their idealising and
sentimental tendencies.
Since that time the situation has become much clearer, and during
recent visits to Russia I have been able to arrive at much more
definite conclusions. These I now proceed to communicate to the
reader.
The Emancipation caused the proprietors of all classes to pass
through a severe economic crisis. Periods of transition always
involve much suffering, and the amount of suffering is generally in
the inverse ratio of the precautions taken beforehand. In Russia
the precautions had been neglected. Not one proprietor in a
hundred had made any serious preparations for the inevitable
change. On the eve of the Emancipation there were about ten
millions of male serfs on private properties, and of these nearly
seven millions remained under the old system of paying their dues
in labour. Of course, everybody knew that Emancipation must come
sooner or later, but fore-thought, prudence, and readiness to take
time by the forelock are not among the prominent traits of the
Russian character. Hence most of the land-owners were taken
unawares. But while all suffered, there were differences of
degree. Some were completely shipwrecked. So long as serfage
existed all the relations of life were ill-defined and extremely
elastic, so that a man who was hopelessly insolvent might contrive,
with very little effort, to keep his bead above water for half a
lifetime. For such men the Emancipation, like a crisis in the
commercial world, brought a day of reckoning. It did not really
ruin them, but it showed them and the world at large that they were
ruined, and they could no longer continue their old mode of life.
For others the crisis was merely temporary. These emerged with a
larger income than they ever had before, but I am not prepared to
say that their material condition has improved, because the social
habits have changed, the cost of living has become much greater,
and the work of administering estates is incomparably more
complicated and laborious than in the old patriarchal times.
We may greatly simplify the problem by reducing it to two definite
questions:
1. How far were the proprietors directly indemnified for the loss
of serf labour and for the transfer in perpetual usufruct of a
large part of their estates to the peasantry?
2. What have the proprietors done with the remainder of their
estates, and how far have they been indirectly indemnified by the
economic changes which have taken place since the Emancipation?
With the first of these questions I shall deal very briefly,
because it is a controversial subject involving very complicated
calculations which only a specialist can understand. The
conclusion at which I have arrived, after much patient research, is
that in most provinces the compensation was inadequate, and this
conclusion is confirmed by excellent native authorities. M.
Bekhteyev, for example, one of the most laborious and conscientious
investigators in this field of research, and the author of an
admirable work on the economic results of the Emancipation,* told
me recently, in course of conversation, that in his opinion the
peasant dues fixed by the Emancipation Law represented, throughout
the Black-earth Zone, only about a half of the value of the labour
previously supplied by the serfs. To this I must add that the
compensation was in reality not nearly so great as it seemed to be
according to the terms of the law. As the proprietors found it
extremely difficult to collect the dues from the emancipated serfs,
and as they required a certain amount of capital to reorganise the
estate on the new basis of free labour, most of them were
practically compelled to demand the obligatory redemption of the
land (obiazatelny vuikup), and in adopting this expedient they had
to make considerable sacrifices. Not only had they to accept as
full payment four-fifths of the normal sum, but of this amount the
greater portion was paid in Treasury bonds, which fell at once to
80 per cent. of their nominal value.
* "Khozaistvenniye Itogi istekshago Sorokoletiya." St. Petersburg,
1902.
Let us now pass to the second part of the problem: What have the
proprietors done with the part of their estates which remained to
them after ceding the required amount of land to the Communes?
Have they been indirectly indemnified for the loss of serf labour
by subsequent economic changes? How far have they succeeded in
making the transition from serfage to free labour, and what
revenues do they now derive from their estates? The answer to
these questions will necessarily contain some account of the
present economic position of the proprietors.
On all proprietors the Emancipation had at least one good effect:
it dragged them forcibly from the old path of indolence and routine
and compelled them to think and calculate regarding their affairs.
The hereditary listlessness and apathy, the traditional habit of
looking on the estate with its serfs as a kind of self-acting
machine which must always spontaneously supply the owner with the
means of living, the inveterate practice of spending all ready
money and of taking little heed for the morrow--all this, with much
that resulted from it, was rudely swept away and became a thing of
the past.
The broad, easy road on which the proprietors had hitherto let
themselves be borne along by the force of circumstances suddenly
split up into a number of narrow, arduous, thorny paths. Each one
had to use his judgement to determine which of the paths he should
adopt, and, having made his choice, he had to struggle along as he
best could. I remember once asking a proprietor what effect the
Emancipation had had on the class to which he belonged, and he gave
me an answer which is worth recording. "Formerly," he said, "we
kept no accounts and drank champagne; now we keep accounts and
content ourselves with kvass." Like all epigrammatic sayings, this
laconic reply is far from giving a complete description of reality,
but it indicates in a graphic way a change that has unquestionably
taken place. As soon as serfage was abolished it was no longer
possible to live like "the flowers of the field." Many a
proprietor who had formerly vegetated in apathetic ease had to ask
himself the question: How am I to gain a living? All had to
consider what was the most profitable way of employing the land
that remained to them.
The ideal solution of the problem was that as soon as the peasant-
land had been demarcated, the proprietor should take to farming the
remainder of his estate by means of hired labour and agricultural
machines in West European or American fashion. Unfortunately, this
solution could not be generally adopted, because the great majority
of the landlords, even when they had the requisite practical
knowledge of agriculture, had not the requisite capital, and could
not easily obtain it. Where were they to find money for buying
cattle, horses, and agricultural implements, for building stables
and cattle-sheds, and for defraying all the other initial expenses?
And supposing they succeeded in starting the new system, where was
the working capital to come from? The old Government institution
in which estates could be mortgaged according to the number of
serfs was permanently closed, and the new land-credit associations
had not yet come into existence. To borrow from private
capitalists was not to be thought of, for money was so scarce than
ten per cent. was considered a "friendly" rate of interest.
Recourse might be had, it is true, to the redemption operation, but
in that case the Government would deduct the unpaid portion of any
outstanding mortgage, and would pay the balance in depreciated
Treasury bonds. In these circumstances the proprietors could not,
as a rule, adopt what I have called the ideal solution, and had to
content themselves with some simpler and more primitive
arrangement. They could employ the peasants of the neighbouring
villages to prepare the land and reap the crops either for a fixed
sum per acre or on the metayage system, or they could let their
land to the peasants for one, three or six years at a moderate
rent.
In the northern agricultural zone, where the soil is poor and
primitive farming with free labour can hardly be made to pay, the
proprietors had to let their land at a small rent, and those of
them who could not find places in the rural administration migrated
to the towns and sought employment in the public service or in the
numerous commercial and industrial enterprises which were springing
up at that time. There they have since remained. Their country-
houses, if inhabited at all, are occupied only for a few months in
summer, and too often present a melancholy spectacle of neglect and
dilapidation. In the Black-earth Zone, on the contrary, where the
soil still possesses enough of its natural fertility to make
farming on a large scale profitable, the estates are in a very
different condition. The owners cultivate at least a part of their
property, and can easily let to the peasants at a fair rent the
land which they do not wish to farm themselves. Some have adopted
the metayage system; others get the field-work done by the peasants
at so much per acre. The more energetic, who have capital enough
at their disposal, organise farms with hired labourers on the
European model. If they are not so well off as formerly, it is
because they have adopted a less patriarchal and more expensive
style of living. Their land has doubled and trebled in value
during the last thirty years, and their revenues have increased, if
not in proportion, at least considerably. In 1903 I visited a
number of estates in this region and found them in a very
prosperous condition, with agricultural machines of the English or
American types, an increasing variety in the rotation of crops,
greatly improved breeds of cattle and horses, and all the other
symptoms of a gradual transition to a more intensive and more
rational system of agriculture.
It must be admitted, however, that even in the Black-earth Zone the
proprietors have formidable difficulties to contend with, the chief
of which are the scarcity of good farm-labourers, the frequent
droughts, the low price of cereals, and the delay in getting the
grain conveyed to the seaports. On each of these difficulties and
the remedies that might be applied I could write a separate
chapter, but I fear to overtax the reader's patience, and shall
therefore confine myself to a few remarks about the labour
question. On this subject the complaints are loud and frequent all
over the country. The peasants, it is said, have become lazy,
careless, addicted to drunkenness, and shamelessly dishonest with
regard to their obligations, so that it is difficult to farm even
in the old primitive fashion and impossible to introduce radical
improvements in the methods of culture. In these sweeping
accusations there is a certain amount of truth. That the muzhik,
when working for others, exerts himself as little as possible; that
he pays little attention to the quality of the work done; that he
shows a reckless carelessness with regard to his employer's
property; that he is capable of taking money in advance and failing
to fulfil his contract; that he occasionally gets drunk; and that
he is apt to commit certain acts of petty larceny when he gets the
chance--all this is undoubtedly true, whatever biassed theorists
and sentimental peasant-worshippers may say to the contrary.* It
would be a mistake, however, to suppose that the fault is entirely
on the side of the peasants, and equally erroneous to believe that
the evils might be remedied, as is often suggested, by greater
severity on the part of the tribunals, or by an improved system of
passports. Farming with free labour, like every other department
of human activity, requires a fair amount of knowledge, judgment,
prudence, and tact, which cannot be replaced by ingenious
legislation or judicial severity. In engaging labourers or
servants it is necessary to select them carefully and make such
conditions that they feel it to be to their interest to fulfil
their contract loyally. This is too often overlooked by the
Russian land-owners. From false views of economy they are inclined
to choose the cheapest labourer without examining closely his other
qualifications, or they take advantage of the peasant's pecuniary
embarrassments and make with him a contract which it is hardly
possible for him to fulfil. In spring, for instance, when his
store of provisions is exhausted and he is being hard pressed by
the tax-collector, they supply him with rye-meal or advance him a
small sum of money on condition of his undertaking to do a
relatively large amount of summer work. He knows that the contract
is unfair to him, but what is he to do? He must get food for
himself and his family and a little ready money for his taxes, for
the Communal authorities will probably sell his cow if he does not
pay his arrears.** In desperation he accepts the conditions and
puts off the evil day--consoling himself with the reflection that
perhaps (avos') something may turn up in the meantime--but when the
time comes for fulfilling his engagements the dilemma revives.
According to the contract he ought to work nearly the whole summer
for the proprietor; but he has his own land to attend to, and he
has to make provision for the winter. In such circumstances the
temptation to evade the terms of the contract is probably too
strong to be resisted.
* Amongst themselves the peasants are not addicted to thieving, as
is proved by the fact that they habitually leave their doors
unlocked when the inmates of the house are working in the fields;
but if the muzhik finds in the proprietor's farmyard a piece of
iron or a bit of rope, or any of those little things that he
constantly requires and has difficulty in obtaining, he is very apt
to pick it up and carry it home. Gathering firewood in the
landlord's forest he does not consider as theft, because "God
planted the trees and watered them," and in the time of serfage he
was allowed to supply himself with firewood in this way.
** Until last year (1904) they could use also corporal punishment
as a means of pressure, and I am not sure that they do not
occasionally use it still, though it is no longer permitted by law.
In Russia, as in other countries, the principle holds true that for
good labour a fair price must be paid. Several large proprietors
of my acquaintance who habitually act on this principle assure me
that they always obtain as much good labour as they require. I
must add, however, that these fortunate proprietors have the
advantage of possessing a comfortable amount of working capital,
and are therefore not compelled, as so many of their less fortunate
neighbours are, to manage their estates on the hand-to-mouth
principle.
It is only, I fear, a minority of the landed proprietors that have
grappled successfully with these and other difficulties of their
position. As a class they are impoverished and indebted, but this
state of things is not due entirely to serf-emancipation. The
indebtedness of the Noblesse is a hereditary peculiarity of much
older date. By some authorities it is attributed to the laws of
Peter the Great, by which all nobles were obliged to spend the best
part of their lives in the military or civil service, and to leave
the management of their estates to incompetent stewards. However
that may be, it is certain that from the middle of the eighteenth
century downwards the fact has frequently occupied the attention of
the Government, and repeated attempts have been made to alleviate
the evil. The Empress Elizabeth, Catherine II., Paul, Alexander
I., Nicholas I., Alexander II., and Alexander III. tried
successively, as one of the older ukazes expressed it, "to free the
Noblesse from debt and from greedy money-lenders, and to prevent
hereditary estates from passing into the hands of strangers." The
means commonly adopted was the creation of mortgage banks founded
and controlled by the Government for the purpose of advancing money
to landed proprietors at a comparatively low rate of interest.
These institutions may have been useful to the few who desired to
improve their estates, but they certainly did not cure, and rather
tended to foster, the inveterate improvidence of the many. On the
eve of the Emancipation the proprietors were indebted to the
Government for the sum of 425 millions of roubles, and 69 per cent.
of their serfs were mortgaged. A portion of this debt was
gradually extinguished by the redemption operation, so that in 1880
over 300 millions had been paid off, but in the meantime new debts
were being contracted. In 1873-74 nine private land-mortgage banks
were created, and there was such a rush to obtain money from them
that their paper was a glut in the market, and became seriously
depreciated. When the prices of grain rose in 1875-80 the mortgage
debt was diminished, but when they began to fall in 1880 it again
increased, and in 1881 it stood at 396 millions. As the rate of
interest was felt to be very burdensome there was a strong feeling
among the landed proprietors at that time that the Government ought
to help them, and in 1883 the nobles of the province of Orel
ventured to address the Emperor on the subject. In reply to the
address, Alexander III., who had strong Conservative leanings, was
graciously pleased to declare in an ukaz that "it was really time
to do something to help the Noblesse," and accordingly a new land-
mortgage bank for the Noblesse was created. The favourable terms
offered by it were taken advantage of to such an extent that in the
first four years of its activity (1886-90) it advanced to the
proprietors over 200 million roubles. Then came two famine years,
and in 1894 the mortgage debt of the Noblesse in that and other
credit establishments was estimated at 994 millions. It has since
probably increased rather than diminished, for in that year the
prices of grain began to fall steadily on all the corn-exchanges of
the world, and they have never since recovered.
By means of mortgages some proprietors succeeded in weathering the
storm, but many gave up the struggle altogether, and settled in the
towns. In the space of thirty years 20,000 of them sold their
estates, and thus, between 1861 and 1892, the area of land
possessed by the Noblesse diminished 30 per cent.--from 77,804,000
to 55,500,000 dessyatins.
This expropriation of the Noblesse, as it is called, was evidently
not the result merely of the temporary economic disturbance caused
by the abolition of serfage, for as time went on it became more
rapid. During the first twenty years the average annual amount of
Noblesse land sold was 517,000 dessyatins, and it rose steadily
until 1892-96, when it reached the amount of 785,000. As I have
already stated, the townward movement of the proprietors was
strongest in the barren Northern provinces. In the province of
Olonetz, for example, they have already parted with 87 per cent. of
their land. In the black-soil region, on the contrary, there is no
province in which more than 27 per cent. of the Noblesse land has
been alienated, and in one province (Tula) the amount is only 19
per cent.
The habit of mortgaging and selling estates does not necessarily
mean the impoverishment of the landlords as a class. If the
capital raised in that way is devoted to agricultural improvements,
the result may be an increase of wealth. Unfortunately, in Russia
the realised capital was usually not so employed. A very large
proportion of it was spent unproductively, partly in luxuries and
living abroad, and partly in unprofitable commercial and industrial
speculations. The industrial and railway fever which raged at the
time induced many to risk and lose their capital, and it had
indirectly an injurious effect on all by making money plentiful in
the towns and creating a more expensive style of living, from which
the landed gentry could not hold entirely aloof.
So far I have dwelt on the dark shadows of the picture, but it is
not all shadow. In the last forty years the production and export
of grain, which constitute the chief source of revenue for the
Noblesse, have increased enormously, thanks mainly to the improved
means of transport. In the first decade after the Emancipation
(1860-70) the average annual export did not exceed 88 million puds;
in the second decade (1870-80) it leapt up to 218 millions; and so
it went up steadily until in the last decade of the century it had
reached 388 millions--i.e., over six million tons. At the same
time the home trade had increased likewise in consequence of the
rapidly growing population of the towns. All this must have
enriched the land-proprietors. Not to such an extent, it is true,
as the figures seem to indicate, because the old prices could not
be maintained. Rye, for example, which in 1868 stood at 129 kopeks
per pud, fell as low as 56, and during the rest of the century,
except during a short time in 1881-82 and the famine years of 1891-
92, when there was very little surplus to sell, it never rose above
80. Still, the increase in quantity more than counterbalanced the
fall in price. For example: in 1881 the average price of grain per
pud was 119, and in 1894 it had sunk to 59; but the amount exported
during that time rose from 203 to 617 million puds, and the sum
received for it had risen from 242 to 369 millions of roubles.
Surely the whole of that enormous sum was not squandered on
luxuries and unprofitable speculation!
The pessimists, however--and in Russia their name is legion--will
not admit that any permanent advantage has been derived from this
enormous increase in exports. On the contrary, they maintain that
it is a national misfortune, because it is leading rapidly to a
state of permanent impoverishment. It quickly exhausted, they say,
the large reserves of grain in the village, so that as soon as
there was a very bad harvest the Government had to come to the
rescue and feed the starving peasantry. Worse than this, it
compromised the future prosperity of the country. Being in
pecuniary difficulties, and consequently impatient to make money,
the proprietors increased inordinately the area of grain-producing
land at the expense of pasturage and forests, with the result that
the live stock and the manuring of the land were diminished, the
fertility of the soil impaired, and the necessary quantity of
moisture in the atmosphere greatly lessened. There is some truth
in this contention; but it would seem that the soil and climate
have not been affected so much as the pessimists suppose, because
in recent years there have been some very good harvests.
On the whole, then, I think it may be justly said that the efforts
of the landed proprietors to work their estates without serf labour
have not as yet been brilliantly successful. Those who have failed
are in the habit of complaining that they have not received
sufficient support from the Government, which is accused of having
systematically sacrificed the interests of agriculture, the
mainstay of the national resources, to the creation of artificial
and unnecessary manufacturing industries. How far such complaints
and accusations are well founded I shall not attempt to decide. It
is a complicated polemical question, into which the reader would
probably decline to accompany me. Let us examine rather what
influence the above-mentioned changes have had on the peasantry.
CHAPTER XXXI
THE EMANCIPATED PEASANTRY
The Effects of Liberty--Difficulty of Obtaining Accurate
Information--Pessimist Testimony of the Proprietors--Vague Replies
of the Peasants--My Conclusions in 1877--Necessity of Revising
Them--My Investigations Renewed in 1903--Recent Researches by
Native Political Economists--Peasant Impoverishment Universally
Recognised--Various Explanations Suggested--Demoralisation of the
Common People--Peasant Self-government--Communal System of Land
Tenure--Heavy Taxation--Disruption of Peasant Families--Natural
Increase of Population--Remedies Proposed--Migration--Reclamation
of Waste Land--Land-purchase by Peasantry--Manufacturing Industry--
Improvement of Agricultural Methods--Indications of Progress.
At the commencement of last chapter I pointed out in general terms
the difficulty of describing clearly the immediate consequences of
the Emancipation. In beginning now to speak of the influence which
the great reform has had on the peasantry, I feel that the
difficulty has reached its climax. The foreigner who desires
merely to gain a general idea of the subject cannot be expected to
take an interest in details, and even if he took the trouble to
examine them attentively, he would derive from the labour little
real information. What he wishes is a clear, concise, and dogmatic
statement of general results. Has the material and moral condition
of the peasantry improved since the Emancipation? That is the
simple question which he has to put, and he naturally expects a
simple, categorical answer.
In beginning my researches in this interesting field of inquiry, I
had no adequate conception of the difficulties awaiting me. I
imagined that I had merely to question intelligent, competent men
who had had abundant opportunities of observation, and to criticise
and boil down the information collected; but when I put this method
of investigation to the test of experience it proved
unsatisfactory. Very soon I came to perceive that my authorities
were very far from being impartial observers. Most of them were
evidently suffering from shattered illusions. They had expected
that the Emancipation would produce instantaneously a wonderful
improvement in the life and character of the rural population, and
that the peasant would become at once a sober, industrious, model
agriculturist.
These expectations were not realised. One year passed, five years
passed, ten years passed, and the expected transformation did not
take place. On the contrary, there appeared certain very ugly
phenomena which were not at all in the programme. The peasants
began to drink more and to work less,* and the public life which
the Communal institutions produced was by no means of a desirable
kind. The "bawlers" (gorlopany) acquired a prejudicial influence
in the Village Assemblies, and in very many Volosts the peasant
judges, elected by their fellow-villagers, acquired a bad habit of
selling their decisions for vodka. The natural consequence of all
this was that those who had indulged in exaggerated expectations
sank into a state of inordinate despondency, and imagined things to
be much worse than they really were.
* I am not at all sure that the peasants really drank more, but
such was, and still is, a very general conviction.
For different reasons, those who had not indulged in exaggerated
expectations, and had not sympathised with the Emancipation in the
form in which it was effected, were equally inclined to take a
pessimistic view of the situation. In every ugly phenomenon they
found a confirmation of their opinions. The result was precisely
what they had foretold. The peasants had used their liberty and
their privileges to their own detriment and to the detriment of
others!
The extreme "Liberals" were also inclined, for reasons of their
own, to join in the doleful chorus. They desired that the
condition of the peasantry should be further improved by
legislative enactments, and accordingly they painted the evils in
as dark colours as possible.
Thus, from various reasons, the majority of the educated classes
were unduly disposed to represent to themselves and to others the
actual condition of the peasantry in a very unfavourable light, and
I felt that from them there was no hope of obtaining the lumen
siccum which I desired. I determined, therefore, to try the method
of questioning the peasants themselves. Surely they must know
whether their condition was better or worse than it had been before
their Emancipation.
Again I was doomed to disappointment. A few months' experience
sufficed to convince me that my new method was by no means so
effectual as I had imagined. Uneducated people rarely make
generalisations which have no practical utility, and I feel sure
that very few Russian peasants ever put to themselves the question:
Am I better off now than I was in the time of serfage? When such a
question is put to them they feel taken aback. And in truth it is
no easy matter to sum up the two sides of the account and draw an
accurate balance, save in those exceptional cases in which the
proprietor flagrantly abused his authority. The present money-dues
and taxes are often more burdensome than the labour-dues in the old
times. If the serfs had a great many ill-defined obligations to
fulfil--such as the carting of the master's grain to market, the
preparing of his firewood, the supplying him with eggs, chickens,
home-made linen, and the like--they had, on the other hand, a good
many ill-defined privileges. They grazed their cattle during a
part of the year on the manor-land; they received firewood and
occasionally logs for repairing their huts; sometimes the
proprietor lent them or gave them a cow or a horse when they had
been visited by the cattle-plague or the horse-stealer; and in
times of famine they could look to their master for support. All
this has now come to an end. Their burdens and their privileges
have been swept away together, and been replaced by clearly
defined, unbending, unelastic legal relations. They have now to
pay the market-price for every stick of firewood which they burn,
for every log which they require for repairing their houses, and
for every rood of land on which to graze their cattle. Nothing is
now to be had gratis. The demand to pay is encountered at every
step. If a cow dies or a horse is stolen, the owner can no longer
go to the proprietor with the hope of receiving a present, or at
least a loan without interest, but must, if he has no ready money,
apply to the village usurer, who probably considers twenty or
thirty per cent, as a by no means exorbitant rate of interest.
Besides this, from the economic point of view village life has been
completely revolutionised. Formerly the members of a peasant
family obtained from their ordinary domestic resources nearly all
they required. Their food came from their fields, cabbage-garden,
and farmyard. Materials for clothing were supplied by their plots
of flax and their sheep, and were worked up into linen and cloth by
the female members of the household. Fuel, as I have said, and
torches wherewith to light the izba--for oil was too expensive and
petroleum was unknown--were obtained gratis. Their sheep, cattle,
and horses were bred at home, and their agricultural implements,
except in so far as a little iron was required, could be made by
themselves without any pecuniary expenditure. Money was required
only for the purchase of a few cheap domestic utensils, such as
pots, pans, knives, hatchets, wooden dishes, and spoons, and for
the payment of taxes, which were small in amount and often paid by
the proprietor. In these circumstances the quantity of money in
circulation among the peasants was infinitesimally small, the few
exchanges which took place in a village being generally effected by
barter. The taxes, and the vodka required for village festivals,
weddings, or funerals, were the only large items of expenditure for
the year, and they were generally covered by the sums brought home
by the members of the family who went to work in the towns.
Very different is the present condition of affairs. The spinning,
weaving, and other home industries have been killed by the big
factories, and the flax and wool have to be sold to raise a little
ready money for the numerous new items of expenditure. Everything
has to be bought--clothes, firewood, petroleum, improved
agricultural implements, and many other articles which are now
regarded as necessaries of life, whilst comparatively little is
earned by working in the towns, because the big families have been
broken up, and a household now consists usually of husband and
wife, who must both remain at home, and children who are not yet
bread-winners. Recalling to mind all these things and the other
drawbacks and advantages of his actual position, the old muzhik has
naturally much difficulty in striking a balance, and he may well be
quite sincere when, on being asked whether things now are on the
whole better or worse than in the time of serfage, he scratches the
back of his head and replies hesitatingly, with a mystified
expression on his wrinkled face: "How shall I say to you? They are
both better and worse!" ("Kak vam skazat'? I l tche i kh dzhe!")? ?
If, however, you press him further and ask whether he would himself
like to return to the old state of things, he is pretty sure to
answer, with a slow shake of the head and a twinkle in his eye, as
if some forgotten item in the account had suddenly recurred to him:
"Oh, no!"
What materially increases the difficulty of this general
computation is that great changes have taken place in the well-
being of the particular households. Some have greatly prospered,
while others have become impoverished. That is one of the most
characteristic consequences of the Emancipation. In the old times
the general economic stagnation and the uncontrolled authority of
the proprietor tended to keep all the households of a village on
the same level. There was little opportunity for an intelligent,
enterprising serf to become rich, and if he contrived to increase
his revenue he had probably to give a considerable share of it to
the proprietor, unless he had the good fortune to belong to a grand
seigneur like Count Sheremetief, who was proud of having rich men
among his serfs. On the other hand, the proprietor, for evident
reasons of self-interest, as well as from benevolent motives,
prevented the less intelligent and less enterprising members of the
Commune from becoming bankrupt. The Communal equality thus
artificially maintained has now disappeared, the restrictions on
individual freedom of action have been removed, the struggle for
life has become intensified, and, as always happens in such
circumstances, the strong men go up in the world while the weak
ones go to the wall. All over the country we find on the one hand
the beginnings of a village aristocracy--or perhaps we should call
it a plutocracy, for it is based on money--and on the other hand an
ever-increasing pauperism. Some peasants possess capital, with
which they buy land outside the Commune or embark in trade, while
others have to sell their live stock, and have sometimes to cede to
neighbours their share of the Communal property. This change in
rural life is so often referred to that, in order to express it a
new, barbarous word, differentsiatsia (differentiation) has been
invented.
Hoping to obtain fuller information with the aid of official
protection, I attached myself to one of the travelling sections of
an agricultural Commission appointed by the Government, and during
a whole summer I helped to collect materials in the provinces
bordering on the Volga. The inquiry resulted in a gigantic report
of nearly 2,500 folio pages, but the general conclusions were
extremely vague. The peasantry, it was said, were passing, like
the landed proprietors, through a period of transition, in which
the main features of their future normal life had not yet become
clearly defined. In some localities their condition had decidedly
improved, whereas in others it had improved little or not at all.
Then followed a long list of recommendations in favour of
Government assistance, better agronomic education, competitive
exhibitions, more varied rotation of crops, and greater zeal on the
part of the clergy in disseminating among the people moral
principles in general and love of work in particular.
Not greatly enlightened by this official activity, I returned to my
private studies, and at the end of six years I published my
impressions and conclusions in the first edition of this work.
While recognising that there was much uncertainty as to the future,
I was inclined, on the whole, to take a hopeful view of the
situation. I was unable, however, to maintain permanently that
comfortable frame of mind. After my departure from Russia in 1878,
the accounts which reached me from various parts of the country
became blacker and blacker, and were partly confirmed by short
tours which I made in 1889-1896. At last, in the summer of 1903, I
determined to return to some of my old haunts and look at things
with my own eyes. At that moment some hospitable friends invited
me to pay them a visit at their country-house in the province of
Smolensk, and I gladly accepted the invitation, because Smolensk,
when I knew it formerly, was one of the poorest provinces, and I
thought it well to begin my new studies by examining the
impoverishment, of which I had heard so much, at its maximum.
From the railway station at Viazma, where I arrived one morning at
sunrise, I had some twenty miles to drive, and as soon as I got
clear of the little town I began my observations. What I saw
around me seemed to contradict the sombre accounts I had received.
The villages through which I passed had not at all the look of
dilapidation and misery which I expected. On the contrary, the
houses were larger and better constructed than they used to be, and
each of them had a chimney! That latter fact was important because
formerly a large proportion of the peasants of this region had no
such luxury, and allowed the smoke to find its exit by the open
door. In vain I looked for a hut of the old type, and my yamstchik
assured me I should have to go a long way to find one. Then I
noticed a good many iron ploughs of the European model, and my
yamstchik informed me that their predecessor, the sokha with which
I had been so familiar, had entirely disappeared from the district.
Next I noticed that in the neighbourhood of the villages flax was
grown in large quantities. That was certainly not an indication of
poverty, because flax is a valuable product which requires to be
well manured, and plentiful manure implies a considerable quantity
of live stock. Lastly, before arriving at my destination, I
noticed clover being grown in the fields. This made me open my
eyes with astonishment, because the introduction of artificial
grasses into the traditional rotation of crops indicates the
transition to a higher and more intensive system of agriculture.
As I had never seen clover in Russia except on the estates of very
advanced proprietors, I said to my yamstchik:
"Listen, little brother! That field belongs to the landlord?"
"Not at all, Master; it is muzhik-land."
On arriving at the country-house I told my friends what I had seen,
and they explained it to me. Smolensk is no longer one of the
poorer provinces; it has become comparatively prosperous. In two
or three districts large quantities of flax are produced and give
the cultivators a big revenue; in other districts plenty of
remunerative work is supplied by the forests. Everywhere a
considerable proportion of the younger men go regularly to the
towns and bring home savings enough to pay the taxes and make a
little surplus in the domestic budget. A few days afterwards the
village secretary brought me his books, and showed me that there
were practically no arrears of taxation.
Passing on to other provinces I found similar proofs of progress
and prosperity, but at the same time not a few indications of
impoverishment; and I was rapidly relapsing into my previous state
of uncertainty as to whether any general conclusions could be
drawn, when an old friend, himself a first-rate authority with many
years of practical experience, came to my assistance.* He informed
me that a number of specialists had recently made detailed
investigations into the present economic conditions of the rural
population, and he kindly placed at my disposal, in his charming
country-house near Moscow, the voluminous researches of these
investigators. Here, during a good many weeks, I revelled in the
statistical materials collected, and to the best of my ability I
tested the conclusions drawn from them. Many of these conclusions
I had to dismiss with the Scotch verdict of "not proven," whilst
others seemed to me worthy of acceptance. Of these latter the most
important were those drawn from the arrears of taxation.
* I hope I am committing no indiscretion when I say that the old
friend in question was Prince Alexander Stcherbatof of Vasilefskoe.
The arrears in the payment of taxes may be regarded as a pretty
safe barometer for testing the condition of the rural population,
because the peasant habitually pays his rates and taxes when he has
the means of doing so; when he falls seriously and permanently into
arrears it may be assumed that he is becoming impoverished. If the
arrears fluctuate from year to year, the causes of the
impoverishment may be regarded as accidental and perhaps temporary,
but if they steadily accumulate, we must conclude that there is
something radically wrong. Bearing these facts in mind, let us
hear what the statistics say.
During the first twenty years after the Emancipation (1861-81)
things went on in their old grooves. The poor provinces remained
poor, and the fertile provinces showed no signs of distress.
During the next twenty years (1881-1901) the arrears of the whole
of European Russia rose, roughly speaking, from 27 to 144 millions
of roubles, and the increase, strange to say, took place in the
fertile provinces. In 1890, for example, out of 52 millions,
nearly 41 millions, or 78 per cent., fell to the share of the
provinces of the Black-earth Zone. In seven of these the average
arrears per male, which had been in 1882 only 90 kopeks, rose in
1893 to 600, and in 1899 to 2,200! And this accumulation had taken
place in spite of reductions of taxation to the extent of 37
million roubles in 1881-83, and successive famine grants from the
Treasury in 1891-99 to the amount of 203 millions.* On the other
hand, in the provinces with a poor soil the arrears had greatly
decreased. In Smolensk, for example, they had sunk from 202 per
cent, to 13 per cent. of the annual sum to be paid, and in nearly
all the other provinces of the west and north a similar change for
the better had taken place.
These and many other figures which I might quote show that a great
and very curious economic revolution has been gradually effected.
The Black-earth Zone, which was formerly regarded as the
inexhaustible granary of the Empire, has become impoverished,
whilst the provinces which were formerly regarded as hopelessly
poor are now in a comparatively flourishing condition. This fact
has been officially recognised. In a classification of the
provinces according to their degree of prosperity, drawn up by a
special commission of experts in 1903, those with a poor light soil
appear at the top, and those with the famous black earth are at the
bottom of the list. In the deliberations of the commission many
reasons for this extraordinary state of things are adduced. Most
of them have merely a local significance. The big fact, taken as a
whole, seems to me to show that, in consequence of certain changes
of which I shall speak presently, the peasantry of European Russia
can no longer live by the traditional modes of agriculture, even in
the most fertile districts, and require for their support some
subsidiary occupations such as are practised in the less fertile
provinces.
* In 1901 an additional famine grant of 33 1/2 million roubles had
to be made by the Government.
Another sign of impoverishment is the decrease in the quantity of
live stock. According to the very imperfect statistics available,
for every hundred inhabitants the number of horses has decreased
from 26 to 17, the number of cattle from 36 to 25, and the number
of sheep from 73 to 40. This is a serious matter, because it means
that the land is not so well manured and cultivated as formerly,
and is consequently not so productive. Several economists have
attempted to fix precisely to what extent the productivity has
decreased, but I confess I have little faith in the accuracy of
their conclusions. M. Polenof, for example, a most able and
conscientious investigator, calculates that between 1861 and 1895,
all over Russia, the amount of food produced, in relation to the
number of the population, has decreased by seven per cent. His
methods of calculation are ingenious, but the statistical data with
which he operates are so far from accurate that his conclusions on
this point have, in my opinion, little or no scientific value.
With all due deference to Russian economists, I may say
parenthetically that they are very found of juggling with
carelessly collected statistics, as if their data were mathematical
quantities.
Several of the Zemstvos have grappled with this question of peasant
impoverishment, and the data which they have collected make a very
doleful impression. In the province of Moscow, for example, a
careful investigation gave the following results: Forty per cent.
of the peasant households had no longer any horses, 15 per cent.
had given up agriculture altogether, and about 10 per cent. had no
longer any land. We must not, however, assume, as is often done,
that the peasant families who have no live stock and no longer till
the land are utterly ruined. In reality many of them are better
off than their neighbours who appear as prosperous in the official
statistics, having found profitable occupation in the home
industries, in the towns, in the factories, or on the estates of
the landed proprietors. It must be remembered that Moscow is the
centre of one of the regions in which manufacturing industry has
progressed with gigantic strides during the last half-century, and
it would be strange indeed if, in such a region, the peasantry who
supply the labour to the towns and factories remained thriving
agriculturists. That many Russians are surprised and horrified at
the actual state of things shows to what an extent the educated
classes are still under the illusion that Russia can create for
herself a manufacturing industry capable of competing with that of
Western Europe without uprooting from the soil a portion of her
rural population.
It is only in the purely agricultural regions that families
officially classed as belonging to the peasantry may be regarded as
on the brink of pauperism because they have no live stock, and even
with regard to them I should hesitate to make such an assumption,
because the muzhiks, as I have already had occasion to remark, have
strange nomadic habits unknown to the rural population of other
countries. It is a mistake, therefore, to calculate the Russian
peasant's budget exclusively on the basis of local resources.
To the pessimists who assure me that according to their
calculations the peasantry in general must be on the brink of
starvation, I reply that there are many facts, even in the
statistical tables on which they rely, which run counter to their
deductions. Let me quote one by way of illustration. The total
amount of deposits in savings banks, about one-fourth of which is
believed to belong to the rural population, rose in the course of
six years (1894-1900) from 347 to 680 millions of roubles. Besides
the savings banks, there existed in the rural districts on 1st
December, 1902, no less than 1,614 small-credit institutions, with
a total capital (1st January, 1901) of 69 million roubles, of which
only 4,653,000 had been advanced by the State Bank and the Zemstvo,
the remainder coming in from private sources. This is not much for
a big country like Russia, but it is a beginning, and it suggests
that the impoverishment is not so severe and so universal as the
pessimists would have us believe.
There is thus room for differences of opinion as to how far the
peasantry have become impoverished, but there is no doubt that
their condition is far from satisfactory, and we have to face the
important problem why the abolition of serfage has not produced the
beneficent consequences which even moderate men so confidently
predicted, and how the present unsatisfactory state of things is to
be remedied.
The most common explanation among those who have never seriously
studied the subject is that it all comes from the demoralisation of
the common people. In this view there is a modicum of truth. That
the peasantry injure their material welfare by drunkenness and
improvidence there can be no reasonable doubt, as is shown by the
comparatively flourishing state of certain villages of Old
Ritualists and Molokanye in which there is no drunkenness, and in
which the community exercises a strong moral control over the
individual members. If the Orthodox Church could make the
peasantry refrain from the inordinate use of strong drink as
effectually as it makes them refrain during a great part of the
year from animal food, and if it could instil into their minds a
few simple moral principles as successfully as it has inspired them
with a belief in the efficacy of the Sacraments, it would certainly
confer on them an inestimable benefit. But this is not to be
expected. The great majority of the parish priests are quite unfit
for such a task, and the few who have aspirations in that direction
rarely acquire a perceptible moral influence over their
parishioners. Perhaps more is to be expected from the schoolmaster
than from the priest, but it will be long before the schools can
produce even a partial moral regeneration. Their first influence,
strange as the assertion may seem, is often in a diametrically
opposite direction. When only a few peasants in a village can read
and write they have such facilities for overreaching their "dark"
neighbours that they are apt to employ their knowledge for
dishonest purposes; and thus it occasionally happens that the man
who has the most education is the greatest scoundrel in the Mir.
Such facts are often used by the opponents of popular education,
but in reality they supply a good reason for disseminating primary
education as rapidly as possible. When all the peasants have
learned to read and write they will present a less inviting field
for swindling, and the temptations to dishonesty will be
proportionately diminished. Meanwhile, it is only fair to state
that the common assertions about drunkenness being greatly on the
increase are not borne out by the official statistics concerning
the consumption of spirituous liquors.
After drunkenness, the besetting sin which is supposed to explain
the impoverishment of the peasantry is incorrigible laziness. On
that subject I feel inclined to put in a plea of extenuating
circumstances in favour of the muzhik. Certainly he is very slow
in his movements--slower perhaps than the English rustic--and he
has a marvellous capacity for wasting valuable time without any
perceptible qualms of conscience; but he is in this respect, if I
may use a favourite phrase of the Social Scientists, "the product
of environment." To the proprietors who habitually reproach him
with time-wasting he might reply with a very strong tu quoque
argument, and to all the other classes the argument might likewise
be addressed. The St. Petersburg official, for example, who writes
edifying disquisitions about peasant indolence, considers that for
himself attendance at his office for four hours, a large portion of
which is devoted to the unproductive labour of cigarette smoking,
constitutes a very fair day's work. The truth is that in Russia
the struggle for life is not nearly so intense as in more densely
populated countries, and society is so constituted that all can
live without very strenuous exertion. The Russians seem,
therefore, to the traveller who comes from the West an indolent,
apathetic race. If the traveller happens to come from the East--
especially if he has been living among pastoral races--the Russians
will appear to him energetic and laborious. Their character in
this respect corresponds to their geographical position: they stand
midway between the laborious, painstaking, industrious population
of Western Europe and the indolent, undisciplined, spasmodically
energetic populations of Central Asia. They are capable of
effecting much by vigorous, intermittent effort--witness the
peasant at harvest-time, or the St. Petersburg official when some
big legislative project has to be submitted to the Emperor within a
given time--but they have not yet learned regular laborious habits.
In short, the Russians might move the world if it could be done by
a jerk, but they are still deficient in that calm perseverance and
dogged tenacity which characterise the Teutonic race.
Without seeking further to determine how far the moral defects of
the peasantry have a deleterious influence on their material
welfare, I proceed to examine the external causes which are
generally supposed to contribute largely to their impoverishment,
and will deal first with the evils of peasant self-government.
That the peasant self-government is very far from being in a
satisfactory condition must be admitted by any impartial observer.
The more laborious and well-to-do peasants, unless they wish to
abuse their position directly or indirectly for their own
advantage, try to escape election as office-bearers, and leave the
administration in the hands of the less respectable members. Not
unfrequently a Volost Elder trades with the money he collects as
dues or taxes; and sometimes, when he becomes insolvent, the
peasants have to pay their taxes and dues a second time. The
Village Assemblies, too, have become worse than they were in the
days of serfage. At that time the Heads of Households--who, it
must be remembered, have alone a voice in the decisions--were few
in number, laborious, and well-to-do, and they kept the lazy,
unruly members under strict control. Now that the large families
have been broken up and almost every adult peasant is Head of a
Household, the Communal affairs are sometimes decided by a noisy
majority; and certain Communal decisions may be obtained by
"treating the Mir"--that is to say, by supplying a certain amount
of vodka. Often I have heard old peasants speak of these things,
and finish their recital by some such remark as this: "There is no
order now; the people have been spoiled; it was better in the time
of the masters."
These evils are very real, and I have no desire to extenuate them,
but I believe they are by no means so great as is commonly
supposed. If the lazy, worthless members of the Commune had really
the direction of Communal affairs we should find that in the
Northern Agricultural Zone, where it is necessary to manure the
soil, the periodical redistributions of the Communal land would be
very frequent; for in a new distribution the lazy peasant has a
good chance of getting a well-manured lot in exchange for the lot
which he has exhausted. In reality, so far as my observations
extend, these general distributions of the land are not more
frequent than they were before.
Of the various functions of the peasant self-government the
judicial are perhaps the most frequently and the most severely
criticised. And certainly not without reason, for the Volost
Courts are too often accessible to the influence of alcohol, and in
some districts the peasants say that he who becomes a judge takes a
sin on his soul. I am not at all sure, however, that it would be
well to abolish these courts altogether, as some people propose.
In many respects they are better suited to peasant requirements
than the ordinary tribunals. Their procedure is infinitely
simpler, more expeditious, and incomparably less expensive, and
they are guided by traditional custom and plain common-sense,
whereas the ordinary tribunals have to judge according to the civil
law, which is unknown to the peasantry and not always applicable to
their affairs.
Few ordinary judges have a sufficiently intimate knowledge of the
minute details of peasant life to be able to decide fairly the
cases that are brought before the Volost Courts; and even if a
Justice had sufficient knowledge he could not adopt the moral and
juridical notions of the peasantry. These are often very different
from those of the upper classes. In cases of matrimonial
separation, for instance, the educated man naturally assumes that,
if there is any question of aliment, it should be paid by the
husband to the wife. The peasant, on the contrary, assumes as
naturally that it should be paid by the wife to the husband--or
rather to the Head of the Household--as a compensation for the loss
of labour which her desertion involves. In like manner, according
to traditional peasant-law, if an unmarried son is working away
from home, his earnings do not belong to himself, but to the
family, and in Volost Court they could be claimed by the Head of
the Household.
Occasionally, it is true, the peasant judges allow their respect
for old traditional conceptions in general and for the authority of
parents in particular, to carry them a little too far. I was told
lately of one affair which took place not long ago, within a
hundred miles of Moscow, in which the judge decided that a
respectable young peasant should be flogged because he refused to
give his father the money he earned as groom in the service of a
neighbouring proprietor, though it was notorious in the district
that the father was a disreputable old drunkard who carried to the
kabak (gin-shop) all the money he could obtain by fair means and
foul. When I remarked to my informant, who was not an admirer of
peasant institutions, that the incident reminded me of the respect
for the patria potestas in old Roman times, he stared at me with a
look of surprise and indignation, and exclaimed laconically,
"Patria potestas? . . . Vodka!" He was evidently convinced that
the disreputable father had got his respectable son flogged by
"treating" the judges. In such cases flogging can no longer be
used, for the Volost Courts, as we have seen, were recently
deprived of the right to inflict corporal punishment.
These administrative and judicial abuses gradually reached the ears
of the Government, and in 1889 it attempted to remove them by
creating a body of Rural Supervisors (Zemskiye Natchalniki). Under
their supervision and control some abuses may have been
occasionally prevented or corrected, and some rascally Volost
secretaries may have been punished or dismissed, but the peasant
self-government as a whole has not been perceptibly improved.
Let us glance now at the opinions of those who hold that the
material progress of the peasantry is prevented chiefly, not by the
mere abuses of the Communal administration, but by the essential
principles of the Communal institutions, and especially by the
practice of periodically redistributing the Communal land. From
the theoretical point of view this question is one of great
interest, and it may acquire in the future an immense practical
significance; but for the present it has not, in my opinion, the
importance which is usually attributed to it. There can be no
doubt that it is much more difficult to farm well on a large number
of narrow strips of land, many of which are at a great distance
from the farmyard, than on a compact piece of land which the farmer
may divide and cultivate as he pleases; and there can be as little
doubt that the husbandman is more likely to improve his land if his
tenure is secure. All this and much more of the same kind must be
accepted as indisputable truth, but it has little direct bearing on
the practical question under consideration. We are not considering
in the abstract whether it would be better that the peasant should
be a farmer with abundant capital and all the modern scientific
appliances, but simply the practical question, What are the
obstructions which at present prevent the peasant from ameliorating
his actual condition?
That the Commune prevents its members from adopting various systems
of high farming is a supposition which scarcely requires serious
consideration. The peasants do not yet think of any such radical
innovations; and if they did, they have neither the knowledge nor
the capital necessary to effect them. In many villages a few of
the richer and more intelligent peasants have bought land outside
of the Commune and cultivate it as they please, free from all
Communal restraints; and I have always found that they cultivate
this property precisely in the same way as their share of the
Communal land. As to minor changes, we know by experience that the
Mir opposes to them no serious obstacles.
The cultivation of beet for the production of sugar has greatly
increased in the central and southwestern provinces, and flax is
now largely produced in Communes in northern districts where it was
formerly cultivated merely for domestic use. The Communal system
is, in fact, extremely elastic, and may be modified as soon as the
majority of the members consider modifications profitable. When
the peasants begin to think of permanent improvements, such as
drainage, irrigation, and the like, they will find the Communal
institutions a help rather than an obstruction; for such
improvements, if undertaken at all, must be undertaken on a larger
scale, and the Mir is an already existing association. The only
permanent improvements which can be for the present profitably
undertaken consist in the reclaiming of waste land; and such
improvements are already sometimes attempted. I know at least of
one case in which a Commune in the province of Yaroslavl has
reclaimed a considerable tract of waste land by means of hired
labourers. Nor does the Mir prevent in this respect individual
initiative. In many Communes of the northern provinces it is a
received principle of customary law that if any member reclaims
waste land he is allowed to retain possession of it for a number of
years proportionate to the amount of labour expended.
But does not the Commune, as it exists, prevent good cultivation
according to the mode of agriculture actually in use?
Except in the far north and the steppe region, where the
agriculture is of a peculiar kind, adapted to the local conditions,
the peasants invariably till their land according to the ordinary
three-field system, in which good cultivation means, practically
speaking, the plentiful use of manure. Does, then, the existence
of the Mir prevent the peasants from manuring their fields well?
Many people who speak on this subject in an authoritative tone seem
to imagine that the peasants in general do not manure their fields
at all. This idea is an utter mistake. In those regions, it is
true, where the rich black soil still retains a large part of its
virgin fertility, the manure is used as fuel, or simply thrown
away, because the peasants believe that it would not be profitable
to put it on their fields, and their conviction is, at least to
some extent, well founded;* but in the Northern Agricultural Zone,
where unmanured soil gives almost no harvest, the peasants put upon
their fields all the manure they possess. If they do not put
enough it is simply because they have not sufficient live stock.
* As recently as two years ago (1903) I found that one of the most
intelligent and energetic landlords of the province of Voronezh
followed in this respect the example of the peasants, and he
assured me that he had proved by experience the advantage of doing
so.
It is only in the southern provinces, where no manure is required,
that periodical re-distributions take place frequently. As we
travel northward we find the term lengthens; and in the Northern
Agricultural Zone, where manure is indispensable, general re-
distributions are extremely rare. In the province of Yaroslavl,
for example, the Communal land is generally divided into two parts:
the manured land lying near the village, and the unmanured land
lying beyond. The latter alone is subject to frequent re-
distribution. On the former the existing tenures are rarely
disturbed, and when it becomes necessary to give a share to a new
household, the change is effected with the least possible prejudice
to vested rights.
The policy of the Government has always been to admit
redistributions in principle, but to prevent their too frequent
recurrence. For this purpose the Emancipation Law stipulated that
they could be decreed only by a three-fourths majority of the
Village Assembly, and in 1893 a further obstacle was created by a
law providing that the minimum term between two re-distributions
should be twelve years, and that they should never be undertaken
without the sanction of the Rural Supervisor.
A certain number of Communes have made the experiment of
transforming the Communal tenure into hereditary allotments, and
its only visible effect has been that the allotments accumulate in
the hands of the richer and more enterprising peasants, and the
poorer members of the Commune become landless, while the primitive
system of agriculture remains unimproved.
Up to this point I have dealt with the so-called causes of peasant
impoverishment which are much talked of, but which are, in my
opinion, only of secondary importance. I pass now to those which
are more tangible and which have exerted on the condition of the
peasantry a more palpable influence. And, first, inordinate
taxation.
This is a very big subject, on which a bulky volume might be
written, but I shall cut it very short, because I know that the
ordinary reader does not like to be bothered with voluminous
financial statistics. Briefly, then, the peasant has to pay three
kinds of direct taxation: Imperial to the Central Government, local
to the Zemstvo, and Commune to the Mir and the Volost; and besides
these he has to pay a yearly sum for the redemption of the land-
allotment which he received at the time of the Emancipation. Taken
together, these form a heavy burden, but for ten or twelve years
the emancipated peasantry bore it patiently, without falling very
deeply into arrears. Then began to appear symptoms of distress,
especially in the provinces with a poor soil, and in 1872 the
Government appointed a Commission of Inquiry, in which I had the
privilege of taking part unofficially. The inquiry showed that
something ought to be done, but at that moment the Government was
so busy with administrative reforms and with trying to develop
industry and commerce that it had little time to devote to studying
and improving the economic position of the silent, long-suffering
muzhik. It was not till nearly ten years later, when the
Government began to feel the pinch of the ever-increasing arrears,
that it recognised the necessity of relieving the rural population.
For this purpose it abolished the salt-tax and the poll-tax and
repeatedly lessened the burden of the redemption-payments. At a
later period (1899) it afforded further relief by an important
reform in the mode of collecting the direct taxes. From the
police, who often ruined peasant householders by applying distraint
indiscriminately, the collection of taxes was transferred to
special authorities who took into consideration the temporary
pecuniary embarrassments of the tax-payers. Another benefit
conferred on the peasantry by this reform is that an individual
member of the Commune is no longer responsible for the fiscal
obligations of the Commune as a whole.
Since these alleviations have been granted the annual total
demanded from the peasantry for direct taxation and land-redemption
payments is 173 million roubles, and the average annual sum to be
paid by each peasant household varies, according to the locality,
from 11 1/2 to 20 roubles (21s. 6d. to 40s.). In addition to this
annuity there is a heavy burden of accumulated arrears, especially
in the central and eastern provinces, which amounted in 1899 to 143
millions. Of the indirect taxes I can say nothing definite,
because it is impossible to calculate, even approximately, the
share of them which falls on the rural population, but they must
not be left out of account. During the ten years of M. Witte's
term of office the revenue of the Imperial Treasury was nearly
doubled, and though the increase was due partly to improvements in
the financial administration, we can hardly believe that the
peasantry did not in some measure contribute to it. In any case,
it is very difficult, if not impossible, for them, under actual
conditions, to improve their economic position. On that point all
Russian economists are agreed. One of the most competent and
sober-minded of them, M. Schwanebach, calculates that the head of a
peasant household, after deducting the grain required to feed his
family, has to pay into the Imperial Treasury, according to the
district in which he resides, from 25 to 100 per cent, of his
agricultural revenue. If that ingenious calculation is even
approximately correct, we must conclude that further financial
reforms are urgently required, especially in those provinces where
the population live exclusively by agriculture.
Heavy as the burden of taxation undoubtedly is, it might perhaps be
borne without very serious inconvenience if the peasant families
could utilise productively all their time and strength.
Unfortunately in the existing economic organisation a great deal of
their time and energy is necessarily wasted. Their economic life
was radically dislocated by the Emancipation, and they have not yet
succeeded in reorganising it according to the new conditions.
In the time of serfage an estate formed, from the economic point of
view, a co-operative agricultural association, under a manager who
possessed unlimited authority, and sometimes abused it, but who was
generally worldly-wise enough to understand that the prosperity of
the whole required the prosperity of the component parts. By the
abolition of serfage the association was dissolved and liquidated,
and the strong, compact whole fell into a heap of independent
units, with separate and often mutually hostile interests. Some of
the disadvantages of this change for the peasantry I have already
enumerated above. The most important I have now to mention. In
virtue of the Emancipation Law each family received an amount of
land which tempted it to continue farming on its own account, but
which did not enable it to earn a living and pay its rates and
taxes. The peasant thus became a kind of amphibious creature--half
farmer and half something else--cultivating his allotment for a
portion of his daily bread, and obliged to have some other
occupation wherewith to cover the inevitable deficit in his
domestic budget. If he was fortunate enough to find near his home
a bit of land to be let at a reasonable rent, he might cultivate it
in addition to his own and thereby gain a livelihood; but if he had
not the good luck to find such a piece of land in the immediate
neighbourhood, he had to look for some subsidiary occupation in
which to employ his leisure time; and where was such occupation to
be found in an ordinary Russian village? In former years he might
have employed himself perhaps in carting the proprietor's grain to
distant markets or still more distant seaports, but that means of
making a little money has been destroyed by the extension of
railways. Practically, then, he is now obliged to choose between
two alternatives: either to farm his allotment and spend a great
part of the year in idleness, or to leave the cultivation of his
allotment to his wife and children and to seek employment
elsewhere--often at such a distance that his earnings hardly cover
the expenses of the journey. In either case much time and energy
are wasted.
The evil results of this state of things were intensified by
another change which was brought about by the Emancipation. In the
time of serfage the peasant families, as I have already remarked,
were usually very large. They remained undivided, partly from the
influence of patriarchal conceptions, but chiefly because the
proprietors, recognising the advantage of large units, prevented
them from breaking up. As soon as the proprietor's authority was
removed, the process of disintegration began and spread rapidly.
Every one wished to be independent, and in a very short time nearly
every able-bodied married peasant had a house of his own. The
economic consequences were disastrous. A large amount of money had
to be expended in constructing new houses and farmsteadings; and
the old habit of one male member remaining at home to cultivate the
land allotment with the female members of the family whilst the
others went to earn wages elsewhere had to be abandoned. Many
large families, which had been prosperous and comfortable--rich
according to peasant conceptions--dissolved into three or four
small ones, all on the brink of pauperism.
The last cause of peasant impoverishment that I have to mention is
perhaps the most important of all: I mean the natural increase of
population without a corresponding increase in the means of
subsistence. Since the Emancipation in 1861 the population has
nearly doubled, whilst the amount of Communal land has remained the
same. It is not surprising, therefore, that when talking with
peasants about their actual condition, one constantly hears the
despairing cry, "Zemli malo!" ("There is not enough land"); and one
notices that those who look a little ahead ask anxiously: "What is
to become of our children? Already the Communal allotment is too
small for our wants, and the land outside is doubling and trebling
in price! What will it be in the future?" At the same time, not a
few Russian economists tell us--and their apprehensions are shared
by foreign observers--that millions of peasants are in danger of
starvation in the near future.
Must we, then, accept for Russia the Malthus doctrine that
population increases more rapidly than the means of subsistence,
and that starvation can be avoided only by plague, pestilence, war,
and other destructive forces? I think not. It is quite true that,
if the amount of land actually possessed by the peasantry and the
present system of cultivating it remained unchanged, semi-
starvation would be the inevitable result within a comparatively
short space of time; but the danger can be averted, and the proper
remedies are not far to seek. If Russia is suffering from over-
population, it must be her own fault, for she is, with the
exception of Norway and Sweden, the most thinly populated country
in Europe, and she has more than her share of fertile soil and
mineral resources.
A glance at the map showing the density of population in the
various provinces suggests an obvious remedy, and I am happy to say
it is already being applied. The population of the congested
districts of the centre is gradually spreading out, like a drop of
oil on a sheet of soft paper, towards the more thinly populated
regions of the south and east. In this way the vast region
containing millions and millions of acres which lies to the north
of the Black Sea, the Caucasus, the Caspian, and Central Asia is
yearly becoming more densely peopled, and agriculture is steadily
encroaching on the pastoral area. Breeders of sheep and cattle,
who formerly lived and throve in the western portion of that great
expanse, are being pushed eastwards by the rapid increase in the
value of land, and their place is being taken by enterprising
tillers of the soil. Further north another stream of emigration is
flowing into Central Siberia. It does not flow so rapidly, because
in that part of the Empire, unlike the bare, fertile steppes of the
south, the land has to be cleared before the seed can be sown, and
the pioneer colonists have to work hard for a year or two before
they get any return for their labour; but the Government and
private societies come to their assistance, and for the last twenty
years their numbers have been steadily increasing. During the ten
years 1886-96 the annual contingent rose from 25,000 to 200,000,
and the total number amounted to nearly 800,000. For the
subsequent period I have not been able to obtain the official
statistics, but a friend who has access to the official sources of
information on this subject assures me that during the last twelve
years about four millions of peasants from European Russia have
been successfully settled in Siberia.
Even in the European portion of the Empire millions of acres which
are at present unproductive might be utilised. Any one who has
travelled by rail from Berlin to St. Petersburg must have noticed
how the landscape suddenly changes its character as soon as he has
crossed the frontier. Leaving a prosperous agricultural country,
he traverses for many weary hours a region in which there is hardly
a sign of human habitation, though the soil and climate of that
region resembles closely the soil and climate of East Prussia. The
difference lies in the amount of labour and capital expended.
According to official statistics the area of European Russia
contains, roughly speaking, 406 millions of dessyatins, of which 78
millions, or 19 per cent., are classified as neudobniya, unfit for
cultivation; 157 millions, or 39 per cent., as forest; 106
millions, or 26 per cent., as arable land; and 65 millions, or 16
per cent., as pasturage. Thus the arable and pasture land compose
only 42 per cent., or considerably less than half the area.
Of the land classed as unfit for cultivation--19 per cent. of the
whole--a large portion, including the perennially frozen tundri of
the far north, must ever remain unproductive, but in latitudes with
a milder climate this category of land is for the most part
ordinary morass or swamp, which can be transformed into pasturage,
or even into arable land, by drainage at a moderate cost. As a
proof of this statement I may cite the draining of the great Pinsk
swamps, which was begun by the Government in 1872. If we may trust
an official report of the progress of the works in 1897, an area of
2,855,000 dessyatins (more than seven and a half million acres) had
been drained at an average cost of about three shillings an acre,
and the price of land had risen from four to twenty-eight roubles
per dessyatin.
Reclamation of marshes might be undertaken elsewhere on a much more
moderate scale. The observant traveller on the highways and byways
of the northern provinces must have noticed on the banks of almost
every stream many acres of marshy land producing merely reeds or
coarse rank grass that no well-brought-up animal would look at.
With a little elementary knowledge of engineering and the
expenditure of a moderate amount of manual labour these marshes
might be converted into excellent pasture or even into highly
productive kitchen-gardens; but the peasants have not yet learned
to take advantage of such opportunities, and the reformers, who
deal only in large projects and scientific panaceas for the cure of
impoverishment, consider such trifles as unworthy of their
attention. The Scotch proverb that if the pennies be well looked
after, the pounds will look after themselves, contains a bit of
homely wisdom totally unknown to the Russian educated classes.
After the morasses, swamps, and marshes come the forests,
constituting 39 per cent. of the whole area, and the question
naturally arises whether some portions of them might not be
advantageously transformed into pasturage or arable land. In the
south and east they have been diminished to such an extent as to
affect the climate injuriously, so that the area of them should be
increased rather than lessened; but in the northern provinces the
vast expanses of forest, covering millions of acres, might perhaps
be curtailed with advantage. The proprietors prefer, however, to
keep them in their present condition because they give a modest
revenue without any expenditure of capital.
Therein lies the great obstacle to land-reclamation in Russia: it
requires an outlay of capital, and capital is extremely scarce in
the Empire of the Tsars. Until it becomes more plentiful, the area
of arable land and pasturage is not likely to be largely increased,
and other means of checking the impoverishment of the peasantry
must be adopted.
A less expensive means is suggested by the statistics of foreign
trade. In the preceding chapter we have seen that from 1860 to
1900 the average annual export of grain rose steadily from under 1
1/2 millions to over 6 millions of tons. It is evident, therefore,
that in the food supply, so far from there being a deficiency,
there has been a large and constantly increasing surplus. If the
peasantry have been on short rations, it is not because the
quantity of food produced has fallen short of the requirements of
the population, but because it has been unequally distributed. The
truth is that the large landed proprietors produce more and the
peasants less than they consume, and it has naturally occurred to
many people that the present state of things might be improved if a
portion of the arable land passed, without any socialistic,
revolutionary measures, from the one class to the other. This
operation began spontaneously soon after the Emancipation. Well-
to-do peasants who had saved a little money bought from the
proprietors bits of land near their villages and cultivated them in
addition to their allotments. At first this extension of peasant
land was confined within very narrow limits, because the peasants
had very little capital at their disposal, but in 1882 the
Government came to their aid by creating the Peasant Land Bank, the
object of which was to advance money to purchasers of the peasant
class on the security of the land purchased, at the rate of 7 1/2
per cent., including sinking fund.* From that moment the purchases
increased rapidly. They were made by individual peasants, by rural
Communes, and, most of all, by small voluntary associations
composed of three, four, or more members. In the course of twenty
years (1883-1903) the Bank made 47,791 advances, and in this way
were purchased about eighteen million acres. This sounds a very
big acquisition, but it will not do much to relieve the pressure on
the peasantry as a whole, because it adds only about 6 per cent. to
the amount they already possessed in virtue of the Emancipation
Law.
* This arrangement extinguishes the debt in 34 1/2 years; an
additional 1 per cent, extinguishes it in 24 1/2 years. By recent
legislation other arrangements are permitted.
Nearly all of this land purchased by the peasantry comes directly
or indirectly from the Noblesse, and much more will doubtless pass
from the one class to the other if the Government continues to
encourage the operation; but already symptoms of a change of policy
are apparent. In the higher official regions it is whispered that
the existing policy is objectionable from the political point of
view, and one sometimes hears the question asked: Is it right and
desirable that the Noblesse, who have ever done their duty in
serving faithfully the Tsar and Fatherland, and who have ever been
the representatives of civilisation and culture in Russian country
life, should be gradually expropriated in favour of other and less
cultivated social classes? Not a few influential personages are of
opinion that such a change is unjust and undesirable, and they
argue that it is not advantageous to the peasants themselves,
because the price of land has risen much more than the rents. It
is not at all uncommon, for example, to find that land can be
rented at five roubles per dessyatin, whereas it cannot be bought
under 200 roubles. In that case the peasant can enjoy the use of
the land at the moderate rate of 2 1/2 per cent. of the capital
value, whereas by purchasing the land with the assistance of the
bank he would have to pay, without sinking fund, more than double
that rate. The muzhik, however, prefers to be owner of the land,
even at a considerable sacrifice. When he can be induced to give
his reasons, they are usually formulated thus: "With my own land I
can do as I like; if I hire land from the neighbouring proprietor,
who knows whether, at the end of the term, he may not raise the
rent or refuse to renew the contract at any price?"
Even if the Government should continue to encourage the purchase of
land by the peasantry, the process is too slow to meet all the
requirements of the situation. Some additional expedient must be
found, and we naturally look for it in the experience of older
countries with a denser population.
In the more densely populated countries of Western Europe a safety-
valve for the inordinate increase of the rural population has been
provided by the development of manufacturing industry. High wages
and the attractions of town life draw the rural population to the
industrial centres, and the movement has increased to such an
extent that already complaints are heard of the rural districts
becoming depopulated. In Russia a similar movement is taking place
on a smaller scale. During the last forty years, under the
fostering influence of a protective tariff, the manufacturing
industry has made gigantic strides, as we shall see in a future
chapter, and it has already absorbed about two millions of the
redundant hands in the villages; but it cannot keep pace with the
rapid increasing surplus. Two millions are less than two per cent.
of the population. The great mass of the people has always been,
and must long continue to be, purely agricultural; and it is to
their fields that they must look for the means of subsistence. If
the fields do not supply enough for their support under the
existing primitive methods of cultivation, better methods must be
adopted. To use a favourite semi-scientific phrase, Russia has now
reached the point in her economic development at which she must
abandon her traditional extensive system of agriculture and adopt a
more intensive system. So far all competent authorities are
agreed. But how is the transition, which requires technical
knowledge, a spirit of enterprise, an enormous capital, and a dozen
other things which the peasantry do not at present possess, to be
effected? Here begin the well-marked differences of opinion.
Hitherto the momentous problem has been dealt with chiefly by the
theorists and doctrinaires who delight in radical solutions by
means of panaceas, and who have little taste for detailed local
investigation and gradual improvement. I do not refer to the so-
called "Saviours of the Fatherland" (Spasiteli Otetchestva), well-
meaning cranks and visionaries who discover ingenious devices for
making their native country at once prosperous and happy. I speak
of the great majority of reasonable, educated men who devote some
attention to the problem. Their favourite method of dealing with
it is this: The intensive system of agriculture requires scientific
knowledge and a higher level of intellectual culture. What has to
be done, therefore, is to create agricultural colleges supplied
with all the newest appliances of agronomic research and to educate
the peasantry to such an extent that they may be able to use the
means which science recommends.
For many years this doctrine prevailed in the Press, among the
reading public, and even in the official world. The Government was
accordingly urged to improve and multiply the agronomic colleges
and the schools of all grades and descriptions. Learned
dissertations were published on the chemical constitution of the
various soils, the action of the atmosphere on the different
ingredients, the necessity of making careful meteorological
observations, and numerous other topics of a similar kind; and
would-be reformers who had no taste for such highly technical
researches could console themselves with the idea that they were
advancing the vital interests of the country by discussing the
relative merits of Communal and personal land-tenure--deciding
generally in favour of the former as more in accordance with the
peculiarities of Russian, as contrasted with West European,
principles of economic and social development.
While much valuable time and energy were thus being expended to
little purpose, on the assumption that the old system might be left
untouched until the preparations for a radical solution had been
completed, disagreeable facts which could not be entirely
overlooked gradually produced in influential quarters the
conviction that the question was much more urgent than was commonly
supposed. A sensitive chord in the heart of the Government was
struck by the steadily increasing arrears of taxation, and
spasmodic attempts have since been made to cure the evil.
In the local administration, too, the urgency of the question has
come to be recognised, and measures are now being taken by the
Zemstvo to help the peasantry in making gradually the transition to
that higher system of agriculture which is the only means of
permanently saving them from starvation. For this purpose, in many
districts well-trained specialists have been appointed to study the
local conditions and to recommend to the villagers such simple
improvements as are within their means. These improvements may be
classified under the following heads:
(1) Increase of the cereal crops by better seed and improved
implements.
(2) Change in the rotation of crops by the introduction of certain
grasses and roots which improve the soil and supply food for live
stock.
(3) Improvement and increase of live stock, so as to get more
labour-power, more manure, more dairy-produce, and more meat.
(4) Increased cultivation of vegetables and fruit.
With these objects in view the Zemstvo is establishing depots in
which improved implements and better seed are sold at moderate
prices, and the payments are made in installments, so that even the
poorer members of the community can take advantage of the
facilities offered. Bulls and stallions are kept at central points
for the purpose of improving the breed of cattle and horses, and
the good results are already visible. Elementary instruction in
farming and gardening is being introduced into the primary schools.
In some districts the exertions of the Zemstvo are supplemented by
small agricultural societies, mutual credit associations, and
village banks, and these are to some extent assisted by the Central
Government. But the beneficent action in this direction is not all
official. Many proprietors deserve great praise for the good
influence which they exercise on the peasants of their
neighbourhood and the assistance they give them; and it must be
admitted that their patience is often sorely tried, for the
peasants have the obstinacy of ignorance, and possess other
qualities which are not sympathetic. I know one excellent
proprietor who began his civilising efforts by giving to the Mir of
the nearest village an iron plough as a model and a fine pedigree
ram as a producer, and who found, on returning from a tour abroad,
that during his absence the plough had been sold for vodka, and the
pedigree ram had been eaten before it had time to produce any
descendants! In spite of this he continues his efforts, and not
altogether without success.
It need hardly be said that the progress of the peasantry is not so
rapid as could be wished. The muzhik is naturally conservative,
and is ever inclined to regard novelties with suspicion. Even when
he is half convinced of the utility of some change, he has still to
think about it for a long time and talk it over again and again
with his friends and neighbours, and this preparatory stage of
progress may last for years. Unless he happens to be a man of
unusual intelligence and energy, it is only when he sees with his
own eyes that some humble individual of his own condition in life
has actually gained by abandoning the old routine and taking to new
courses, that he makes up his mind to take the plunge himself.
Still, he is beginning to jog on. E pur si muove! A spirit of
progress is beginning to move on the face of the long-stagnant
waters, and progress once begun is pretty sure to continue with
increasing rapidity. With starvation hovering in the rear, even
the most conservative are not likely to stop or turn back.
CHAPTER XXXII
THE ZEMSTVO AND THE LOCAL SELF-GOVERNMENT
Necessity of Reorganising the Provincial Administration--Zemstvo
Created in 1864--My First Acquaintance with the Institution--
District and Provincial Assemblies--The Leading Members--Great
Expectations Created by the Institution--These Expectations Not
Realised--Suspicions and Hostility of the Bureaucracy--Zemstvo
Brought More Under Control of the Centralised Administration--What
It Has Really Done--Why It Has Not Done More---Rapid Increase of
the Rates--How Far the Expenditure Is Judicious--Why the
Impoverishment of the Peasantry Was Neglected--Unpractical,
Pedantic Spirit--Evil Consequences--Chinese and Russian Formalism--
Local Self-Government of Russia Contrasted with That of England--
Zemstvo Better than Its Predecessors--Its Future.
After the emancipation of the serfs the reform most urgently
required was the improvement of the provincial administration. In
the time of serfage the Emperor Nicholas, referring to the landed
proprietors, used to say in a jocular tone that he had in his
Empire 50,000 most zealous and efficient hereditary police-masters.
By the Emancipation Law the authority of these hereditary police-
masters was for ever abolished, and it became urgently necessary to
put something else in its place. Peasant self-government was
accordingly organised on the basis of the rural Commune; but it
fell far short of meeting the requirements of the situation. Its
largest unit was the Volost, which comprises merely a few
contiguous Communes, and its action is confined exclusively to the
peasantry. Evidently it was necessary to create a larger
administrative unit, in which the interests of all classes of the
population could be attended to, and for this purpose Alexander II.
in November, 1859, more than a year before the Emancipation Edict,
instructed a special Commission to prepare a project for giving to
the inefficient, dislocated provincial administration greater unity
and independence. The project was duly prepared, and after being
discussed in the Council of State it received the Imperial sanction
in January, 1864. It was supposed to give, in the words of an
explanatory memorandum attached to it, "as far as possible a
complete and logical development to the principle of local self-
government." Thus was created the Zemstvo,* which has recently
attracted considerable attention in Western Europe, and which is
destined, perhaps, to play a great political part in the future.
* The term Zemstvo is derived from the word Zemlya, meaning land,
and might be translated, if a barbarism were permissible, by Land-
dom on the analogy of Kingdom, Dukedom, etc.
My personal acquaintance with this interesting institution dates
from 1870. Very soon after my arrival at Novgorod in that year, I
made the acquaintance of a gentleman who was described to me as
"the president of the provincial Zemstvo-bureau," and finding him
amiable and communicative, I suggested that he might give me some
information regarding the institution of which he was the chief
local representative. With the utmost readiness he proposed to be
my Mentor, introduced me to his colleagues, and invited me to come
and see him at his office as often as I felt inclined. Of this
invitation I made abundant use. At first my visits were discreetly
few and short, but when I found that my new friend and his
colleagues really wished to instruct me in all the details of
Zemstvo administration, and had arranged a special table in the
president's room for my convenience, I became a regular attendant,
and spent daily several hours in the bureau, studying the current
affairs, and noting down the interesting bits of statistical and
other information which came before the members, as if I had been
one of their number. When they went to inspect the hospital, the
lunatic asylum, the seminary for the preparation of village
schoolmasters, or any other Zemstvo institution, they invariably
invited me to accompany them, and made no attempt to conceal from
me the defects which they happened to discover.
I mention all this because it illustrates the readiness of most
Russians to afford every possible facility to a foreigner who
wishes seriously to study their country. They believe that they
have long been misunderstood and systematically calumniated by
foreigners, and they are extremely desirous that the prevalent
misconceptions regarding their country should be removed. It must
be said to their honour that they have little or none of that false
patriotism which seeks to conceal national defects; and in judging
themselves and their institutions they are inclined to be over-
severe rather than unduly lenient. In the time of Nicholas I.
those who desired to stand well with the Government proclaimed
loudly that they lived in the happiest and best-governed country of
the world, but this shallow official optimism has long since gone
out of fashion. During all the years which I spent in Russia I
found everywhere the utmost readiness to assist me in my
investigations, and very rarely noticed that habit of "throwing
dust in the eyes of foreigners," of which some writers have spoken
so much.
The Zemstvo is a kind of local administration which supplements the
action of the rural Communes, and takes cognizance of those higher
public wants which individual Communes cannot possibly satisfy.
Its principal duties are to keep the roads and bridges in proper
repair, to provide means of conveyance for the rural police and
other officials, to look after primary education and sanitary
affairs, to watch the state of the crops and take measures against
approaching famine, and, in short, to undertake, within certain
clearly defined limits, whatever seems likely to increase the
material and moral well-being of the population. In form the
institution is Parliamentary--that is to say, it consists of an
assembly of deputies which meets regularly once a year, and of a
permanent executive bureau elected by the Assembly from among its
members. If the Assembly be regarded as a local Parliament, the
bureau corresponds to the Cabinet. In accordance with this analogy
my friend the president was sometimes jocularly termed the Prime
Minister. Once every three years the deputies are elected in
certain fixed proportions by the landed proprietors, the rural
Communes, and the municipal corporations. Every province
(guberniya) and each of the districts (uyezdi) into which the
province is subdivided has such an assembly and such a bureau.
Not long after my arrival in Novgorod I had the opportunity of
being present at a District Assembly. In the ball-room of the
"Club de la Noblesse" I found thirty or forty men seated round a
long table covered with green cloth. Before each member lay sheets
of paper for the purpose of taking notes, and before the president--
the Marshal of Noblesse for the district--stood a small hand-bell,
which he rang vigorously at the commencement of the proceedings and
on all the occasions when he wished to obtain silence. To the
right and left of the president sat the members of the executive
bureau (uprava), armed with piles of written and printed documents,
from which they read long and tedious extracts, till the majority
of the audience took to yawning and one or two of the members
positively went to sleep. At the close of each of these reports
the president rang his bell--presumably for the purpose of
awakening the sleepers--and inquired whether any one had remarks to
make on what had just been read. Generally some one had remarks to
make, and not unfrequently a discussion ensued. When any decided
difference of opinion appeared a vote was taken by handing round a
sheet of paper, or by the simpler method of requesting the Ayes to
stand up and the Noes to sit still.
What surprised me most in this assembly was that it was composed
partly of nobles and partly of peasants--the latter being decidedly
in the majority--and that no trace of antagonism seemed to exist
between the two classes. Landed proprietors and their ci-devant
serfs, emancipated only ten years before, evidently met for the
moment on a footing of equality. The discussions were carried on
chiefly by the nobles, but on more than one occasion peasant
members rose to speak, and their remarks, always clear, practical,
and to the point, were invariably listened to with respectful
attention. Instead of that violent antagonism which might have
been expected, considering the constitution of the Assembly, there
was too much unanimity--a fact indicating plainly that the majority
of the members did not take a very deep interest in the matters
presented to them.
This assembly was held in the month of September. At the beginning
of December the Assembly for the Province met, and during nearly
three weeks I was daily present at its deliberations. In general
character and mode of procedure it resembled closely the District
Assembly. Its chief peculiarities were that its members were
chosen, not by the primary electors, but by the assemblies of the
ten districts which compose the province, and that it took
cognisance merely of those matters which concerned more than one
district. Besides this, the peasant deputies were very few in
number--a fact which somewhat surprised me, because I was aware
that, according to the law, the peasant members of the District
Assemblies were eligible, like those of the other classes. The
explanation is that the District Assemblies choose their most
active members to represent them in the Provincial Assemblies, and
consequently the choice generally falls on landed proprietors. To
this arrangement the peasants make no objection, for attendance at
the Provincial Assemblies demands a considerable pecuniary outlay,
and payment to the deputies is expressly prohibited by law
To give the reader an idea of the elements composing this assembly,
let me introduce him to a few of the members. A considerable
section of them may be described in a single sentence. They are
commonplace men, who have spent part of their youth in the public
service as officers in the army, or officials in the civil
administration, and have since retired to their estates, where they
gain a modest competence by farming. Some of them add to their
agricultural revenue by acting as justices of the peace.* A few
may be described more particularly.
* That is no longer possible. The institution of justices elected
and paid by the Zemstvo was abolished in 1889.
You see there, for instance, that fine-looking old general in
uniform, with the St. George's Cross at his button-hole--an order
given only for bravery in the field. That is Prince Suvorof, a
grandson of the famous general. He has filled high posts in the
Administration without ever tarnishing his name by a dishonest or
dishonourable action, and has spent a great part of his life at
Court without ceasing to be frank, generous, and truthful. Though
he has no intimate knowledge of current affairs, and sometimes
gives way a little to drowsiness, his sympathies in disputed points
are always on the right side, and when he gets to his feet he
always speaks in a clear soldierlike fashion.
The tall gaunt man, somewhat over middle age, who sits a little to
the left is Prince Vassiltchikof. He too, has an historic name,
but he cherishes above all things personal independence, and has
consequently always kept aloof from the Imperial Administration and
the Court. The leisure thus acquired he has devoted to study, and
he has produced several valuable works on political and social
science. An enthusiastic but at the same time cool-headed
abolitionist at the time of the Emancipation, he has since
constantly striven to ameliorate the condition of the peasantry by
advocating the spread of primary education, the rural credit
associations in the village, the preservation of the Communal
institutions, and numerous important reforms in the financial
system. Both of these gentlemen, it is said, generously gave to
their peasants more land than they were obliged to give by the
Emancipation Law. In the Assembly Prince Vassiltchikof speaks
frequently, and always commands attention; and in all important
committees he is leading member. Though a warm defender of the
Zemstvo institutions, he thinks that their activity ought to be
confined to a comparatively narrow field, and he thereby differs
from some of his colleagues, who are ready to embark in hazardous,
not to say fanciful, schemes for developing the natural resources
of the province. His neighbour, Mr. P----, is one of the ablest
and most energetic members of the Assembly. He is president of the
executive bureau in one of the districts, where he has founded many
primary schools and created several rural credit associations on
the model of those which bear the name of Schultze Delitsch in
Germany. Mr. S----, who sits beside him, was for some years an
arbiter between the proprietors and emancipated serfs, then a
member of the Provincial Executive Bureau, and is now director of a
bank in St. Petersburg.
To the right and left of the president--who is Marshal of Noblesse
for the province--sit the members of the bureau. The gentleman who
reads the long reports is my friend "the Prime Minister," who began
life as a cavalry officer, and after a few years of military
service retired to his estate; he is an intelligent, able
administrator, and a man of considerable literary culture. His
colleague, who assists him in reading the reports, is a merchant,
and director of the municipal bank. The next member is also a
merchant, and in some respects the most remarkable man in the room.
Though born a serf, he is already, at middle age, an important
personage in the Russian commercial world. Rumour says that he
laid the foundation of his fortune by one day purchasing a copper
cauldron in a village through which he was passing on his way to
St. Petersburg, where he hoped to gain a little money by the sale
of some calves. In the course of a few years he amassed an
enormous fortune; but cautious people think that he is too fond of
hazardous speculations, and prophesy that he will end life as poor
as he began it.
All these men belong to what may be called the party of progress,
which anxiously supports all proposals recognised as "liberal," and
especially all measures likely to improve the condition of the
peasantry. Their chief opponent is that little man with close-
cropped, bullet-shaped head and small piercing eyes, who may be
called the Leader of the opposition. He condemns many of the
proposed schemes, on the ground that the province is already
overtaxed, and that the expenditure ought to be reduced to the
smallest possible figure. In the District Assembly he preaches
this doctrine with considerable success, for there the peasantry
form the majority, and he knows how to use that terse, homely
language, interspersed with proverbs, which has far more influence
on the rustic mind than scientific principles and logical
reasoning; but here, in Provincial Assembly, his following composes
only a respectable minority, and he confines himself to a policy of
obstruction.
The Zemstvo of Novgorod had at that time the reputation of being
one of the most enlightened and energetic, and I must say that the
proceedings were conducted in a business-like, satisfactory way.
The reports were carefully considered, and each article of the
annual budget was submitted to minute scrutiny and criticism. In
several of the provinces which I afterwards visited I found that
affairs were conducted in a very different fashion: quorums were
formed with extreme difficulty, and the proceedings, when they at
last commenced, were treated as mere formalities and despatched as
speedily as possible. The character of the Assembly depends of
course on the amount of interest taken in local public affairs. In
some districts this interest is considerable; in others it is very
near zero.
The birth of this new institution was hailed with enthusiasm, and
produced great expectations. At that time a large section of the
Russian educated classes had a simple, convenient criterion for
institutions of all kinds. They assumed as a self-evident axiom
that the excellence of an institution must always be in proportion
to its "liberal" and democratic character. The question as to how
far it might be appropriate to the existing conditions and to the
character of the people, and as to whether it might not, though
admirable in itself, be too expensive for the work to be performed,
was little thought of. Any organisation which rested on "the
elective principle," and provided an arena for free public
discussion, was sure to be well received, and these conditions were
fulfilled by the Zemstvo.
The expectations excited were of various kinds. People who thought
more of political than economic progress saw in the Zemstvo the
basis of boundless popular liberty. Prince Yassiltchikof, for
example, though naturally of a phlegmatic temperament, became for a
moment enthusiastic, and penned the following words: "With a daring
unparalleled in the chronicles of the world, we have entered on the
career of public life." If local self-government in England had,
in spite of its aristocratic character, created and preserved
political liberty, as had been proved by several learned Germans,
what might be expected from institutions so much more liberal and
democratic? In England there had never been county parliaments,
and the local administration had always been in the hands of the
great land-owners; whilst in Russia every district would have its
elective assembly, in which the peasant would be on a level with
the richest landed proprietors. People who were accustomed to
think of social rather than political progress expected that they
would soon see the country provided with good roads, safe bridges,
numerous village schools, well-appointed hospitals, and all the
other requisites of civilisation. Agriculture would become more
scientific, trade and industry would be rapidly developed, and the
material, intellectual, and moral condition of the peasantry would
be enormously improved. The listless apathy of provincial life and
the hereditary indifference to local public affairs were now, it
was thought, about to be dispelled; and in view of this change,
patriotic mothers took their children to the annual assemblies in
order to accustom them from their early years to take an interest
in the public welfare.
It is hardly necessary to say that these inordinate expectations
were not realised. From the very beginning there had been a
misunderstanding regarding the character and functions of the new
institutions. During the short period of universal enthusiasm for
reform the great officials had used incautiously some of the vague
liberal phrases then in fashion, but they never seriously intended
to confer on the child which they were bringing into the world a
share in the general government of the country; and the rapid
evaporation of their sentimental liberalism, which began as soon as
they undertook practical reforms, made them less and less
conciliatory. When the vigorous young child, therefore, showed a
natural desire to go beyond the humble functions accorded to it,
the stern parents proceeded to snub it and put it into its proper
place. The first reprimand was administered publicly in the
capital. The St. Petersburg Provincial Assembly, having shown a
desire to play a political part, was promptly closed by the
Minister of the Interior, and some of the members were exiled for a
time to their homes in the country.
This warning produced merely a momentary effect. As the functions
of the Imperial Administration and of the Zemstvo had never been
clearly defined, and as each was inclined to extend the sphere of
its activity, friction became frequent. The Zemstvo had the right,
for example, to co-operate in the development of education, but as
soon as it organised primary schools and seminaries it came into
contact with the Ministry of Public Instruction. In other
departments similar conflicts occurred, and the tchinovniks came to
suspect that the Zemstvo had the ambition to play the part of a
parliamentary Opposition. This suspicion found formal expression
in at least one secret official document, in which the writer
declares that "the Opposition has built itself firmly a nest in the
Zemstvo." Now, if we mean to be just to both parties in this
little family quarrel, we must admit that the Zemstvo, as I shall
explain in a future chapter, had ambitions of that kind, and it
would have been better perhaps for the country at the present
moment if it had been able to realise them. But this is a West-
European idea. In Russia there is, and can be, no such thing as
"His Majesty's Opposition." To the Russian official mind the three
words seem to contain a logical contradiction. Opposition to
officials, even within the limits of the law, is equivalent to
opposition to the Autocratic Power, of which they are the incarnate
emanations; and opposition to what they consider the interests of
autocracy comes within measurable distance of high treason. It was
considered necessary, therefore, to curb and suppress the ambitious
tendencies of the wayward child, and accordingly it was placed more
and more under the tutelage of the provincial Governors. To show
how the change was effected, let me give an illustration. In the
older arrangements the Governor could suspend the action of the
Zemstvo only on the ground of its being illegal or ultra vires, and
when there was an irreconcilable difference of opinion between the
two parties the question was decided judicially by the Senate;
under the more recent arrangements his Excellency can interpose his
veto whenever he considers that a decision, though it may be
perfectly legal, is not conducive to the public good, and
differences of opinion are referred, not to the Senate, but to the
Minister of the Interior, who is always naturally disposed to
support the views of his subordinate.
In order to put an end to all this insubordination, Count Tolstoy,
the reactionary Minister of the Interior, prepared a scheme of
reorganisation in accordance with his anti-liberal views, but he
died before he could carry it out, and a much milder reorganisation
was adopted in the law of 12th (24th) June, 1890. The principal
changes introduced by that law were that the number of delegates in
the Assemblies was reduced by about a fourth, and the relative
strength of the different social classes was altered. Under the
old law the Noblesse had about 42 per cent., and the peasantry
about 38 per cent, of the seats; by the new electoral arrangements
the former have 57 per cent, and the latter about 30. It does not
necessarily follow, however, that the Assemblies are more
conservative or more subservient on that account. Liberalism and
insubordination are much more likely to be found among the nobles
than among the peasants.
In addition to all this, as there was an apprehension in the higher
official spheres of St. Petersburg that the opposition spirit of
the Zemstvo might find public expression in a printed form, the
provincial Governors received extensive rights of preventive
censure with regard to the publication of the minutes of Zemstvo
Assemblies and similar documents.
What the bureaucracy, in its zeal to defend the integrity of the
Autocratic Power, feared most of all was combination for a common
purpose on the part of the Zemstvos of different provinces. It
vetoed, therefore, all such combinations, even for statistical
purposes; and when it discovered, a few years ago, that leading
members of the Zemstvo from all parts of the country were holding
private meetings in Moscow for the ostensible purpose of discussing
economic questions, it ordered them to return to their homes.
Even within its proper sphere, as defined by law, the Zemstvo has
not accomplished what was expected of it. The country has not been
covered with a network of macadamised roads, and the bridges are by
no means as safe as could be desired. Village schools and
infirmaries are still far below the requirements of the population.
Little or nothing has been done for the development of trade or
manufactures; and the villages remain very much what they were
under the old Administration. Meanwhile the local rates have been
rising with alarming rapidity; and many people draw from all this
the conclusion that the Zemstvo is a worthless institution which
has increased the taxation without conferring any corresponding
benefit on the country.
If we take as our criterion in judging the institution the
exaggerated expectations at first entertained, we may feel inclined
to agree with this conclusion, but this is merely tantamount to
saying that the Zemstvo has performed no miracles. Russia is much
poorer and much less densely populated than the more advanced
nations which she takes as her model. To suppose that she could at
once create for herself by means of an administrative reform all
the conveniences which those more advanced nations enjoy, was as
absurd as it would be to imagine that a poor man can at once
construct a magnificent palace because he has received from a
wealthy neighbour the necessary architectural plans. Not only
years but generations must pass before Russia can assume the
appearance of Germany, France, or England. The metamorphosis may
be accelerated or retarded by good government, but it could not be
effected at once, even if the combined wisdom of all the
philosophers and statesmen in Europe were employed in legislating
for the purpose.
The Zemstvo has, however, done much more than the majority of its
critics admit. It fulfils tolerably well, without scandalous
peculation and jobbery, its commonplace, every-day duties, and it
has created a new and more equitable system of rating, by which
landed proprietors and house-owners are made to bear their share of
the public burdens. It has done a very great deal to provide
medical aid and primary education for the common people, and it has
improved wonderfully the condition of the hospitals, lunatic
asylums, and other benevolent institutions committed to its charge.
In its efforts to aid the peasantry it has helped to improve the
native breeds of horses and cattle, and it has created a system of
obligatory fire-insurance, together with means for preventing and
extinguishing fires in the villages--a most important matter in a
country where the peasants live in wooden houses and big fires are
fearfully frequent. After neglecting for a good many years the
essential question as to how the peasants' means of subsistence can
be increased, it has latterly, as I have mentioned in a foregoing
chapter, helped them to obtain improved agricultural implements and
better seed, encouraged the formation of small credit associations
and savings banks, and appointed agricultural inspectors to teach
them how they may introduce modest improvements within their
limited means.* At the same time, in many districts it has
endeavoured to assist the home industries which are threatened with
annihilation by the big factories, and whenever measures have been
proposed for the benefit of the rural population, such as the
lowering of the land-redemption payments and the creation of the
Peasant Land Bank, it has invariably given them its cordial
support.
* The amount expended for these objects in 1897, the latest year
for which I have statistical data, was about a million and a half
of roubles, or, roughly speaking, 150,000 pounds, distributed under
the following heads:--
1. Agricultural tuition 41,100 pounds.
2. Experimental stations, museums, etc 19,800
3. Scientific agriculturists 17,400
4. Agricultural industries 26,700
5. Improving breeds of horses and cattle 45,300
-------
150,300 pounds.
If you ask a zealous member of the Zemstvo why it has not done more
he will probably tell you that it is because its activity has been
constantly restricted and counteracted by the Government. The
Assemblies were obliged to accept as presidents the Marshals of
Noblesse, many of whom were men of antiquated ideas and retrograde
principles. At every turn the more enlightened, more active
members found themselves opposed, thwarted, and finally checkmated
by the Imperial officials. When a laudable attempt was made to tax
trade and industry more equitably the scheme was vetoed, and
consequently the mercantile class, sure of being always taxed at a
ridiculously low maximum, have lost all interest in the
proceedings. Even with regard to the rating of landed and house
property a low limit is imposed by the Government, because it is
afraid that if the rates were raised much it would not be able to
collect the heavy Imperial taxation. The uncontrolled publicity
which was at first enjoyed by the Assemblies was afterwards
curtailed by the bureaucracy. Under such restrictions all free,
vigorous action became impossible, and the institutions failed to
effect what was reasonably anticipated.
All this is true in a certain sense, but it is not the whole truth.
If we examine some of the definite charges brought against the
institution we shall understand better its real character.
The most common complaint made against it is that it has enormously
increased the rates. On that point there is no possibility of
dispute. At first its expenditure in the thirty-four provinces in
which it existed was under six millions of roubles; in two years
(1868) it had jumped up to fifteen millions; in 1875 it was nearly
twenty-eight millions, in 1885 over forty-three millions, and at
the end of the century it had attained the respectable figure of
95,800,000 roubles. As each province had the right of taxing
itself, the increase varied greatly in different provinces. In
Smolensk, for example, it was only about thirty per cent., whilst
in Samara it was 436, and in Viatka, where the peasant element
predominates, no less than 1,262 per cent.! In order to meet this
increase, the rates on land rose from under ten millions in 1868 to
over forty-seven millions in 1900. No wonder that the landowners
who find it difficult to work their estates at a profit should
complain!
Though this increase is disagreeable to the rate-payers, it does
not follow that it is excessive. In all countries rates and local
taxation are on the increase, and it is in the backward countries
that they increase most rapidly. In France, for example, the
average yearly increase has been 2.7 per cent., while in Austria it
has been 5.59. In Russia it ought to have been more than in
Austria, whereas it has been, in the provinces with Zemstvo
institutions, only about 4 per cent. In comparison with the
Imperial taxation the local does not seem excessive when compared
with other countries. In England and Prussia, for instance, the
State taxation as compared with the local is as a hundred to fifty-
four and fifty-one, whilst in Russia it is as a hundred to
sixteen.* A reduction in the taxation as a whole would certainly
contribute to the material welfare of the rural population, but it
is desirable that it should be made in the Imperial taxes rather
than in the rates, because the latter may be regarded as something
akin to productive investments, whilst the proceeds of the former
are expended largely on objects which have little or nothing to do
with the wants of the common people. In speaking thus I am
assuming that the local expenditure is made judiciously, and this
is a matter on which, I am bound to confess, there is by no means
unanimity of opinion.
* These figures are taken from the best available authorities,
chiefly Schwanebach and Scalon, but I am not prepared to guarantee
their accuracy.
Hostile critics can point to facts which are, to say the least,
strange and anomalous. Out of the total of its revenue the Zemstvo
spends about twenty-eight per cent. under the heading of public
health and benevolent institutions; and about fifteen per cent. for
popular education, whilst it devotes only about six per cent. to
roads and bridges, and until lately it neglected, as I have said
above, the means for improving agriculture and directly increasing
the income of the peasantry.
Before passing sentence with regard to these charges we must
remember the circumstances in which the Zemstvo was founded and has
grown up. In the early times its members were well-meaning men who
had had very little experience in administration or in practical
life of any sort except the old routine in which they had
previously vegetated. Most of them had lived enough in the country
to know how much the peasants were in need of medical assistance of
the most elementary kind, and to this matter they at once turned
their attention. They tried to organise a system of doctors,
hospital assistants, and dispensaries by which the peasant would
not have to go more than fifteen or twenty miles to get a wound
dressed or to have a consultation or to obtain a simple remedy for
ordinary ailments. They felt the necessity, too, of thoroughly
reorganising the hospitals and the lunatic asylums, which were in a
very unsatisfactory condition. Plainly enough, there was here good
work to be done. Then there were the higher aims. In the absence
of practical experience there were enthusiasms and theories.
Amongst these was the enthusiasm for education, and the theory that
the want of it was the chief reason why Russia had remained so far
behind the nations of Western Europe. Give us education, it was
said, and all other good things will be added thereto. Liberate
the Russian people from the bonds of ignorance as you have
liberated it from the bonds of serfage, and its wonderful natural
capacities will then be able to create everything that is required
for its material, intellectual, and moral welfare.
If there was any one among the leaders who took a more sober,
prosaic view of things he was denounced as an ignoramus and a
reactionary. Willingly or unwillingly, everybody had to swim with
the current. Roads and bridges were not entirely neglected, but
the efforts in that direction were confined to the absolutely
indispensable. For such prosaic concerns there was no enthusiasm,
and it was universally recognised that in Russia the construction
of good roads, as the term is understood in Western Europe, was far
beyond the resources of any Administration. Of the necessity for
such roads few were conscious. All that was required was to make
it possible to get from one place to another in ordinary weather
and ordinary circumstances. If a stream was too deep to be forded,
a bridge had to be built or a ferry had to be established; and if
the approach to a bridge was so marshy or muddy that vehicles often
sank quite up to the axles and had to be dragged out by ropes, with
the assistance of the neighbouring villagers, repairs had to be
made. Beyond this the efforts of the Zemstvo rarely went. Its
road-building ambition remained within very modest bounds.
As for the impoverishment of the peasantry and the necessity of
improving their system of agriculture, that question had hardly
appeared above the horizon. It might have to be dealt with in the
future, but there was no need for hurry. Once the rural population
were educated, the question would solve itself. It was not till
about the year 1885 that it was recognised to be more urgent than
had been supposed, and some Zemstvos perceived that the people
might starve before its preparatory education was completed.
Repeated famines pushed the lesson home, and the landed proprietors
found their revenues diminished by the fall in the price of grain
on the European markets. Thus was raised the cry: "Agriculture in
Russia is on the decline! The country has entered on an acute
economic crisis! If energetic measures be not taken promptly the
people will soon find themselves confronted by starvation!"
To this cry of alarm the Zemstvo was neither deaf nor indifferent.
Recognising that the danger could be averted only by inducing the
peasantry to adopt a more intensive system of agriculture, it
directed more and more of its attention to agricultural
improvements, and tried to get them adopted.* It did, in short,
all it could, according to its lights and within the limits of its
moderate resources. Its available resources were small,
unfortunately, for it was forbidden by the Government to increase
the rates, and it could not well dismiss doctors and close
dispensaries and schools when the people were clamouring for more.
So at least the defenders of the Zemstvo maintain, and they go so
far as to contend that it did well not to grapple with the
impoverishment of the peasantry at an earlier period, when the real
conditions of the problem and the means of solving it were only
very imperfectly known: if it had begun at that time it would have
made great blunders and spent much money to little purpose.
* Vide supra, p. 489.
However this may be, it would certainly be unfair to condemn the
Zemstvo for not being greatly in advance of public opinion. If it
endeavours strenuously to supply all clearly recognised wants, that
is all that can reasonably be expected of it. What it may be more
justly reproached with is, in my opinion, that it is, to a certain
extent, imbued with that unpractical, pedantic spirit which is
commonly supposed to reside exclusively in the Imperial
Administration. But here again it simply reflects public opinion
and certain intellectual peculiarities of the educated classes.
When a Russian begins to write on a simple everyday subject, he
likes to connect it with general principles, philosophy, or
history, and begins, perhaps, by expounding his views on the
intellectual and social developments of humanity in general and of
Russia in particular. If he has sufficient space at his disposal
he may even tell you something about the early period of Russian
history previous to the Mongol invasion before he gets to the
simple matter in hand. In a previous chapter I have described the
process of "shedding on a subject the light of science" in Imperial
legislation.* In Zemstvo activity we often meet with pedantry of a
similar kind.
* Vide supra, p. 343.
If this pedantry were confined to the writing of Reports it might
not do much harm. Unfortunately, it often appears in the sphere of
action. To illustrate this I take a recent instance from the
province of Nizhni-Novgorod. The Zemstvo of that province received
from the Central Government in 1895 a certain amount of capital for
road-improvement, with instructions from the Ministry of Interior
that it should classify the roads according to their relative
importance and improve them accordingly. Any intelligent person
well acquainted with the region might have made, in the course of a
week or two, the required classification accurately enough for all
practical purposes. Instead of adopting this simple procedure,
what does the Zemstvo do? It chooses one of the eleven districts
of which the province is composed and instructs its statistical
department to describe all the villages with a view of determining
the amount of traffic which each will probably contribute to the
general movement, and then it verifies its a priori conclusions by
means of a detachment of specially selected "registrars," posted at
all the crossways during six days of each month. These registrars
doubtless inscribed every peasant cart as it passed and made a
rough estimate of the weight of its load. When this complicated
and expensive procedure was completed for one district it was
applied to another; but at the end of three years, before all the
villages of this second district had been described and the traffic
estimated, the energy of the statistical department seems to have
flagged, and, like a young author impatient to see himself in
print, it published a volume at the public expense which no one
will ever read.
The cost entailed by this procedure is not known, but we may form
some idea of the amount of time required for the whole operation.
It is a simple rule-of-three sum. If it took three years for the
preparatory investigation of a district and a half, how many years
will be required for eleven districts? More than twenty years!
During that period it would seem that the roads are to remain as
they are, and when the moment comes for improving them it will be
found that, unless the province is condemned to economic
stagnation, the "valuable statistical material" collected at such
an expenditure of time and money is in great part antiquated and
useless. The statistical department will be compelled, therefore,
like another unfortunate Sisyphus, to begin the work anew, and it
is difficult to see how the Zemstvo, unless it becomes a little
more practical, is ever to get out of the vicious circle.
In this case the evil result of pedantry was simply unnecessary
delay, and in the meantime the capital was accumulating, unless the
interest was entirely swallowed up by the statistical researches;
but there are cases in which the consequences are more serious.
Let me take an illustration from the enlightened province of
Moscow. It was observed that certain villages were particularly
unhealthy, and it was pointed out by a local doctor that the
inhabitants were in the habit of using for domestic purposes the
water of ponds which were in a filthy condition. What was
evidently wanted was good wells, and a practical man would at once
have taken measures to have them dug. Not so the District Zemstvo.
It at once transformed the simple fact into a "question" requiring
scientific investigation. A commission was appointed to study the
problem, and after much deliberation it was decided to make a
geological survey in order to ascertain the depth of good water
throughout the district as a preparatory step towards preparing a
project which will some day be discussed in the District Assembly,
and perhaps in the Assembly of the province. Whilst all this is
being done according to the strict principles of bureaucratic
procedure, the unfortunate peasants for whose benefit the
investigation was undertaken continue to drink the muddy water of
the dirty ponds.
Incidents of that kind, which I might multiply almost to any
extent, remind one of the proverbial formalism of the Chinese; but
between Chinese and Russian pedantry there is an essential
difference. In the Middle Kingdom the sacrifice of practical
considerations proceeds from an exaggerated veneration of the
wisdom of ancestors; in the Empire of the Tsars it is due to an
exaggerated adoration of the goddess Nauka (Science) and a habit of
appealing to abstract principles and scientific methods when only a
little plain common-sense is required.
On one occasion, I remember, in a District Assembly of the province
of Riazan, when the subject of primary schools was being discussed,
an influential member started up, and proposed that an obligatory
system of education should at once be introduced throughout the
whole district. Strange to say, the motion was very nearly
carried, though all the members present knew--or at least might
have known if they had taken the trouble to inquire--that the
actual number of schools would have to be multiplied twenty-fold,
and all were agreed that the local rates must not be increased. To
preserve his reputation for liberalism, the honourable member
further proposed that, though the system should be obligatory, no
fines, punishments, or other means of compulsion should be
employed. How a system could be obligatory without using some
means of compulsion, he did not condescend to explain. To get out
of the difficulty one of his supporters suggested that the peasants
who did not send their children to school should be excluded from
serving as office-bearers in the Communes; but this proposition
merely created a laugh, for many deputies knew that the peasants
would regard this supposed punishment as a valuable privilege. And
whilst this discussion about the necessity of introducing an ideal
system of obligatory education was being carried on, the street
before the windows of the room was covered with a stratum of mud
nearly two feet in depth! The other streets were in a similar
condition; and a large number of the members always arrived late,
because it was almost impossible to come on foot, and there was
only one public conveyance in the town. Many members had,
fortunately, their private conveyances, but even in these
locomotion was by no means easy. One day, in the principal
thoroughfare, a member had his tarantass overturned, and he himself
was thrown into the mud!
It is hardly fair to compare the Zemstvo with the older
institutions of a similar kind in Western Europe, and especially
with our own local self-government. Our institutions have all
grown out of real, practical wants keenly felt by a large section
of the population. Cautious and conservative in all that concerns
the public welfare, we regard change as a necessary evil, and put
off the evil day as long as possible, even when convinced that it
must inevitably come. Thus our administrative wants are always in
advance of our means of satisfying them, and we use vigorously
those means as soon as they are supplied. Our method of supplying
the means, too, is peculiar. Instead of making a tabula rasa, and
beginning from the foundations, we utilise to the utmost what we
happen to possess, and add merely what is absolutely indispensable.
Metaphorically speaking, we repair and extend our political edifice
according to the changing necessities of our mode of life, without
paying much attention to abstract principles or the contingencies
of the distant future. The building may be an aesthetic
monstrosity, belonging to no recognised style of architecture, and
built in defiance of the principles laid down by philosophical art
critics, but it is well adapted to our requirements, and every hole
and corner of it is sure to be utilised.
Very different has been the political history of Russia during the
last two centuries. It may be briefly described as a series of
revolutions effected peaceably by the Autocratic Power. Each young
energetic sovereign has attempted to inaugurate a new epoch by
thoroughly remodelling the Administration according to the most
approved foreign political philosophy of the time. Institutions
have not been allowed to grow spontaneously out of popular wants,
but have been invented by bureaucratic theorists to satisfy wants
of which the people were still unconscious. The administrative
machine has therefore derived little or no motive force from the
people, and has always been kept in motion by the unaided energy of
the Central Government. Under these circumstances it is not
surprising that the repeated attempts of the Government to lighten
the burdens of centralised administration by creating organs of
local self-government should not have been very successful.
The Zemstvo, it is true, offered better chances of success than any
of its predecessors. A large portion of the nobles had become
alive to the necessity of improving the administration, and the
popular interest in public affairs was much greater than at any
former period. Hence there was at first a period of enthusiasm,
during which great preparations were made for future activity, and
not a little was actually effected. The institution had all the
charm of novelty, and the members felt that the eyes of the public
were upon them. For a time all went well, and the Zemstvo was so
well pleased with its own activity that the satirical journals
compared it to Narcissus admiring his image reflected in the pool.
But when the charm of novelty had passed and the public turned its
attention to other matters, the spasmodic energy evaporated, and
many of the most active members looked about for more lucrative
employment. Such employment was easily found, for at that time
there was an unusual demand for able, energetic, educated men.
Several branches of the civil service were being reorganised, and
railways, banks, and joint-stock companies were being rapidly
multiplied. With these the Zemstvo had great difficulty in
competing. It could not, like the Imperial service, offer
pensions, decorations, and prospects of promotion, nor could it pay
such large salaries as the commercial and industrial enterprises.
In consequence of all this, the quality of the executive bureaux
deteriorated at the same time as the public interest in the
institution diminished.
To be just to the Zemstvo, I must add that, with all its defects
and errors, it is infinitely better than the institutions which it
replaced. If we compare it with previous attempts to create local
self-government, we must admit that the Russians have made great
progress in their political education. What its future may be I do
not venture to predict. From its infancy it has had, as we have
seen, the ambition to play a great political part, and at the
beginning of the recent stirring times in St. Petersburg its
leading representatives in conclave assembled took upon themselves
to express what they considered the national demand for liberal
representative institutions. The desire, which had previously from
time to time been expressed timidly and vaguely in loyal addresses
to the Tsar, that a central Zemstvo Assembly, bearing the ancient
title of Zemski Sobor, should be convoked in the capital and
endowed with political functions, was now put forward by the
representatives in plain unvarnished form. Whether this desire is
destined to be realised time will show.
CHAPTER XXXIII
THE NEW LAW COURTS
Judicial Procedure in the Olden Times--Defects and Abuses--Radical
Reform--The New System--Justices of the Peace and Monthly Sessions--
The Regular Tribunals--Court of Revision--Modification of the
Original Plan--How Does the System Work?--Rapid Acclimatisation--
The Bench--The Jury--Acquittal of Criminals Who Confess Their
Crimes--Peasants, Merchants, and Nobles as Jurymen--Independence
and Political Significance of the New Courts.
After serf-emancipation and local self-government, the subject
which demanded most urgently the attention of reformers was the
judicial organisation, which had sunk to a depth of inefficiency
and corruption difficult to describe.
In early times the dispensation of justice in Russia, as in other
States of a primitive type, had a thoroughly popular character.
The State was still in its infancy, and the duty of defending the
person, the property, and the rights of individuals lay, of
necessity, chiefly on the individuals themselves. Self-help formed
the basis of the judicial procedure, and the State merely assisted
the individual to protect his rights and to avenge himself on those
who voluntarily infringed them.
By the rapid development of the Autocratic Power all this was
changed. Autocracy endeavoured to drive and regulate the social
machine by its own unaided force, and regarded with suspicion and
jealousy all spontaneous action in the people. The dispensation of
justice was accordingly appropriated by the central authority,
absorbed into the Administration, and withdrawn from public
control. Themis retired from the market-place, shut herself up in
a dark room from which the contending parties and the public gaze
were rigorously excluded, surrounded herself with secretaries and
scribes who put the rights and claims of the litigants into
whatever form they thought proper, weighed according to her own
judgment the arguments presented to her by her own servants, and
came forth from her seclusion merely to present a ready-made
decision or to punish the accused whom she considered guilty.
This change, though perhaps to some extent necessary, was attended
with very bad consequences. Freed from the control of the
contending parties and of the public, the courts acted as
uncontrolled human nature generally does. Injustice, extortion,
bribery, and corruption assumed gigantic proportions, and against
these evils the Government found no better remedy than a system of
complicated formalities and ingenious checks. The judicial
functionaries were hedged in by a multitude of regulations, so
numerous and complicated that it seemed impossible for even the
most unjust judge to swerve from the path of uprightness.
Explicit, minute rules were laid down for investigating facts and
weighing evidence; every scrap of evidence and every legal ground
on which the decision was based were committed to writing; every
act in the complicated process of coming to a decision was made the
subject of a formal document, and duly entered in various
registers; every document and register had to be signed and
countersigned by various officials who were supposed to control
each other; every decision might be carried to a higher court and
made to pass a second time through the bureaucratic machine. In a
word, the legislature introduced a system of formal written
procedure of the most complicated kind, in the belief that by this
means mistakes and dishonesty would be rendered impossible.
It may be reasonably doubted whether this system of judicial
administration can anywhere give satisfactory results. It is
everywhere found by experience that in tribunals from which the
healthy atmosphere of publicity is excluded justice languishes, and
a great many ugly plants shoot up with wonderful vitality. Languid
indifference, an indiscriminating spirit of routine, and unblushing
dishonesty invariably creep in through the little chinks and
crevices of the barrier raised against them, and no method of
hermetically sealing these chinks and crevices has yet been
invented. The attempt to close them up by increasing the
formalities and multiplying the courts of appeal and revision
merely adds to the tediousness of the procedure, and withdraws the
whole process still more completely from public control. At the
same time the absence of free discussion between the contending
parties renders the task of the judge enormously difficult. If the
system is to succeed at all, it must provide a body of able,
intelligent, thoroughly-trained jurists, and must place them beyond
the reach of bribery and other forms of corruption.
In Russia neither of these conditions was fulfilled. Instead of
endeavouring to create a body of well-trained jurists, the
Government went further and further in the direction of letting the
judges be chosen for a short period by popular election from among
men who had never received a juridical education, or a fair
education of any kind; whilst the place of judge was so poorly
paid, and stood so low in public estimation, that the temptations
to dishonesty were difficult to resist.
The practice of choosing the judges by popular election was an
attempt to restore to the courts something of their old popular
character; but it did not succeed, for very obvious reasons.
Popular election in a judicial organisation is useful only when the
courts are public and the procedure simple; on the contrary, it is
positively prejudicial when the procedure is in writing and
extremely complicated. And so it proved in Russia. The elected
judges, unprepared for their work, and liable to be changed at
short intervals, rarely acquired a knowledge of law or procedure.
They were for the most part poor, indolent landed proprietors, who
did little more than sign the decisions prepared for them by the
permanent officials. Even when a judge happened to have some legal
knowledge he found small scope for its application, for he rarely,
if ever, examined personally the materials out of which a decision
was to be elaborated. The whole of the preliminary work, which was
in reality the most important, was performed by minor officials
under the direction of the secretary of the court. In criminal
cases, for instance, the secretary examined the written evidence--
all evidence was taken down in writing--extracted what he
considered the essential points, arranged them as he thought
proper, quoted the laws which ought in his opinion to be applied,
put all this into a report, and read the report to the judges. Of
course the judges, if they had no personal interest in the
decision, accepted the secretary's view of the case. If they did
not, all the preliminary work had to be done anew by themselves--a
task that few judges were able, and still fewer willing, to
perform. Thus the decision lay virtually in the hands of the
secretary and the minor officials, and in general neither the
secretary nor the minor officials were fit persons to have such
power. There is no need to detail here the ingenious expedients by
which they increased their meagre salaries, and how they generally
contrived to extract money from both parties.* Suffice it to say
that in general the chancelleries of the courts were dens of
pettifogging rascality, and the habitual, unblushing bribery had a
negative as well as a positive effect. If a person accused of some
crime had no money wherewith to grease the palm of the secretary he
might remain in prison for years without being brought to trial. A
well-known Russian writer still living relates that when visiting a
prison in the province of Nizhni-Novgorod he found among the
inmates undergoing preliminary arrest two peasant women, who were
accused of setting fire to a hayrick to revenge themselves on a
landed proprietor, a crime for which the legal punishment was from
four to eight months' imprisonment. One of them had a son of seven
years of age, and the other a son of twelve, both of whom had been
born in the prison, and had lived there ever since among the
criminals. Such a long preliminary arrest caused no surprise or
indignation among those who heard of it, because it was quite a
common occurrence. Every one knew that bribes were taken not only
by the secretary and his scribes, but also by the judges, who were
elected by the local Noblesse from its own ranks.
* Old book-catalogues sometimes mention a play bearing the
significant title, "The Unheard-of Wonder; or, The Honest
Secretary" (Neslykhannoe Dyelo ili Tchestny Sekretar). I have
never seen this curious production, but I have no doubt that it
referred to the peculiarities of the old judicial procedure.
With regard to the scale of punishments, notwithstanding some
humanitarian principles in the legislation, they were very severe,
and corporal punishment played amongst them a disagreeably
prominent part. Capital sentences were abolished as early as 1753-
54, but castigation with the knout, which often ended fatally,
continued until 1845, when it was replaced by flogging in the civil
administration, though retained for the military and for
insubordinate convicts. For the non-privileged classes the knout
or the lash supplemented nearly all punishments of a criminal kind.
When a man was condemned, for example, to penal servitude, he
received publicly from thirty to one hundred lashes, and was then
branded on the forehead and cheeks with the letters K. A. T.--the
first three letters of katorzhnik (convict). If he appealed he
received his lashes all the same, and if his appeal was rejected by
the Senate he received some more castigation for having troubled
unnecessarily the higher judicial authorities. For the military
and insubordinate convicts there was a barbarous punishment called
Spitsruten, to the extent of 5,000 or 6,000 blows, which often
ended in the death of the unfortunate.
The use of torture in criminal investigations was formally
abolished in 1801, but if we may believe the testimony of a public
prosecutor, it was occasionally used in Moscow as late as 1850.
The defects and abuses of the old system were so flagrant that they
became known even to the Emperor Nicholas I., and caused him
momentary indignation, but he never attempted seriously to root
them out. In 1844, for example, he heard of some gross abuses in a
tribunal not far from the Winter Palace, and ordered an
investigation. Baron Korff, to whom the investigation was
entrusted, brought to light what he called "a yawning abyss of all
possible horrors, which have been accumulating for years," and his
Majesty, after reading the report, wrote upon it with his own hand:
"Unheard-of disgrace! The carelessness of the authority
immediately concerned is incredible and unpardonable. I feel
ashamed and sad that such disorder could exist almost under my eyes
and remain unknown to me." Unfortunately the outburst of Imperial
indignation did not last long enough to produce any desirable
consequences. The only result was that one member of the tribunal
was dismissed from the service, and the Governor-General of St.
Petersburg had to resign, but the latter subsequently received an
honorary reward, and the Emperor remarked that he was himself to
blame for having kept the Governor-General so long at his post.
When his Majesty's habitual optimism happened to be troubled by
incidents of this sort he probably consoled himself with
remembering that he had ordered some preparatory work, by which the
administration of justice might be improved, and this work was
being diligently carried out in the legislative section of his own
chancery by Count Bludof, one of the ablest Russian lawyers of his
time. Unfortunately the existing state of things was not thereby
improved, because the preparatory work was not of the kind that was
wanted. On the assumption that any evil which might exist could be
removed by improving the laws, Count Bludof devoted his efforts
almost entirely to codification. In reality what was required was
to change radically the organisation of the courts and the
procedure, and above all to let in on their proceedings the
cleansing atmosphere of publicity. This the Emperor Nicholas could
not understand, and if he had understood it he could not have
brought himself to adopt the appropriate remedies, because radical
reform and control of officials by public opinion were his two pet
bugbears.
Very different was his son and successor, Alexander II., in the
first years of his reign. In his accession manifesto a prominent
place was given to his desire that justice and mercy should reign
in the courts of law. Referring to these words in a later
manifesto, he explained his wishes more fully as "the desire to
establish in Russia expeditious, just, merciful, impartial courts
of justice for all our subjects; to raise the judicial authority;
to give it the proper independence, and in general to implant in
the people that respect for the law which ought to be the constant
guide of all and every one from the highest to the lowest." These
were not mere vain words. Peremptory orders had been given that
the great work should be undertaken without delay, and when the
Emancipation question was being discussed in the Provincial
Committees, the Council of State examined the question of judicial
reform "from the historical, the theoretical, and the practical
point of view," and came to the conclusion that the existing
organisation must be completely transformed.
The commission appointed to consider this important matter filed a
lengthy indictment against the existing system, and pointed out no
less than twenty-five radical defects. To remove these it proposed
that the judicial organisation should be completely separated from
all other branches of the Administration; that the most ample
publicity, with trial by jury in criminal cases, should be
introduced into the tribunals; that Justice of Peace Courts should
be created for petty affairs; and that the procedure in the
ordinary courts should be greatly simplified.
These fundamental principles were published by Imperial command on
September 29th, 1862--a year and a half after the publication of
the Emancipation Manifesto--and on November 20th, 1864, the new
legislation founded on these principles received the Imperial
sanction.
Like most institutions erected on a tabula rasa, the new system is
at once simple and symmetrical. As a whole, the architecture of
the edifice is decidedly French, but here and there we may detect
unmistakable symptoms of English influence. It is not, however, a
servile copy of any older edifice; and it may be fairly said that,
though every individual part has been fashioned according to a
foreign model, the whole has a certain originality.
The lower part of the building in its original form was composed of
two great sections, distinct from, and independent of, each other--
on the one hand the Justice of Peace Courts, and on the other the
Regular Tribunals. Both sections contained an Ordinary Court and a
Court of Appeal. The upper part of the building, covering equally
both sections, was the Senate as Supreme Court of Revision (Cour de
Cassation).
The distinctive character of the two independent sections may be
detected at a glance. The function of the Justice of Peace Courts
is to decide petty cases that involve no abstruse legal principles,
and to settle, if possible by conciliation, those petty conflicts
and disputes which arise naturally in the relations of everyday
life; the function of the Regular Tribunals is to take cognisance
of those graver affairs in which the fortune or honour of
individuals or families is more or less implicated, or in which the
public tranquillity is seriously endangered. The two kinds of
courts were organised in accordance with these intended functions.
In the former the procedure is simple and conciliatory, the
jurisdiction is confined to cases of little importance, and the
judges were at first chosen by popular election, generally from
among the local inhabitants. In the latter there is more of "the
pomp and majesty of the law." The procedure is more strict and
formal, the jurisdiction is unlimited with regard to the importance
of the cases, and the judges are trained jurists nominated by the
Emperor.
The Justice of Peace Courts received jurisdiction over all
obligations and civil injuries in which the sum at stake was not
more than 500 roubles--about 50 pounds--and all criminal affairs in
which the legal punishment did not exceed 300 roubles--about 30
pounds--or one year of punishment. When any one had a complaint to
make, he might go to the Justice of the Peace (Mirovoi Sudya) and
explain the affair orally, or in writing, without observing any
formalities; and if the complaint seemed well founded, the Justice
at once fixed a day for hearing the case, and gave the other party
notice to appear at the appointed time. When the time appointed
arrived, the affair was discussed publicly and orally, either by
the parties themselves, or by any representatives whom they might
appoint. If it was a civil suit, the Justice began by proposing to
the parties to terminate it at once by a compromise, and indicated
what he considered a fair arrangement. Many affairs were
terminated in this simple way. If, however, either of the parties
refused to consent to a compromise, the matter was fully discussed,
and the Justice gave a formal written decision, containing the
grounds on which it was based. In criminal cases the amount of
punishment was always determined by reference to a special Criminal
Code.
If the sum at issue exceeded thirty roubles--about 3 pounds--or if
the punishment exceeded a fine of fifteen roubles--about 30s.--or
three days of arrest, an appeal might be made to the Assembly of
Justices (Mirovoi Syezd). This is a point in which English rather
than French institutions were taken as a model. According to the
French system, all appeals from a Juge de Paix are made to the
"Tribunal d'Arrondissement," and the Justice of Peace Courts are
thereby subordinated to the Regular Tribunals. According to the
English system, certain cases may be carried on appeal from the
Justice of the Peace to the Quarter Sessions. This latter
principle was adopted and greatly developed by the Russian
legislation. The Monthly Sessions, composed of all the Justices of
the District (uyezd), considered appeals against the decisions of
the individual Justices. The procedure was simple and informal, as
in the lower court, but an assistant of the Procureur was always
present. This functionary gave his opinion in some civil and in
all criminal cases immediately after the debate, and the Court took
his opinion into consideration in framing its judgment.
In the other great section of the judicial organisation--the
Regular Tribunals--there are likewise Ordinary Courts and Courts of
Appeal, called respectively "Tribunaux d'Arrondissement"
(Okruzhniye Sudy) and "Palais de Justice" (Sudebniya Palaty). Each
Ordinary Court has jurisdiction over several Districts (uyezdy),
and the jurisdiction of each Court of Appeals comprehends several
Provinces. All civil cases are subject to appeal, however small
the sum at stake may be, but criminal cases are decided FINALLY by
the lower court with the aid of a jury. Thus in criminal affairs
the "Palais de Justice" is not at all a court of appeal, but as no
regular criminal prosecution can be raised without its formal
consent, it controls in some measure the action of the lower
courts.
As the general reader cannot be supposed to take an interest in the
details of civil procedure, I shall merely say on this subject that
in both sections of the Regular Tribunals the cases are always
tried by at least three judges, the sittings are public, and oral
debates by officially recognised advocates form an important part
of the proceedings. I venture, however, to speak a little more at
length regarding the change which has been made in the criminal
procedure--a subject that is less technical and more interesting
for the uninitiated.
Down to the time of the recent judicial reforms the procedure in
criminal cases was secret and inquisitorial. The accused had
little opportunity of defending himself, but, on the other hand,
the State took endless formal precautions against condemning the
innocent. The practical consequence of this system was that an
innocent man might remain for years in prison until the authorities
convinced themselves of his innocence, whilst a clever criminal
might indefinitely postpone his condemnation.
In studying the history of criminal procedure in foreign countries,
those who were entrusted with the task of preparing projects of
reform found that nearly every country of Europe had experienced
the evils from which Russia was suffering, and that one country
after another had come to the conviction that the most efficient
means of removing these evils was to replace the inquisitorial by
litigious procedure, to give a fair field and no favour to the
prosecutor and the accused, and allow them to fight out their
battle with whatever legal weapons they might think fit. Further,
it was discovered that, according to the most competent foreign
authorities, it was well in this modern form of judicial combat to
leave the decision to a jury of respectable citizens. The steps
which Russia had to take were thus clearly marked out by the
experience of other nations, and it was decided that they should be
taken at once. The organs for the prosecution of supposed
criminals were carefully separated from the judges on the one hand,
and from the police on the other; oral discussions between the
Public Prosecutor and the prisoner's counsel, together with oral
examination and cross-questioning of witnesses, were introduced
into the procedure; and the jury was made an essential factor in
criminal trials.
When a case, whether civil or criminal, has been decided in the
Regular Tribunals, there is no possibility of appeal in the strict
sense of the term, but an application may be made for a revision of
the case on the ground of technical informality. To use the French
terms, there cannot be appel, but there may be cassation. If there
has been any omission or transgression of essential legal
formalities, or if the Court has overstepped the bounds of its
legal authority, the injured party may make an application to have
the case revised and tried again.* This is not, according to
French juridical conceptions, an appeal. The Court of Revision**
(Cour de Cassation) does not enter into the material facts of the
case, but merely decides the question as to whether the essential
formalities have been duly observed, and as to whether the law has
been properly interpreted and applied; and if it be found on
examination that there is some ground for invalidating the
decision, it does not decide the case. According to the new
Russian system, the sole Court of Revision is the Senate.
* This is the procedure referred to by Karl Karl'itch, vide supra,
p 37.
** I am quite aware that the term "Court of Revision" is equivocal,
but I have no better term to propose, and I hope the above
explanations will prevent confusion.
The Senate thus forms the regulator of the whole judicial system,
but its action is merely regulative. It takes cognisance only of
what is presented to it, and supplies to the machine no motive
power. If any of the lower courts should work slowly or cease to
work altogether, the Senate might remain ignorant of the fact, and
certainly could take no official notice of it. It was considered
necessary, therefore, to supplement the spontaneous vitality of the
lower courts, and for this purpose was created a special
centralised judicial administration, at the head of which was
placed the Minister of Justice. The Minister is "Procureur-
General," and has subordinates in all the courts. The primary
function of this administration is to preserve the force of the
law, to detect and repair all infractions of judicial order, to
defend the interests of the State and of those persons who are
officially recognised as incapable of taking charge of their own
affairs, and to act in criminal matters as Public Prosecutor.
Viewed as a whole, and from a little distance, this grand judicial
edifice seems perfectly symmetrical, but a closer and more minute
inspection brings to light unmistakable indications of a change of
plan during the process of construction. Though the work lasted
only about half-a-dozen years, the style of the upper differs from
the style of the lower parts, precisely as in those Gothic
cathedrals which grew up slowly during the course of centuries.
And there is nothing here that need surprise us, for a considerable
change took place in the opinions of the official world during that
short period. The reform was conceived at a time of uncritical
enthusiasm for advanced liberal ideas, of boundless faith in the
dictates of science, of unquestioning reliance on public spirit,
public control, and public honesty--a time in which it was believed
that the public would spontaneously do everything necessary for the
common weal, if it were only freed from the administrative
swaddling-clothes in which it had been hitherto bound. Still
smarting from the severe regime of Nicholas, men thought more about
protecting the rights of the individual than about preserving
public order, and under the influence of the socialistic ideas in
vogue malefactors were regarded as the unfortunate, involuntary
victims of social inequality and injustice.
Towards the end of the period in question all this had begun to
change. Many were beginning to perceive that liberty might easily
turn to license, that the spontaneous public energy was largely
expended in empty words, and that a certain amount of hierarchical
discipline was necessary in order to keep the public administration
in motion. It was found, therefore, in 1864, that it was
impossible to carry out to their ultimate consequences the general
principles laid down and published in 1862. Even in those parts of
the legislation which were actually put in force, it was found
necessary to make modifications in an indirect, covert way. Of
these, one may be cited by way of illustration. In 1860 criminal
inquiries were taken out of the hands of the police and transferred
to Juges d'instruction (Sudebniye Sledovateli), who were almost
entirely independent of the Public Prosecutor, and could not be
removed unless condemned for some legal transgression by a Regular
Tribunal. This reform created at first much rejoicing and great
expectations, because it raised a barrier against the tyranny of
the police and against the arbitrary power of the higher officials.
But very soon the defects of the system became apparent. Many
Juges d'instruction, feeling themselves independent, and knowing
that they would not be prosecuted except for some flagrantly
illegal act, gave way to indolence, and spent their time in
inactivity.* In such cases it was always difficult, and sometimes
impossible, to procure a condemnation--for indolence must assume
gigantic proportions in order to become a crime--and the minister
had to adopt the practice of appointing, without Imperial
confirmation, temporary Juges d'instruction whom he could remove at
pleasure.
* A flagrant case of this kind came under my own observation.
It is unnecessary, however, to enter into these theoretical
defects. The important question for the general public is: How do
the institutions work in the local conditions in which they are
placed?
This is a question which has an interest not only for Russians, but
for all students of social science, for it tends to throw light on
the difficult subject as to how far institutions may be
successfully transplanted to a foreign soil. Many thinkers hold,
and not without reason, that no institution can work well unless it
is the natural product of previous historical development. Now we
have here an opportunity of testing this theory by experience; we
have even what Bacon terms an experimentum crucis. This new
judicial system is an artificial creation constructed in accordance
with principles laid down by foreign jurists. All that the
elaborators of the project said about developing old institutions
was mere talk. In reality they made a tabula rasa of the existing
organisation. If the introduction of public oral procedure and
trial by jury was a return to ancient customs, it was a return to
what had been long since forgotten by all except antiquarian
specialists, and no serious attempt was made to develop what
actually existed. One form, indeed, of oral procedure had been
preserved in the Code, but it had fallen completely into disuse,
and seems to have been overlooked by the elaborators of the new
system.*
* I refer to the so-called Sud po forme established by an ukaz of
Peter the Great, in 1723. I was much astonished when I
accidentally stumbled upon it in the Code.
Having in general little confidence in institutions which spring
ready-made from the brains of autocratic legislators, I expected to
find that this new judicial organisation, which looks so well on
paper, was well-nigh worthless in reality. Observation, however,
has not confirmed my pessimistic expectations. On the contrary, I
have found that these new institutions, though they have not yet
had time to strike deep root, and are very far from being perfect
even in the human sense of the term, work on the whole remarkably
well, and have already conferred immense benefit on the country.
In the course of a few years the Justice of Peace Courts, which may
perhaps be called the newest part of the new institutions, became
thoroughly acclimatised, as if they had existed for generations.
As soon as they were opened they became extremely popular. In
Moscow the authorities had calculated that under the new system the
number of cases would be more than doubled, and that on an average
each justice would have nearly a thousand cases brought before him
in the course of the year. The reality far exceeded their
expectations: each justice had on an average 2,800 cases. In St.
Petersburg and the other large towns the amount of work which the
justices had to get through was equally great.
To understand the popularity of the Justice of Peace Courts, we
must know something of the old police courts which they supplanted.
The nobles, the military, and the small officials had always looked
on the police with contempt, because their position secured them
against interference, and the merchants acquired a similar immunity
by submitting to blackmail, which often took the form of a fixed
subsidy; but the lower classes in town and country stood, in fear
of the humblest policeman, and did not dare to complain of him to
his superiors. If two workmen brought their differences before a
police court, instead of getting their case decided on grounds of
equity, they were pretty sure to get scolded in language unfit for
ears polite, or to receive still worse treatment. Even among the
higher officers of the force many became famous for their
brutality. A Gorodnitchi of the town of Tcherkassy, for example,
made for himself in this respect a considerable reputation. If any
humble individual ventured to offer an objection to him, he had at
once recourse to his fists, and any reference to the law put him
into a state of frenzy. "The town," he was wont to say on such
occasions, "has been entrusted to me by his Majesty, and you dare
to talk to me of the law? There is the law for you!"--the remark
being accompanied with a blow. Another officer of the same type,
long resident in Kief, had a somewhat different method of
maintaining order. He habitually drove about the town with a
Cossack escort, and when any one of the lower classes had the
misfortune to displease him, he ordered one of his Cossacks to
apply a little corporal punishment on the spot without any legal
formalities.
In the Justice of Peace Courts things were conducted in a very
different style. The justice, always scrupulously polite without
distinction of persons, listened patiently to the complaint, tried
to arrange the affairs amicably, and when his efforts failed, gave
his decision at once according to law and common-sense. No
attention was paid to rank or social position. A general who would
not attend to the police regulations was fined like an ordinary
workingman, and in a dispute between a great dignitary and a man of
the people the two were treated in precisely the same way. No
wonder such courts became popular among the masses; and their
popularity was increased when it became known that the affairs were
disposed of expeditiously, without unnecessary formalities and
without any bribes or blackmail. Many peasants regarded the
justice as they had been wont to regard kindly proprietors of the
old patriarchal type, and brought their griefs and sorrows to him
in the hope that he would somehow alleviate them. Often they
submitted most intimate domestic and matrimonial concerns of which
no court could possibly take cognisance, and sometimes they
demanded the fulfilment of contracts which were in flagrant
contradiction not only with the written law, but also with ordinary
morality.*
* Many curious instances of this have come to my knowledge, but
they are of such a kind that they cannot be quoted in a work
intended for the general public.
Of course, the courts were not entirely without blemishes. In the
matter, for example, of making no distinction of persons some of
the early justices, in seeking to avoid Scylla, came dangerously
near to Charybdis. Imagining that their mission was to eradicate
the conceptions and habits which had been created and fostered by
serfage, they sometimes used their authority for giving lessons in
philanthropic liberalism, and took a malicious delight in wounding
the susceptibilities, and occasionally even the material interests,
of those whom they regarded as enemies to the good cause. In
disputes between master and servant, or between employer and
workmen, the justice of this type considered it his duty to resist
the tyranny of capital, and was apt to forget his official
character of judge in his assumed character of social reformer.
Happily these aberrations on the part of the justices are already
things of the past, but they helped to bring about a reaction, as
we shall see presently.
The extreme popularity of the Justice of Peace Courts did not last
very long. Their history resembled that of the Zemstvo and many
other new institutions in Russia--at first, enthusiasm and
inordinate expectations; then consciousness of defects and
practical inconveniences; and, lastly, in an influential section of
the public, the pessimism of shattered illusions, accompanied by
the adoption of a reactionary policy on the part of the Government.
The discontent appeared first among the so-called privileged
classes. To people who had all their lives enjoyed great social
consideration it seemed monstrous that they should be treated
exactly in the same way as the muzhik; and when a general who was
accustomed to be addressed as "Your Excellency," was accused of
using abusive language to his cook, and found himself seated on the
same bench with the menial, he naturally supposed that the end of
all things was at hand; or perhaps a great civil official, who was
accustomed to regard the police as created merely for the lower
classes, suddenly found himself, to his inexpressible astonishment,
fined for a contravention of police regulations! Naturally the
justices were accused of dangerous revolutionary tendencies, and
when they happened to bring to light some injustice on the part of
the tchinovnik they were severely condemned for undermining the
prestige of the Imperial authority.
For a time the accusations provoked merely a smile or a caustic
remark among the Liberals, but about the middle of the eighties
criticisms began to appear even in the Liberal Press. No very
grave allegations were made, but defects in the system and
miscarriages of justice were put forward and severely commented
upon. Occasionally it happened that a justice was indolent, or
that at the Sessions in a small country town it was impossible to
form a quorum on the appointed day. Overlooking the good features
of the institution and the good services rendered by it, the
critics began to propose partial reorganisation in the sense of
greater control by central authorities. It was suggested, for
example, that the President of Sessions should be appointed by the
Government, that the justices should be subordinated to the Regular
Tribunals, and that the principle of election by the Zemstvo should
be abolished.
These complaints were not at all unwelcome to the Government,
because it had embarked on a reactionary policy, and in 1889 it
suddenly granted to the critics a great deal more than they
desired. In the rural districts of Central Russia the justices
were replaced by the rural supervisors, of whom I have spoken in a
previous chapter, and the part of their functions which could not
well be entrusted to those new officials was transferred to judges
of the Regular Courts. In some of the larger towns and in the
rural districts of outlying provinces the justices were preserved,
but instead of being elected by the Zemstvo they were nominated by
the Government.
The regular Tribunals likewise became acclimatised in an incredibly
short space of time. The first judges were not by any means
profound jurists, and were too often deficient in that
dispassionate calmness which we are accustomed to associate with
the Bench; but they were at least honest, educated men, and
generally possessed a fair knowledge of the law. Their defects
were due to the fact that the demand for trained jurists far
exceeded the supply, and the Government was forced to nominate men
who under ordinary circumstances would never have thought of
presenting themselves as candidates. At the beginning of 1870, in
the 32 "Tribunaux d'Arrondissement" which then existed, there were
227 judges, of whom 44 had never received a juridical education.
Even the presidents had not all passed through a school of law. Of
course the courts could not become thoroughly effective until all
the judges were men who had received a good special education and
had a practical acquaintance with judicial matters. This has now
been effected, and the present generation of judges are better
prepared and more capable than their predecessors. On the score of
probity I have never heard any complaints.
Of all the judicial innovations, perhaps the most interesting is
the jury.
At the time of the reforms the introduction of the jury into the
judicial organisation awakened among the educated classes a great
amount of sentimental enthusiasm. The institution had the
reputation of being "liberal," and was known to be approved of by
the latest authorities in criminal jurisprudence. This was
sufficient to insure it a favourable reception, and to excite most
exaggerated expectations as to its beneficent influence. Ten years
of experience somewhat cooled this enthusiasm, and voices might be
heard declaring that the introduction of the jury was a mistake.
The Russian people, it was held, was not yet ripe for such an
institution, and numerous anecdotes were related in support of this
opinion. One jury, for instance, was said to have returned a
verdict of "NOT guilty with extenuating circumstances"; and
another, being unable to come to a decision, was reported to have
cast lots before an Icon, and to have given a verdict in accordance
with the result! Besides this, juries often gave a verdict of "not
guilty" when the accused made a full and formal confession to the
court.
How far the comic anecdotes are true I do not undertake to decide,
but I venture to assert that such incidents, if they really occur,
are too few to form the basis of a serious indictment. The fact,
however, that juries often acquit prisoners who openly confess
their crime is beyond all possibility of doubt.
To most Englishmen this fact will probably seem sufficient to prove
that the introduction of the institution was at least premature,
but before adopting this sweeping conclusion it will be well to
examine the phenomenon a little more closely in connection with
Russian criminal procedure as a whole.
In England the Bench is allowed very great latitude in fixing the
amount of punishment. The jury can therefore confine themselves to
the question of fact and leave to the judge the appreciation of
extenuating circumstances. In Russia the position of the jury is
different. The Russian criminal law fixes minutely the punishment
for each category of crimes, and leaves almost no latitude to the
judge. The jury know that if they give a verdict of guilty, the
prisoner will inevitably be punished according to the Code. Now
the Code, borrowed in great part from foreign legislation, is
founded on conceptions very different from those of the Russian
people, and in many cases it attaches heavy penalties to acts which
the ordinary Russian is wont to regard as mere peccadilloes, or
positively justifiable. Even in those matters in which the Code is
in harmony with the popular morality, there are many exceptional
cases in which summum jus is really summa injuria. Suppose, for
instance--as actually happened in a case which came under my
notice--that a fire breaks out in a village, and that the Village
Elder, driven out of patience by the apathy and laziness of some of
his young fellow-villagers, oversteps the limits of his authority
as defined by law, and accompanies his reproaches and exhortations
with a few lusty blows. Surely such a man is not guilty of a very
heinous crime--certainly he is not in the opinion of the peasantry--
and yet if he be prosecuted and convicted he inevitably falls into
the jaws of an article of the Code which condemns to transportation
for a long term of years.
In such cases what is the jury to do? In England they might safely
give a verdict of guilty, and leave the judge to take into
consideration all the extenuating circumstances; but in Russia they
cannot act in this way, for they know that the judge must condemn
the prisoner according to the Criminal Code. There remains,
therefore, but one issue out of the difficulty--a verdict of
acquittal; and Russian juries--to their honour be it said--
generally adopt this alternative. Thus the jury, in those cases in
which it is most severely condemned, provides a corrective for the
injustice of the criminal legislation. Occasionally, it is true,
they go a little too far in this direction and arrogate to
themselves a right of pardon, but cases of that kind are, I
believe, very rare. I know of only one well-authenticated
instance. The prisoner had been proved guilty of a serious crime,
but it happened to be the eve of a great religious festival, and
the jury thought that in pardoning the prisoner and giving a
verdict of acquittal they would be acting as good Christians!
The legislation regards, of course, this practice as an abuse, and
has tried to prevent it by concealing as far as possible from the
jury the punishment that awaits the accused if he be condemned.
For this purpose it forbids the counsel for the prisoner to inform
the jury what punishment is prescribed by the Code for the crime in
question. This ingenious device not only fails in its object, but
has sometimes a directly opposite effect. Not knowing what the
punishment will be, and fearing that it may be out of all
proportion to the crime, the jury sometimes acquit a criminal whom
they would condemn if they knew what punishment would be inflicted.
And when a jury is, as it were, entrapped, and finds that the
punishment is more severe than it supposed, it can take its revenge
in the succeeding cases. I know at least of one instance of this
kind. A jury convicted a prisoner of an offence which it regarded
as very trivial, but which in reality entailed, according to the
Code, seven years of penal servitude! So surprised and frightened
were the jurymen by this unexpected consequence of their verdict,
that they obstinately acquitted, in the face of the most convincing
evidence, all the other prisoners brought before them.
The most famous case of acquital when there was no conceivable
doubt as to the guilt of the accused was that of Vera Zasulitch,
who shot General Trepof, Prefect of St. Petersburg; but the
circumstances were so peculiar that they will hardly support any
general conclusion. I happened to be present, and watched the
proceedings closely. Vera Zasulitch, a young woman who had for
some time taken part in the revolutionary movement, heard that a
young revolutionist called Bogoliubof, imprisoned in St.
Petersburg, had been flogged by orders of General Trepof,* and
though she did not know the victim personally she determined to
avenge the indignity to which he had been subjected. With this
intention she appeared at the Prefecture, ostensibly for the
purpose of presenting a petition, and when she found herself in the
presence of the Prefect she fired a revolver at him, wounding him
seriously, but not mortally. At the trial the main facts were not
disputed, and yet the jury brought in a verdict of not guilty.
This unexpected result was due, I believe, partly to a desire to
make a little political demonstration, and partly to a strong
suspicion that the prison authorities, in carrying out the
Prefect's orders, had acted in summary fashion without observing
the tedious formalities prescribed by the law. Certainly one of
the prison officials, when under cross-examination, made on me, and
on the public generally, the impression that he was prevaricating
in order to shield his superiors.
* The reason alleged by General Trepof for giving these orders was
that, during a visit of inspection, Bogoliubof had behaved
disrespectfully towards him, and had thereby committed an
infraction of prison discipline, for which the law prescribes the
use of corporal punishment.
At the close of the proceedings, which were dexterously conducted
by Counsel in such a way that, as the Emperor is reported to have
said, it was not Vera Zasulitch but General Trepof who was being
tried, an eminent Russian journalist rushed up to me in a state of
intense excitement and said: "Is not this a great day for the cause
of political freedom in Russia?" I could not agree with him and I
ventured to predict that neither of us would ever again see a
political case tried publicly by jury in an ordinary court. The
prediction has proved true. Since that time political offenders
have been tried by special tribunals without a jury or dealt with
"by administrative procedure," that is to say, inquisitorially,
without any regular trial.
The defects, real and supposed, of the present system are commonly
attributed to the predominance of the peasant element in the
juries; and this opinion, founded on a priori reasoning, seems to
many too evident to require verification. The peasantry are in
many respects the most ignorant class, and therefore, it is
assumed, they are least capable of weighing conflicting evidence.
Plain and conclusive as this reasoning seems, it is in my opinion
erroneous. The peasants have, indeed, little education, but they
have a large fund of plain common-sense; and experience proves--so
at least I have been informed by many judges and Public
Prosecutors--that, as a general rule, a peasant jury is more to be
relied on than a jury drawn from the educated classes. It must be
admitted, however, that a peasant jury has certain peculiarities,
and it is not a little interesting to observe what those
peculiarities are.
In the first place, a jury composed of peasants generally acts in a
somewhat patriarchal fashion, and does not always confine its
attention to the evidence and the arguments adduced at the trial.
The members form their judgment as men do in the affairs of
ordinary life, and are sure to be greatly influenced by any jurors
who happen to be personally acquainted with the prisoner. If
several of the jurors know him to be a bad character, he has little
chance of being acquitted, even though the chain of evidence
against him should not be quite perfect. Peasants cannot
understand why a notorious scoundrel should be allowed to escape
because a little link in the evidence is wanting, or because some
little judicial formality has not been duly observed. Indeed,
their ideas of criminal procedure in general are extremely
primitive. The Communal method of dealing with malefactors is best
in accordance with their conceptions of well-regulated society.
The Mir may, by a Communal decree and without a formal trial, have
any of its unruly members transported to Siberia! This summary,
informal mode of procedure seems to the peasants very satisfactory.
They are at a loss to understand how a notorious culprit is allowed
to "buy" an advocate to defend him, and are very insensible to the
bought advocate's eloquence. To many of them, if I may trust to
conversations which I have casually overheard in and around the
courts, "buying an advocate" seems to be very much the same kind of
operation as bribing a judge.
In the second place, the peasants, when acting as jurors, are very
severe with regard to crimes against property. In this they are
instigated by the simple instinct of self-defence. They are, in
fact, continually at the mercy of thieves and malefactors. They
live in wooden houses easily set on fire; their stables might be
broken into by a child; at night the village is guarded merely by
an old man, who cannot be in more than one place at a time, and in
the one place he is apt to go to sleep; a police officer is rarely
seen, except when a crime has actually been committed. A few
clever horse-stealers may ruin many families, and a fire-raiser, in
his desire to avenge himself on an enemy, may reduce a whole
village to destitution. These and similar considerations tend to
make the peasants very severe against theft, robbery, and arson;
and a Public Prosecutor who desires to obtain a conviction against
a man charged with one of these crimes endeavours to have a jury in
which the peasant class is largely represented.
With regard to fraud in its various forms, the peasants are much
more lenient, probably because the line of demarcation between
honest and dishonest dealing in commercial affairs is not very
clearly drawn in their minds. Many, for instance, are convinced
that trade cannot be successfully carried on without a little
clever cheating; and hence cheating is regarded as a venial
offence. If the money fraudulently acquired be restored to the
owner, the crime is supposed to be completely condoned. Thus when
a Volost Elder appropriates the public money, and succeeds in
repaying it before the case comes on for trial, he is invariably
acquitted--and sometimes even re-elected!
An equal leniency is generally shown by peasants towards crimes
against the person, such as assaults, cruelty, and the like. This
fact is easily explained. Refined sensitiveness and a keen
sympathy with physical suffering are the result of a certain amount
of material well-being, together with a certain degree of
intellectual and moral culture, and neither of these is yet
possessed by the Russian peasantry. Any one who has had
opportunities of frequently observing the peasants must have been
often astonished by their indifference to suffering, both in their
own persons and in the person of others. In a drunken brawl heads
may be broken and wounds inflicted without any interference on the
part of the spectators. If no fatal consequences ensue, the
peasant does not think it necessary that official notice should be
taken of the incident, and certainly does not consider that any of
the combatants should be transported to Siberia. Slight wounds
heal of their own accord without any serious loss to the sufferer,
and therefore the man who inflicts them is not to be put on the
same level as the criminal who reduces a family to beggary. This
reasoning may, perhaps, shock people of sensitive nerves, but it
undeniably contains a certain amount of plain, homely wisdom.
Of all kinds of cruelty, that which is perhaps most revolting to
civilised mankind is the cruelty of the husband towards his wife;
but to this crime the Russian peasant shows especial leniency. He
is still influenced by the old conceptions of the husband's rights,
and by that low estimate of the weaker sex which finds expression
in many popular proverbs.
The peculiar moral conceptions reflected in these facts are
evidently the result of external conditions, and not of any
recondite ethnographical peculiarities, for they are not found
among the merchants, who are nearly all of peasant origin. On the
contrary, the merchants are more severe with regard to crimes
against the person than with regard to crimes against property.
The explanation of this is simple. The merchant has means of
protecting his property, and if he should happen to suffer by
theft, his fortune is not likely to be seriously affected by it.
On the other hand, he has a certain sensitiveness with regard to
such crimes as assault; for though he has commonly not much more
intellectual and moral culture than the peasant, he is accustomed
to comfort and material well-being, which naturally develop
sensitiveness regarding physical pain.
Towards fraud the merchants are quite as lenient as the peasantry.
This may, perhaps, seem strange, for fraudulent practices are sure
in the long run to undermine trade. The Russian merchants,
however, have not yet arrived at this conception, and can point to
many of the richest members of their class as a proof that
fraudulent practices often create enormous fortunes. Long ago
Samuel Butler justly remarked that we damn the sins we have no mind
to.
As the external conditions have little or no influence on the
religious conceptions of the merchants and the peasantry, the two
classes are equally severe with regard to those acts which are
regarded as crimes against the Deity. Hence acquittals in cases of
sacrilege, blasphemy, and the like never occur unless the jury is
in part composed of educated men.
In their decisions, as in their ordinary modes of thought, the
jurors drawn from the educated classes are little, if at all,
affected by theological conceptions, but they are sometimes
influenced in a not less unfortunate way by conceptions of a
different order. It may happen, for instance, that a juror who had
passed through one of the higher educational establishments has his
own peculiar theory about the value of evidence, or he is
profoundly impressed with the idea that it is better that a
thousand guilty men should escape than that one innocent man should
be punished, or he is imbued with sentimental pseudo-philanthropy,
or he is convinced that punishments are useless because they
neither cure the delinquent nor deter others from crime; in a word,
he may have in some way or other lost his mental balance in that
moral chaos through which Russia is at present passing. In
England, France, or Germany such an individual would have little
influence on his fellow-jurymen, for in these countries there are
very few people who allow new paradoxical ideas to overturn their
traditional notions and obscure their common-sense; but in Russia,
where even the elementary moral conceptions are singularly unstable
and pliable, a man of this type may succeed in leading a jury.
More than once I have heard men boast of having induced their
fellow-jurymen to acquit every prisoner brought before them, not
because they believed the prisoners to be innocent or the evidence
to be insufficient, but because all punishments are useless and
barbarous.
One word in conclusion regarding the independence and political
significance of the new courts. When the question of judicial
reform was first publicly raised many people hoped that the new
courts would receive complete autonomy and real independence, and
would thus form a foundation for political liberty. These hopes,
like so many illusions of that strange time, have not been
realised. A large measure of autonomy and independence was indeed
granted in theory. The law laid down the principle that no judge
could be removed unless convicted of a definite crime, and that the
courts should present candidates for all the vacant places on the
Bench; but these and similar rights have little practical
significance. If the Minister cannot depose a judge, he can
deprive him of all possibility of receiving promotion, and he can
easily force him in an indirect way to send in his resignation; and
if the courts have still the right to present candidates for vacant
places, the Minister has also this right, and can, of course,
always secure the nomination of his own candidate. By the
influence of that centripetal force which exists in all centralised
bureaucracies, the Procureurs have become more important personages
than the Presidents of the courts.
From the political point of view the question of the independence
of the Courts has not yet acquired much practical importance,
because the Government can always have political offenders tried by
a special tribunal or can send them to Siberia for an indefinite
term of years without regular trial by the "administrative
procedure" to which I have above referred.
CHAPTER XXXIV
REVOLUTIONARY NIHILISM AND THE REACTION
The Reform-enthusiasm Becomes Unpractical and Culminates in
Nihilism--Nihilism, the Distorted Reflection of Academic Western
Socialism--Russia Well Prepared for Reception of Ultra-Socialist
Virus--Social Reorganisation According to Latest Results of
Science--Positivist Theory--Leniency of Press-censure--Chief
Representatives of New Movement--Government Becomes Alarmed--
Repressive Measures--Reaction in the Public--The Term Nihilist
Invented--The Nihilist and His Theory--Further Repressive Measures--
Attitude of Landed Proprietors--Foundation of a Liberal Party--
Liberalism Checked by Polish Insurrection--Practical Reform
Continued--An Attempt at Regicide Forms a Turning-point of
Government's Policy--Change in Educational System--Decline of
Nihilism.
The rapidly increasing enthusiasm for reform did not confine itself
to practical measures such as the emancipation of the serfs, the
creation of local self-government, and the thorough reorganisation
of the law-courts and legal procedure. In the younger section of
the educated classes, and especially among the students of the
universities and technical colleges, it produced a feverish
intellectual excitement and wild aspirations which culminated in
what is commonly known as Nihilism.
In a preceding chapter I pointed out that during the last two
centuries all the important intellectual movements in Western
Europe have been reflected in Russia, and that these reflections
have generally been what may fairly be termed exaggerated and
distorted reproductions of the originals.* Roughly speaking, the
Nihilist movement in Russia may be described as the exaggerated,
distorted reflection of the earlier Socialist movements of the
West; but it has local peculiarities and local colouring which
deserve attention.
* See Chapter XXVI.
The Russian educated classes had been well prepared by their past
history for the reception and rapid development of the Socialist
virus. For a century and a half the country had been subjected to
a series of drastic changes, administrative and social, by the
energetic action of the Autocratic Power, with little spontaneous
co-operation on the part of the people. In a nation with such a
history, Socialistic ideas naturally found favour, because all
Socialist systems until quite recent times were founded on the
assumption that political and social progress must be the result
not of slow natural development, but rather of philosophic
speculation, legislative wisdom, and administrative energy.
This assumption lay at the bottom of the reform enthusiasm in St.
Petersburg at the commencement of Alexander II.'s reign. Russia
might be radically transformed, it was thought, politically and
socially, according to abstract scientific principles, in the space
of a few years, and be thereby raised to the level of West-European
civilisation, or even higher. The older nations had for centuries
groped in darkness, or stumbled along in the faint light of
practical experience, and consequently their progress had been slow
and uncertain. For Russia there was no necessity to follow such
devious, unexplored paths. She ought to profit by the experience
of her elder sisters, and avoid the errors into which they had
fallen. Nor was it difficult to ascertain what these errors were,
because they had been discovered, examined and explained by the
most eminent thinkers of France and England, and efficient remedies
had been prescribed. Russian reformers had merely to study and
apply the conclusions at which these eminent authorities had
arrived, and their task would be greatly facilitated by the fact
that they could operate on virgin soil, untrammelled by the feudal
traditions, religious superstitions, metaphysical conceptions,
romantic illusions, aristocratic prejudices, and similar obstacles
to social and political progress which existed in Western Europe.
Such was the extraordinary intellectual atmosphere in which the
Russian educated classes lived during the early years of the
sixties. On the "men with aspirations," who had longed in vain for
more light and more public activity under the obscurantist,
repressive regime of the preceding reign, it had an intoxicating
effect. The more excitable and sanguine amongst them now believed
seriously that they had discovered a convenient short-cut to
national prosperity, and that for Russia a grandiose social and
political millennium was at hand.*
* I was not myself in St. Petersburg at that period, but on
arriving a few years afterwards I became intimately acquainted with
men and women who had lived through it, and who still retained much
of their early enthusiasm.
In these circumstances it is not surprising that one of the most
prominent characteristics of the time was a boundless, child-like
faith in the so-called "latest results of science." Infallible
science was supposed to have found the solution of all political
and social problems. What a reformer had to do--and who was not a
would-be reformer in those days?--was merely to study the best
authorities. Their works had been long rigidly excluded by the
Press censure, but now that it was possible to obtain them, they
were read with avidity. Chief among the new, infallible prophets
whose works were profoundly venerated was Auguste Comte, the
inventor of Positivism. In his classification of the sciences the
crowning of the edifice was sociology, which taught how to organise
human society on scientific principles. Russia had merely to adopt
the principles laid down and expounded at great length in the Cours
de Philosophie Positive. There Comte explained that humanity had
to pass through three stages of intellectual development--the
religious, the metaphysical, and the positive--and that the most
advanced nations, after spending centuries in the two first, were
entering on the third. Russia must endeavour, therefore, to get
into the positive stage as quickly as possible, and there was
reason to believe that, in consequence of certain ethnographical
and historical peculiarities, she could make the transition more
quickly than other nations. After Comte's works, the book which
found, for a time, most favour was Buckle's "History of
Civilisation," which seemed to reduce history and progress to a
matter of statistics, and which laid down the principle that
progress is always in the inverse ratio of the influence of
theological conceptions. This principle was regarded as of great
practical importance, and the conclusion drawn from it was that
rapid national progress was certain if only the influence of
religion and theology could be destroyed. Very popular, too, was
John Stuart Mill, because he was "imbued with enthusiasm for
humanity and female emancipation"; and in his tract on
Utilitarianism he showed that morality was simply the crystallised
experience of many generations as to what was most conducive to the
greatest good of the greatest number. The minor prophets of the
time, among whom Buchner occupied a prominent place, are too
numerous to mention.
Strange to say, the newest and most advanced doctrines appeared
regularly, under a very thin and transparent veil, in the St.
Petersburg daily Press, and especially in the thick monthly
magazines, which were as big as, or bigger than, our venerable
quarterlies. The art of writing and reading "between the lines,"
not altogether unknown under the Draconian regime of Nicholas I.,
was now developed to such a marvellous extent that almost any thing
could be written clearly enough to be understood by the initiated
without calling for the thunderbolts of the Press censors, which
was now only intermittently severe. Indeed, the Press censors
themselves were sometimes carried away by the reform enthusiasm.
One of them long afterwards related to me that during "the mad
time," as he called it, in the course of a single year he had
received from his superiors no less than seventeen reprimands for
passing objectionable articles without remark.
The movement found its warmest partisans among the students and
young literary men, but not a few grey-beards were to be found
among the youthful apostles. All who read the periodical
literature became more or less imbued with the new spirit; but it
must be presumed that many of those who discoursed most eloquently
had no clear idea of what they were talking about; for even at a
later date, when the novices had had time to acquaint themselves
with the doctrines they professed, I often encountered the most
astounding ignorance. Let me give one instance by way of
illustration:
A young gentleman who was in the habit of talking glibly about the
necessity of scientifically reorganising human society, declared to
me one day that not only sociology, but also biology should be
taken into consideration. Confessing my complete ignorance of the
latter science, I requested him to enlighten me by giving me an
instance of a biological principle which could be applied to social
regeneration. He looked confused, and tried to ride out of the
difficulty on vague general phrases; but I persistently kept him to
the point, and maliciously suggested that as an alternative he
might cite to me a biological principle which could NOT be used for
such a purpose. Again he failed, and it became evident to all
present that of biology, about which he talked so often, he knew
absolutely nothing but the name! After this I frequently employed
the same pseudo-Socratic method of discussion, and very often with
a similar result. Not one in fifty, perhaps, ever attempted to
reduce the current hazy conceptions to a concrete form. The
enthusiasm was not the less intense, however, on that account.
At first the partisans of the movement seemed desirous of
assisting, rather than of opposing or undermining the Government,
and so long as they merely talked academically about scientific
principles and similar vague entities, the Government felt no
necessity for energetic interference; but as early as 1861 symptoms
of a change in the character of the movement became apparent. A
secret society of officers organised a small printing-press in the
building of the Headquarters Staff and issued clandestinely three
numbers of a periodical called the Velikoruss (Great Russian),
which advocated administrative reform, the convocation of a
constituent assembly, and the emancipation of Poland from Russian
rule. A few months later (April, 1862) a seditious proclamation
appeared, professing to emanate from a central revolutionary
committee, and declaring that the Romanoffs must expiate with their
blood the misery of the people.
These symptoms of an underground revolutionary agitation caused
alarm in the official world, and repressive measures were at once
adopted. Sunday schools for the working classes, reading-rooms,
students' clubs, and similar institutions which might be used for
purposes of revolutionary propaganda were closed; several trials
for political offences took place; the most popular of the monthly
periodicals (Sovremennik) was suspended, and its editor,
Tchernishevski, arrested. There was nothing to show that
Tchernishevski was implicated in any treasonable designs, but he
was undoubtedly the leader of a group of youthful writers whose
aspirations went far beyond the intentions of the Government, and
it was thought desirable to counteract his influence by shutting
him up in prison. Here he wrote and published, with the permission
of the authorities and the imprimatur of the Press censure, a novel
called "Shto delat'?" (" What is to be Done?"), which was regarded
at first as a most harmless production, but which is now considered
one of the most influential and baneful works in the whole range of
Nihilist literature. As a novel it had no pretensions to artistic
merit, and in ordinary times it would have attracted little or no
attention, but it put into concrete shape many of the vague
Socialist and Communist notions that were at the moment floating
about in the intellectual atmosphere, and it came to be looked upon
by the young enthusiasts as a sort of informal manifesto of their
new-born faith. It was divided into two parts; in the first was
described a group of students living according to the new ideas in
open defiance of traditional conventionalities, and in the second
was depicted a village organised on the communistic principles
recommended by Fourier. The first was supposed to represent the
dawn of the new era; the second, the goal to be ultimately
attained. When the authorities discovered the mistake they had
committed in allowing the book to be published, it was at once
confiscated and withdrawn from circulation, whilst the author,
after being tried by the Senate, was exiled to Northeastern Siberia
and kept there for nearly twenty years.*
* Tchernishevski was a man of encyclopaedic knowledge and specially
conversant with political economy. According to the testimony of
those who knew him intimately, he was one of the ablest and most
sympathetic men of his generation. During his exile a bold attempt
was made to rescue him, and very nearly succeeded. A daring youth,
disguised as an officer of gendarmes and provided with forged
official papers, reached the place where he was confined and
procured his release, but the officer in charge had vague
suspicions, and insisted on the two travellers being escorted to
the next post-station by a couple of Cossacks. The rescuer tried
to get rid of the escort by means of his revolver, but he failed in
the attempt, and the fugitives were arrested. In 1883
Tchernishevski was transferred to the milder climate of Astrakhan,
and in 1889 he was allowed to return to his native town, Saratof,
where he died a few months afterwards.
With the arrest and exile of Tchernishevski the young would-be
reformers were constrained to recognise that they had no chance of
carrying the Government with them in their endeavours to realise
their patriotic aspirations. Police supervision over the young
generation was increased, and all kinds of association, whether for
mutual instruction, mutual aid, or any other purpose, were
discouraged or positively forbidden. And it was not merely in the
mind of the police that suspicion was aroused. In the opinion of
the great majority of moderate, respectable people the young
enthusiasts were becoming discredited. The violently seditious
proclamations with which they were supposed to sympathise, and a
series of destructive fires in St. Petersburg, erroneously
attributed to them, frightened timid Liberals and gave the
Reactionaries, who had hitherto remained silent, an opportunity of
preaching their doctrines with telling effect. The celebrated
novelist, Turgeneif, long the idol of the young generation, had
inadvertently in "Fathers and Children" invented the term Nihilist,
and it at once came to be applied as an opprobrious epithet,
notwithstanding the efforts of Pissaref, a popular writer of
remarkable talent, to prove to the public that it ought to be
regarded as a term of honour.
Pissaref's attempt at rehabilitation made no impression outside of
his own small circle. According to popular opinion the Nihilists
were a band of fanatical young men and women, mostly medical
students, who had determined to turn the world upside down and to
introduce a new kind of social order, founded on the most advanced
principles of social equality and Communism. As a first step
towards the great transformation they had reversed the traditional
order of things in the matter of coiffure: the males allowed their
hair to grow long, and the female adepts cut their hair short,
adding occasionally the additional badge of blue spectacles. Their
unkempt appearance naturally shocked the aesthetic feelings of
ordinary people, but to this they were indifferent. They had
raised themselves above the level of popular notions, took no
account of so-called public opinion, gloried in Bohemianism,
despised Philistine respectability, and rather liked to scandalise
old-fashioned people imbued with antiquated prejudices.
This was the ridiculous side of the movement, but underneath the
absurdities there was something serious. These young men and
women, who were themselves terribly in earnest, were systematically
hostile not only to accepted conventionalities in the matter of
dress, but to all manner of shams, hypocrisy, and cant in the broad
Carlylean sense of those terms. To the "beautiful souls" of the
older generation, who had habitually, in conversation and
literature, shed pathetic tears over the defects of Russian social
and political organisation without ever moving a finger to correct
them--especially the landed proprietors who talked and wrote about
civilisation, culture, and justice while living comfortably on the
revenues provided for them by their unfortunate serfs--these had
the strongest aversion; and this naturally led them to condemn in
strong language the worship of aesthetic culture. But here again
they fell into exaggeration. Professing extreme utilitarianism,
they explained that the humble shoemaker who practises his craft
diligently is, in the true sense, a greater man than a Shakespeare,
or a Goethe, because humanity has more need of shoes than of dramas
and poetry.
Such silly paradoxes provoked, of course, merely a smile of
compassion; what alarmed the sensible, respectable "Philistine" was
the method of cleansing the Augean stable recommended by these
enthusiasts. Having discovered in the course of their desultory
reading that most of the ills that flesh is heir to proceed
directly or indirectly from uncontrolled sexual passion and the
lust of gain, they proposed to seal hermetically these two great
sources of crime and misery by abolishing the old-fashioned
institutions of marriage and private property. When society, they
argued, should be so organised that all the healthy instincts of
human nature could find complete and untrammelled satisfaction,
there would be no motive or inducement for committing crimes or
misdemeanours. For thousands of years humanity had been sailing on
a wrong tack. The great law-givers of the world, religious and
civil, in their ignorance of physical science and positivist
methods, had created institutions, commonly known as law and
morality, which were utterly unfitted to human nature, and then the
magistrate and the moralist had endeavoured to compel or persuade
men and women to conform to them, but their efforts had failed most
signally. In vain the police had threatened and punished and the
priests had preached and admonished. Human nature had
systematically and obstinately rebelled, and still rebels, against
the unnatural constraint. It is time, therefore, to try a new
system. Instead of continuing, as has been done for thousands of
years, to force men and women, as it were, into badly fitting,
unelastic clothes which cause intense discomfort and prevent all
healthy muscular action, why not adapt the costume to the anatomy
and physiology of the human frame? Then the clothes will no longer
be rent, and those who wear them will be contented and happy.
Unfortunately for the progress of humanity there are serious
obstacles in the way of this radical change of system. The absurd,
antiquated and pernicious institutions and customs are supported by
abstruse metaphysical reasons and enshrined in mystical romantic
sentiment, and in this way they may still be preserved for
generations unless the axe be laid to the root of the tree. Now is
the critical moment. Russia must be made to rise at once from the
metaphysical to the positivist stage of intellectual development;
metaphysical reasoning and romantic sentiment must be rigorously
discarded; and everything must be brought to the touchstone of
naked practical utility.
One might naturally suppose that men holding such opinions must be
materialists of the grossest type--and, indeed, many of them
gloried in the name of materialist and atheist--but such an
inference would be erroneous. While denouncing metaphysics, they
were themselves metaphysicians in so far as they were constantly
juggling with abstract conceptions, and letting themselves be
guided in their walk and conversation by a priori deductions; while
ridiculing romanticism, they had romantic sentiment enough to make
them sacrifice their time, their property, and sometimes even their
life, to the attainment of an unrealisable ideal; and while
congratulating themselves on having passed from the religious to
the positivist stage of intellectual development, they frequently
showed themselves animated with the spirit of the early martyrs!
Rarely have the strange inconsistencies of human nature been so
strikingly exemplified as in these unpractical, anti-religious
fanatics. In dealing with them I might easily, without very great
exaggeration, produce a most amusing caricature, but I prefer
describing them as they really were. A few years after the period
here referred to I knew some of them intimately, and I must say
that, without at all sharing or sympathising with their opinions, I
could not help respecting them as honourable, upright, quixotic men
and women who had made great sacrifices for their convictions. One
of them whom I have specially in view at this moment suffered
patiently for years from the utter shipwreck of his generous
illusions, and when he could no longer hope to see the dawn of a
brighter day, he ended by committing suicide. Yet that man
believed himself to be a Realist, a Materialist, and a Utilitarian
of the purest water, and habitually professed a scathing contempt
for every form of romantic sentiment! In reality he was one of the
best and most sympathetic men I have ever known.
To return from this digression. So long as the subversive opinions
were veiled in abstract language they raised misgivings in only a
comparative small circle; but when school-teachers put them into a
form suited to the juvenile mind, they were apt to produce
startling effects. In a satirical novel of the time a little girl
is represented as coming to her mother and saying, "Little mamma!
Maria Ivan'na (our new school-mistress) says there is no God and no
Tsar, and that it is wrong to marry!" Whether such incidents
actually occurred in real life, as several friends assured me, I am
not prepared to say, but certainly people believed that they might
occur in their own families, and that was quite sufficient to
produce alarm even in the ranks of the Liberals, to say nothing of
the rapidly increasing army of the Reactionaries.
To illustrate the general uneasiness produced in St. Petersburg, I
may quote here a letter written in October, 1861, by a man who
occupied one of the highest positions in the Administration. As he
had the reputation of being an ultra-Liberal who sympathised
overmuch with Young Russia, we may assume that he did not take an
exceptionally alarmist view of the situation.
"You have not been long absent--merely a few months; but if you
returned now, you would be astonished by the progress which the
Opposition, one might say the Revolutionary Party, has already
made. The disorders in the university do not concern merely the
students. I see in the affair the beginning of serious dangers for
public tranquillity and the existing order of things. Young
people, without distinction of costume, uniform and origin, take
part in the street demonstrations. Besides the students of the
university, there are the students of other institutions, and a
mass of people who are students only in name. Among these last are
certain gentlemen in long beards and a number of revolutionnaires
in crinoline, who are of all the most fanatical. Blue collars--the
distinguishing mark of the students' uniform--have become the signe
de ralliement. Almost all the professors and many officers take
the part of the students. The newspaper critics openly defend
their colleagues. Mikhailof has been convicted of writing,
printing and circulating one of the most violent proclamations that
ever existed, under the heading, 'To the young generation!' Among
the students and the men of letters there is unquestionably an
organised conspiracy, which has perhaps leaders outside the
literary circle. . . . The police are powerless. They arrest any
one they can lay hands on. About eighty people have already been
sent to the fortress and examined, but all this leads to no
practical result, because the revolutionary ideas have taken
possession of all classes, all ages, all professions, and are
publicly expressed in the streets, in the barracks, and in the
Ministries. I believe the police itself is carried away by them!
What this will lead to, it is difficult to predict. I am very much
afraid of some bloody catastrophe. Even if it should not go to
such a length immediately, the position of the Government will he
extremely difficult. Its authority is shaken, and all are
convinced that it is powerless, stupid and incapable. On that
point there is the most perfect unanimity among all parties of all
colours, even the most opposite. The most desperate 'planter'*
agrees in that respect with the most desperate socialist.
Meanwhile those who have the direction of affairs do almost nothing
and have no plan or definite aim in view. At present the Emperor
is not in the Capital, and now, more than at any other time, there
is complete anarchy in the absence of the master of the house.
There is a great deal of bustle and talk, and all blame they know
not whom."**
* An epithet commonly applied, at the time of the Emancipation, to
the partisans of serfage and the defenders of the proprietors'
rights.
** I found this interesting letter (which might have been written
today) thirty years ago among the private papers of Nicholas
Milutin, who played a leading part as an official in the reforms of
the time. It was first published in an article on "Secret
Societies in Russia," which I contributed to the Fortnightly Review
of 1st August, 1877.
The expected revolution did not take place, but timid people had no
difficulty in perceiving signs of its approach. The Press
continued to disseminate, under a more or less disguised form,
ideas which were considered dangerous. The Kolokol, a Russian
revolutionary paper published in London by Herzen and strictly
prohibited by the Press-censure, found its way in large quantities
into the country, and, as is recorded in an earlier chapter, was
read by thousands, including the higher officials and the Emperor
himself, who found it regularly on his writing-table, laid there by
some unknown hand. In St. Petersburg the arrest of Tchernishevski
and the suspension of his magazine, The Contemporary, made the
writers a little more cautious in their mode of expression, but the
spirit of the articles remained unchanged. These energetic
intolerant leaders of public opinion were novi homines not
personally connected with the social strata in which moderate views
and retrograde tenderness had begun to prevail. Mostly sons of
priests or of petty officials, they belonged to a recently created
literary proletariat composed of young men with boundless
aspirations and meagre national resources, who earned a precarious
subsistence by journalism or by giving lessons in private families.
Living habitually in a world of theories and unrestrained by
practical acquaintance with public life, they were ready, from the
purest and most disinterested motives to destroy ruthlessly the
existing order of things in order to realise their crude notions of
social regeneration. Their heated imagination showed them in the
near future a New Russia, composed of independent federated
Communes, without any bureaucracy or any central power--a happy
land in which everybody virtuously and automatically fulfilled his
public and private duties, and in which the policeman and all other
embodiments of material constraint were wholly superfluous.
Governments are not easily converted to Utopian schemes of that
idyllic type, and it is not surprising that even a Government with
liberal humanitarian aspirations like that of Alexander II. should
have become alarmed and should have attempted to stem the current.
What is to be regretted is that the repressive measures adopted
were a little too Oriental in their character. Scores of young
students of both sexes--for the Nihilist army included a strong
female contingent--were secretly arrested and confined for months
in unwholesome prisons, and many of them were finally exiled,
without any regular trial, to distant provinces in European Russia
or to Siberia. Their exile, it is true, was not at all so terrible
as is commonly supposed, because political exiles are not usually
confined in prisons or compelled to labour in the mines, but are
obliged merely to reside at a given place under police supervision.
Still, such punishment was severe enough for educated young men and
women, especially when their lot was cast among a population
composed exclusively of peasants and small shop-keepers or of
Siberian aborigines, and when there were no means of satisfying the
most elementary intellectual wants. For those who had no private
resources the punishment was particularly severe, because the
Government granted merely a miserable monthly pittance, hardly
sufficient to purchase food of the coarsest kind, and there was
rarely an opportunity of adding to the meagre official allowance by
intellectual or manual labour. In all cases the treatment accorded
to the exiles wounded their sense of justice and increased the
existing discontent among their friends and acquaintances. Instead
of acting as a deterrent, the system produced a feeling of profound
indignation, and ultimately transformed not a few sentimental
dreamers into active conspirators.
At first there was no conspiracy or regularly organised secret
society and nothing of which the criminal law in Western Europe
could have taken cognisance. Students met in each other's rooms to
discuss prohibited books on political and social science, and
occasionally short essays on the subjects discussed were written in
a revolutionary spirit by members of the coterie. This was called
mutual instruction. Between the various coteries or groups there
were private personal relations, not only in the capital, but also
in the provinces, so that manuscripts and printed papers could be
transmitted from one group to another. From time to time the
police captured these academic disquisitions, and made raids on the
meetings of students who had come together merely for conversation
and discussion; and the fresh arrests caused by these incidents
increased the hostility to the Government.
In the letter above quoted it is said that the revolutionary ideas
had taken possession of all classes, all ages, and all professions.
This may have been true with regard to St. Petersburg, but it could
not have been said of the provinces. There the landed proprietors
were in a very different frame of mind. They had to struggle with
a multitude of urgent practical affairs which left them little time
for idyllic dreaming about an imaginary millennium. Their serfs
had been emancipated, and what remained to them of their estates
had to be reorganised on the basis of free labour. Into the semi-
chaotic state of things created by such far-reaching changes, legal
and economic, they did not wish to see any more confusion
introduced, and they did not at all feel that they could dispense
with the Central Government and the policeman. On the contrary,
the Central Government was urgently needed in order to obtain a
little ready money wherewith to reorganise the estates in the new
conditions, and the police organisation required to be strengthened
in order to compel the emancipated serfs to fulfil their legal
obligations. These men and their families were, therefore, much
more conservative than the class commonly designated "the young
generation," and they naturally sympathised with the "Philistines"
in St. Petersburg, who had been alarmed by the exaggerations of the
Nihilists.
Even the landed proprietors, however, were not so entirely free
from discontent and troublesome political aspirations as the
Government would have desired. They had not forgotten the
autocratic and bureaucratic way in which the Emancipation had been
prepared, and their indignation had been only partially appeased by
their being allowed to carry out the provisions of the law without
much bureaucratic interference. So much for the discontent. As
for the reform aspirations, they thought that, as a compensation
for having consented to the liberation of their serfs and for
having been expropriated from about a half of their land, they
ought to receive extensive political rights, and be admitted, like
the upper classes in Western Europe, to a fair share in the
government of the country. Unlike the fiery young Nihilists of St.
Petersburg, they did not want to abolish or paralyse the central
power; what they wanted was to co-operate with it loyally and to
give their advice on important questions by means of representative
institutions. They formed a constitutional group which exists
still at the present day, as we shall see in the sequel, but which
has never been allowed to develop into an organised political
party. Its aims were so moderate that its programme might have
been used as a convenient safety-valve for the explosive forces
which were steadily accumulating under the surface of Society, but
it never found favour in the official world. When some of its
leading members ventured to hint in the Press and in loyal
addresses to the Emperor that the Government would do well to
consult the country on important questions, their respectful
suggestions were coldly received or bluntly rejected by the
bureaucracy and the Autocratic Power.
The more the revolutionary and constitutional groups sought to
strengthen their position, the more pronounced became the
reactionary tendencies in the official world, and these received in
1863 an immense impetus from the Polish insurrection, with which
the Nihilists and even some of the Liberals sympathised.* That
ill-advised attempt on the part of the Poles to recover their
independence had a curious effect on Russian public opinion.
Alexander II., with the warm approval of the more Liberal section
of the educated classes, was in the course of creating for Poland
almost complete administrative autonomy under the viceroyalty of a
Russian Grand Duke; and the Emperor's brother Constantine was
preparing to carry out the scheme in a generous spirit. Soon it
became evident that what the Poles wanted was not administrative
autonomy, but political independence, with the frontiers which
existed before the first partition! Trusting to the expected
assistance of the Western Powers and the secret connivance of
Austria, they raised the standard of insurrection, and some
trifling successes were magnified by the pro-Polish Press into
important victories. As the news of the rising spread over Russia,
there was a moment of hesitation. Those who had been for some
years habitually extolling liberty and self-government as the
normal conditions of progress, who had been sympathising warmly
with every Liberal movement, whether at home or abroad, and who had
put forward a voluntary federation of independent Communes as the
ideal State organism, could not well frown on the political
aspirations of the Polish patriots. The Liberal sentiment of that
time was so extremely philosophical and cosmopolitan that it hardly
distinguished between Poles and Russians, and liberty was supposed
to be the birthright of every man and woman to whatever nationality
they might happen to belong. But underneath these beautiful
artificial clouds of cosmopolitan Liberal sentiment lay the volcano
of national patriotism, dormant for the moment, but by no means
extinct. Though the Russians are in some respects the most
cosmopolitan of European nations, they are at the same time capable
of indulging in violent outbursts of patriotic fanaticism; and
events in Warsaw brought into hostile contact these two
contradictory elements in the national character. The struggle was
only momentary. Ere long the patriotic feelings gained the upper
hand and crushed all cosmopolitan sympathy with political freedom.
The Moscow Gazette, the first of the papers to recover its mental
equilibrium, thundered against the pseudo-Liberal sentimentalism,
which would, if unchecked, necessarily lead to the dismemberment of
the Empire, and its editor, Katkoff, became for a time the most
influential private individual in the country. A few, indeed,
remained true to their convictions. Herzen, for instance, wrote in
the Kolokol a glowing panegyric on two Russian officers who had
refused to fire on the insurgents; and here and there a good
Orthodox Russian might be found who confessed that he was ashamed
of Muravieff's extreme severity in Lithuania. But such men were
few, and were commonly regarded as traitors, especially after the
ill-advised diplomatic intervention of the Western Powers. Even
Herzen, by his publicly expressed sympathy with the insurgents,
lost entirely his popularity and influence among his fellow-
countrymen. The great majority of the public thoroughly approved
of the severe energetic measures adopted by the Government, and
when the insurrection was suppressed, men who had a few months
previously spoken and written in magniloquent terms about
humanitarian Liberalism joined in the ovations offered to
Muravieff! At a great dinner given in his honour, that ruthless
administrator of the old Muscovite type, who had systematically
opposed the emancipation of the serfs and had never concealed his
contempt for the Liberal ideas in fashion, could ironically express
his satisfaction at seeing around him so many "new friends"!**
This revulsion of public feeling gave the Moscow Slavophils an
opportunity of again preaching their doctrine that the safety and
prosperity of Russia were to be found, not in the Liberalism and
Constitutionalism of Western Europe, but in patriarchal autocracy,
Eastern Orthodoxy, and other peculiarities of Russian nationality.
Thus the reactionary tendencies gained ground; but Alexander II.,
while causing all political agitation to be repressed, did not at
once abandon his policy of introducing radical reforms by means of
the Autocratic Power. On the contrary, he gave orders that the
preparatory work for creating local self-government and
reorganising the Law Courts should be pushed on energetically. The
important laws for the establishment of the Zemstvo and for the
great judicial reforms, which I have described in previous
chapters, both date from the year 1864.
* The students of the St. Petersburg University scandalised their
more patriotic fellow-countrymen by making a pro-Polish
demonstration.
** In fairness to Count Muravieff I must say that he was not quite
so black as he was painted in the Polish and West-European Press.
He left an interesting autobiographical fragment relating to the
history of this time, but it is not likely to be printed for some
years. As an historical document it is valuable, but must be used
with caution by the future historian. A copy of it was for some
time in my possession, but I was bound by a promise not to make
extracts.
These and other reforms of a less important kind made no impression
on the young irreconcilables. A small group of them, under the
leadership of a certain Ishutin, formed in Moscow a small secret
society, and conceived the design of assassinating the Emperor, in
the hope that his son and successor, who was erroneously supposed
to be imbued with ultra-Liberal ideas, might continue the work
which his father had begun and had not the courage to complete. In
April, 1866, the attempt on the life of the Emperor was made by a
youth called Karakozof as his Majesty was leaving a public garden
in St. Petersburg, but the bullet happily missed its mark, and the
culprit was executed.
This incident formed a turning-point in the policy of the
Government. Alexander II. began to fear that he had gone too far,
or, at least, too quickly, in his policy of radical reform. An
Imperial rescript announced that law, property, and religion were
in danger, and that the Government would lean on the Noblesse and
other conservative elements of Society. The two periodicals which
advocated the most advanced views (Sovremennik and Russkoye Slovo)
were suppressed permanently, and precautions were taken to prevent
the annual assemblies of the Zemstvo from giving public expression
to the aspirations of the moderate Liberals.
A secret official inquiry showed that the revolutionary agitation
proceeded in all cases from young men who were studying, or had
recently studied, in the universities, the seminaries, or the
technical schools, such as the Medical Academy and the Agricultural
Institute. Plainly, therefore, the system of education was at
fault. The semi-military system of the time of Nicholas had been
supplanted by one in which discipline was reduced to a minimum and
the study of natural science formed a prominent element. Here it
was thought, lay the chief root of the evil. Englishmen may have
some difficulty in imagining a possible connection between natural
science and revolutionary agitation. To them the two things must
seem wide as the poles asunder. Surely mathematics, chemistry,
physiology, and similar subjects have nothing to do with politics.
When a young Englishman takes to studying any branch of natural
science he gets up his subject by means of lectures, text-books,
and museums or laboratories, and when he has mastered it he
probably puts his knowledge to some practical use. In Russia it is
otherwise. Few students confine themselves to their speciality.
The majority of them dislike the laborious work of mastering dry
details, and, with the presumption which is often found in
conjunction with youth and a smattering of knowledge, they aspire
to become social reformers and imagine themselves specially
qualified for such activity.
But what, it may he asked, has social reform to do with natural
science? I have already indicated the connection in the Russian
mind. Though very few of the students of that time had ever read
the voluminous works of Auguste Comte, they were all more or less
imbued with the spirit of the Positive Philosophy, in which all the
sciences are subsidiary to sociology, and social reorganisation is
the ultimate object of scientific research. The imaginative
Positivist can see with prophetic eye humanity reorganised on
strictly scientific principles. Cool-headed people who have had a
little experience of the world, if they ever indulge in such
delightful dreams, recognise clearly that this ultimate goal of
human intellectual activity, if it is ever to be reached, is still
a long way off in the misty distance of the future; but the would-
be social reformers among the Russian students of the sixties were
too young, too inexperienced, and too presumptuously self-confident
to recognise this plain, simple truth. They felt that too much
valuable time had been already lost, and they were madly impatient
to begin the great work without further delay. As soon as they had
acquired a smattering of chemistry, physiology, and biology they
imagined themselves capable of reorganising human society from top
to bottom, and when they had acquired this conviction they were of
course unfitted for the patient, plodding study of details.
To remedy these evils, Count Dimitri Tolstoy, who was regarded as a
pillar of Conservatism, was appointed Minister of Public
Instruction, with the mission of protecting the young generation
against pernicious ideas, and eradicating from the schools,
colleges, and universities all revolutionary tendencies. He
determined to introduce more discipline into all the educational
establishments and to supplant to a certain extent the superficial
study of natural science by the thorough study of the classics--
that is to say, Latin and Greek. This scheme, which became known
before it was actually put into execution, produced a storm of
discontent in the young generation. Discipline at that time was
regarded as an antiquated and useless remnant of patriarchal
tyranny, and young men who were impatient to take part in social
reorganisation resented being treated as naughty schoolboys. To
them it seemed that the Latin grammar was an ingenious instrument
for stultifying youthful intelligence, destroying intellectual
development, and checking political progress. Ingenious
speculations about the possible organisation of the working classes
and grandiose views of the future of humanity are so much more
interesting and agreeable than the rules of Latin syntax and the
Greek irregular verbs!
Count Tolstoy could congratulate himself on the efficacy of his
administration, for from the time of his appointment there was a
lull in the political excitement. During three or four years there
was only one political trial, and that an insignificant one;
whereas there had been twenty between 1861 and 1864, and all more
or less important. I am not at all sure, however, that the
educational reform which created much momentary irritation and
discontent had anything to do with the improvement in the
situation. In any case, there were other and more potent causes at
work. The excitement was too intense to be long-lived, and the
fashionable theories too fanciful to stand the wear and tear of
everyday life. They evaporated, therefore, with amazing rapidity
when the leaders of the movement had disappeared--Tchernishevski
and others by exile, and Dobrolubof and Pissaref by death--and when
among the less prominent representatives of the younger generation
many succumbed to the sobering influences of time and experience or
drifted into lucrative professions. Besides this, the reactionary
currents were making themselves felt, especially since the attempt
on the life of the Emperor. So long as these had been confined to
the official world they had not much affected the literature,
except externally through the Press-censure, but when they
permeated the reading public their influence was much stronger.
Whatever the cause, there is no doubt that, in the last years of
the sixties, there was a subsidence of excitement and enthusiasm
and the peculiar intellectual phenomenon which had been nicknamed
Nihilism was supposed to be a thing of the past. In reality the
movement of which Nihilism was a prominent manifestation had merely
lost something of its academic character and was entering on a new
stage of development.
CHAPTER XXXV
SOCIALIST PROPAGANDA, REVOLUTIONARY AGITATION, AND TERRORISM
Closer Relations with Western Socialism--Attempts to Influence the
Masses--Bakunin and Lavroff--"Going in among the People"--The
Missionaries of Revolutionary Socialism--Distinction between
Propaganda and Agitation--Revolutionary Pamphlets for the Common
People--Aims and Motives of the Propagandists--Failure of
Propaganda--Energetic Repression--Fruitless Attempts at Agitation--
Proposal to Combine with Liberals--Genesis of Terrorism--My
Personal Relations with the Revolutionists--Shadowers and Shadowed--
A Series of Terrorist Crimes--A Revolutionist Congress--
Unsuccessful Attempts to Assassinate the Tsar--Ineffectual Attempt
at Conciliation by Loris Melikof--Assassination of Alexander II.--
The Executive Committee Shows Itself Unpractical--Widespread
Indignation and Severe Repression--Temporary Collapse of the
Revolutionary Movement--A New Revolutionary Movement in Sight.
Count Tolstoy's educational reform had one effect which was not
anticipated: it brought the revolutionists into closer contact with
Western Socialism. Many students, finding their position in Russia
uncomfortable, determined to go abroad and continue their studies
in foreign universities, where they would be free from the
inconveniences of police supervision and Press-censure. Those of
the female sex had an additional motive to emigrate, because they
could not complete their studies in Russia, but they had more
difficulty in carrying out their intention, because parents
naturally disliked the idea of their daughters going abroad to lead
a Bohemian life, and they very often obstinately refused to give
their consent. In such cases the persistent daughter found herself
in a dilemma. Though she might run away from her family and
possibly earn her own living, she could not cross the frontier
without a passport, and without the parental sanction a passport
could not be obtained. Of course she might marry and get the
consent of her husband, but most of the young ladies objected to
the trammels of matrimony. Occasionally the problem was solved by
means of a fictitious marriage, and when a young man could not be
found to co-operate voluntarily in the arrangement, the Terrorist
methods, which the revolutionists adopted a few years later for
other purposes, might be employed. I have heard of at least one
case in which an ardent female devotee of medical science
threatened to shoot a student who was going abroad if he did not
submit to the matrimonial ceremony and allow her to accompany him
to the frontier as his official wife!
Strange as this story may seem, it contains nothing inherently
improbable. At that time the energetic young ladies of the
Nihilist school were not to be diverted from their purpose by
trifling obstacles. We shall meet some of them hereafter,
displaying great courage and tenacity in revolutionary activity.
One of them, for example, attempted to murder the Prefect of St.
Petersburg; and another, a young person of considerable refinement
and great personal charm, gave the signal for the assassination of
Alexander II. and expiated her crime on the scaffold without the
least sign of repentance.
Most of the studious emigres of both sexes went to Zurich, where
female students were admitted to the medical classes. Here they
made the acquaintance of noted Socialists from various countries
who had settled in Switzerland, and being in search of panaceas for
social regeneration, they naturally fell under their influence, at
the same time they read with avidity the works of Proudhon,
Lassalle, Buchner, Marx, Flerovski, Pfeiffer, and other writers of
"advanced opinions."
Among the apostles of socialism living at that time in Switzerland
they found a sympathetic fellow-countryman in the famous Anarchist,
Bakunin, who had succeeded in escaping from Siberia. His ideal was
the immediate overthrow of all existing Governments, the
destruction of all administrative organisation, the abolition of
all bourgeois institutions, and the establishment of an entirely
new order of things on the basis of a free federation of productive
Communes, in which all the land should be distributed among those
capable of tilling it and the instruments of production confided to
co-operative associations. Efforts to obtain mere political
reforms, even of the most radical type, were regarded by him with
contempt as miserable palliatives, which could be of no real,
permanent benefit to the masses, and might be positively injurious
by prolonging the present era of bourgeois domination.
For the dissemination of these principles a special organ called
The Cause of the People (Narodnoye Dyelo) was founded in Geneva in
1868 and was smuggled across the Russian frontier in considerable
quantities. It aimed at drawing away the young generation from
Academic Nihilism to more practical revolutionary activity, but it
evidently remained to some extent under the old influences, for it
indulged occasionally in very abstract philosophical disquisitions.
In its first number, for example, it published a programme in which
the editors thought it necessary to declare that they were
materialists and atheists, because the belief in God and a future
life, as well as every other kind of idealism, demoralises the
people, inspiring it with mutually contradictory aspirations, and
thereby depriving it of the energy necessary for the conquest of
its natural rights in this world, and the complete organisation of
a free and happy life. At the end of two years this organ for
moralising the people collapsed from want of funds, but other
periodicals and pamphlets were printed, and the clandestine
relations between the exiles in Switzerland and their friends in
St. Petersburg were maintained without difficulty, notwithstanding
the efforts of the police to cut the connection. In this way Young
Russia became more and more saturated with the extreme Socialist
theories current in Western Europe.
Thanks partly to this foreign influence and partly to their own
practical experience, the would-be reformers who remained at home
came to understand that academic talking and discussing could bring
about no serious results. Students alone, however numerous and
however devoted to the cause, could not hope to overthrow or coerce
the Government. It was childish to suppose that the walls of the
autocratic Jericho would fall by the blasts of academic trumpets.
Attempts at revolution could not be successful without the active
support of the people, and consequently the revolutionary agitation
must be extended to the masses. So far there was complete
agreement among the revolutionists, but with regard to the modus
operandi emphatic differences of opinion appeared. Those who were
carried away by the stirring accents of Bakunin imagined that if
the masses could only be made to feel themselves the victims of
administrative and economic oppression, they would rise and free
themselves by a united effort. According to this view all that was
required was that popular discontent should be excited and that
precautions should be taken to ensure that the explosions of
discontent should take place simultaneously all over the country.
The rest might safely be left, it was thought, to the operation of
natural forces and the inspiration of the moment. Against this
dangerous illusion warning voices were raised. Lavroff, for
example, while agreeing with Bakunin that mere political reforms
were of little or no value, and that any genuine improvement in the
condition of the working classes could proceed only from economic
and social reorganisation, maintained stoutly that the revolution,
to be permanent and beneficial, must be accomplished, not by
demagogues directing the ignorant masses, but by the people as a
whole, after it had been enlightened and instructed as to its true
interests. The preparatory work would necessarily require a whole
generation of educated propagandists, living among the labouring
population rural and urban.
For some time there was a conflict between these two currents of
opinion, but the views of Lavroff, which were simply a practical
development of academic Nihilism, gained far more adherents than
the violent anarchical proposals of Bakunin, and finally the
grandiose scheme of realising gradually the Socialist ideal by
indoctrinating the masses was adopted with enthusiasm. In St.
Petersburg, Moscow and other large towns the student association
for mutual instruction, to which I have referred in the foregoing
chapter, became centres of popular propaganda, and the academic
Nihilists were transformed into active missionaries. Scores of
male and female students, impatient to convert the masses to the
gospel of freedom and terrestrial felicity, sought to get into
touch with the common people by settling in the villages as school-
teachers, medical practitioners, midwives, etc., or by working as
common factory hands in the industrial centres. In order to obtain
employment in the factories and conceal their real purpose, they
procured false passports, in which they were described as belonging
to the lower classes; and even those who settled in the villages
lived generally under assumed names. Thus was formed a class of
professional revolutionists, sometimes called the Illegals, who
were liable to be arrested at any moment by the police. As
compensation for the privations and hardships which they had to
endure, they had the consolation of believing that they were
advancing the good cause. The means they usually employed were
formal conversations and pamphlets expressly written for the
purpose. The more enthusiastic and persevering of these
missionaries would continue their efforts for months and years,
remaining in communication with the headquarters in the capital or
some provincial town in order to report progress, obtain a fresh
supply of pamphlets, and get their forged passports renewed. This
extraordinary movement was called "going in among the people," and
it spread among the young generation like an epidemic. In 1873 it
was suddenly reinforced by a detachment of fresh recruits. Over a
hundred Russian students were recalled by the Government from
Switzerland, in order to save them from the baneful influence of
Bakunin, Lavroff, and other noted Socialists, and a large
proportion of them joined the ranks of the propagandists.*
* Instances of going in among the people had happened as early as
1864, but they did not become frequent till after 1870.
With regard to the aims and methods of the propagandists, a good
deal of information was obtained in the course of a judicial
inquiry instituted in 1875. A peasant, who was at the same time a
factory worker, informed the police that certain persons were
distributing revolutionary pamphlets among the factory-hands, and
as a proof of what he said he produced some pamphlets which he had
himself received. This led to an investigation, which showed that
a number of young men and women, evidently belonging to the
educated classes, were disseminating revolutionary ideas by means
of pamphlets and conversation. Arrests followed, and it was soon
discovered that these agitators belonged to a large secret
association, which had its centre in Moscow and local branches in
Ivanovo, Tula, and Kief. In Ivanovo, for instance--a manufacturing
town about a hundred miles to the northeast of Moscow--the police
found a small apartment inhabited by three young men and four young
women, all of whom, though belonging by birth to the educated
classes, had the appearance of ordinary factory workers, prepared
their own food, did with their own hands all the domestic work, and
sought to avoid everything which could distinguish them from the
labouring population. In the apartment were found 240 copies of
revolutionary pamphlets, a considerable sum of money, a large
amount of correspondence in cypher, and several forged passports.
How many persons the society contained, it is impossible to say,
because a large portion of them eluded the vigilance of the police;
but many were arrested, and ultimately forty-seven were condemned.
Of these, eleven were noble, seven were sons of parish priests, and
the remainder belong to the lower classes--that is to say, the
small officials, burghers, and peasants. The average age of the
prisoners was twenty-four, the oldest being thirty-six and the
youngest under seventeen! Only five or six were over twenty-five,
and none of these were ringleaders. The female element was
represented by no less than fifteen young persons, whose ages were
on an average under twenty-two. Two of these, to judge by their
photographs, were of refined, prepossessing appearance, and
seemingly little fitted for taking part in wholesale massacres such
as the society talked of organising.
The character and aims of the society were clearly depicted in the
documentary and oral evidence produced at the trial. According to
the fundamental principles, there should exist among the members
absolute equality, complete mutual responsibility and full
frankness and confidence with regard to the affairs of the
association. Among the conditions of admission we find that the
candidate should devote himself entirely to revolutionary activity;
that he should be ready to sever all ties, whether of friendship or
of love, for the good cause; that he should possess great powers of
self-sacrifice and the capacity for keeping secrets; and that he
should consent to become, when necessary, a common labourer in a
factory. The desire to maintain absolute equality is well
illustrated by the article of the statutes regarding the
administration: the office-bearers are not to be chosen by
election, but all members are to be office-bearers in turn, and the
term of office must not exceed one month!
The avowed aim of the society was to destroy the existing social
order, and to replace it by one in which there should be no private
property and no distinctions of class or wealth; or, as it is
expressed in one document, "to found on the ruins of the present
social organisation the Empire of the working classes." The means
to be employed were indicated in a general way, but each member was
to adapt himself to circumstances and was to devote all his energy
to forwarding the cause of the revolution. For the guidance of the
inexperienced, the following means were recommended: simple
conversations, dissemination of pamphlets, the exciting of
discontent, the formation of organised groups, the creation of
funds and libraries. These, taken together, constitute, in the
terminology of revolutionary science, "propaganda," and in addition
to it there should be "agitation." The technical distinction
between these two processes is that propaganda has a purely
preparatory character, and aims merely at enlightening the masses
regarding the true nature of the revolutionary cause, whereas
agitation aims at exciting an individual or a group to acts which
are considered, in the existing regime, as illegal. In time of
peace "pure agitation" was to be carried on by means of organised
bands which should frighten the Government and the privileged
classes, draw away the attention of the authorities from less overt
kinds of revolutionary action, raise the spirit of the people and
thereby render it more accessible to revolutionary ideas, obtain
pecuniary means for further activity, and liberate political
prisoners. In time of insurrection the members should give to all
movements every assistance in their power, and impress on them a
Socialistic character. The central administration and the local
branches should establish relations with publishers, and take steps
to secure a regular supply of prohibited books from abroad. Such
are a few characteristic extracts from a document which might
fairly be called a treatise on revolutionology.
As a specimen of the revolutionary pamphlets circulated by the
propagandists and agitators I may give here a brief account of one
which is well known to the political police. It is entitled
Khitraya Mekhanika (Cunning Machinery), and gives a graphic picture
of the ideas and methods employed. The mise en scene is extremely
simple. Two peasants, Stepan and Andrei, are represented as
meeting in a gin-shop and drinking together. Stepan is described
as good and kindly when he has to do with men of his own class, but
very sharp-tongued when speaking with a foreman or manager. Always
ready with an answer, he can on occasions silence even an official!
He has travelled all over the Empire, has associated with all sorts
and conditions of men, sees everything most clearly, and is, in
short, a very remarkable man. One of his excellent qualities is
that, being "enlightened" himself, he is always ready to enlighten
others, and he now finds an opportunity of displaying his powers.
When Andrei, who is still unenlightened, proposes that they should
drink another glass of vodka, he replies that the Tsar, together
with the nobles and traders, bars the way to the throat. As his
companion does not understand this metaphorical language, he
explains that if there were no Tsars, nobles, or traders, he could
get five glasses of vodka for the sum that he now pays for one
glass. This naturally suggests wider topics, and Stepan gives
something like a lecture. The common people, he explains, pay by
far the greater part of the taxation, and at the same time do all
the work; they plough the fields, build the houses and churches,
work in the mills and factories, and in return they are
systematically robbed and beaten. And what is done with all the
money that is taken from them? First of all, the Tsar gets nine
millions of roubles--enough to feed half a province--and with that
sum he amuses himself, has hunting-parties, and feasts, eats,
drinks, makes merry, and lives in stone houses. He gave liberty,
it is true, to the peasants; but we know what the Emancipation
really was. The best land was taken away and the taxes were
increased, lest the muzhik should get fat and lazy. The Tsar is
himself the richest landed proprietor and manufacturer in the
country. He not only robs us as much as he pleases, but he has
sold into slavery (by forming a national debt) our children and
grandchildren. He takes our sons as soldiers, shuts them up in
barracks so that they should not see their brother-peasants, and
hardens their hearts so that they become wild beasts, ready to rend
their parents. The nobles and traders likewise rob the poor
peasants. In short, all the upper classes have invented a bit of
cunning machinery by which the muzhik is made to pay for their
pleasures and luxuries. The people will one day rise and break
this machinery to pieces. When that day comes they must break
every part of it, for if one bit escapes destruction all the other
parts of it will immediately grow up again. All the force is on
the side of the peasants, if they only knew how to use it.
Knowledge will come in time. They will then destroy this machine,
and perceive that the only real remedy for all social evils is
brotherhood. People should live like brothers, having no mine and
thine, but all things in common. When we have created brotherhood,
there will be no riches and no thieves, but right and righteousness
without end. In conclusion, Stepan addresses a word to "the
torturers": "When the people rise, the Tsar will send troops
against us, and the nobles and capitalists will stake their last
rouble on the result. If they do not succeed, they must not expect
any quarter from us. They may conquer us once or twice, but we
shall at last get our own, for there is no power that can withstand
the whole people. Then we shall cleanse the country of our
persecutors, and establish a brotherhood in which there will be no
mine and thine, but all will work for the common weal. We shall
construct no cunning machinery, but shall pluck up evil by the
roots, and establish eternal justice!"
The above-mentioned distinction between Propaganda and Agitation,
which plays a considerable part in revolutionary literature, had at
that time more theoretical than practical importance. The great
majority of those who took an active part in the movement confined
their efforts to indoctrinating the masses with Socialistic and
subversive ideas, and sometimes their methods were rather childish.
As an illustration I may cite an amusing incident related by one of
the boldest and most tenacious of the revolutionists, who
subsequently acquired a certain sense of humour. He and a friend
were walking one day on a country road, when they were overtaken by
a peasant in his cart. Ever anxious to sow the good seed, they at
once entered into conversation with the rustic, telling him that he
ought not to pay his taxes, because the tchinovniks robbed the
people, and trying to convince him by quotations from Scripture
that he ought to resist the authorities. The prudent muzhik
whipped up his horse and tried to get out of hearing, but the two
zealots ran after him and continued the sermon till they were
completely out of breath. Other propagandists were more practical,
and preached a species of agrarian socialism which the rural
population could understand. At the time of the Emancipation the
peasants were convinced as I have mentioned in a previous chapter,
that the Tsar meant to give them all the land, and to compensate
the landed proprietors by salaries. Even when the law was read and
explained to them, they clung obstinately to their old convictions,
and confidently expected that the REAL Emancipation would be
proclaimed shortly. Taking advantage of this state of things, the
propagandists to whom I refer confirmed the peasants in their
error, and sought in this way to sow discontent against the
proprietors and the Government. Their watchword was "Land and
Liberty," and they formed for a good many years a distinct group,
under that title (Zemlya i Volya, or more briefly Zemlevoltsi).
In the St. Petersburg group, which aspired to direct and control
this movement, there were one or two men who held different views
as to the real object of propaganda and agitation. One of these,
Prince Krapotkin, has told the world what his object was at that
time. He hoped that the Government would be frightened and that
the Autocratic Power, as in France on the eve of the Revolution,
would seek support in the landed proprietors, and call together a
National Assembly. Thus a constitution would be granted, and
though the first Assembly might be conservative in spirit,
autocracy would be compelled in the long run to yield to
parliamentary pressure.
No such elaborate projects were entertained, I believe, by the
majority of the propagandists. Their reasoning was much simpler:
"The Government, having become reactionary, tries to prevent us
from enlightening the people; we will do it in spite of the
Government!" The dangers to which they exposed themselves only
confirmed them in their resolution. Though they honestly believed
themselves to be Realists and Materialists, they were at heart
romantic Idealists, panting to do something heroic. They had been
taught by the apostles whom they venerated, from Belinski
downwards, that the man who simply talks about the good of the
people, and does nothing to promote it, is among the most
contemptible of human beings. No such reproach must be addressed
to them. If the Government opposed and threatened, that was no
excuse for inactivity. They must be up and doing. "Forward!
forward! Let us plunge into the people, identify ourselves with
them, and work for their benefit! Suffering is in store for us,
but we must endure it with fortitude!" The type which
Tchernishevski had depicted in his famous novel, under the name of
Rakhmetof--the youth who led an ascetic life and subjected himself
to privation and suffering as a preparation for future
revolutionary activity--now appeared in the flesh. If we may
credit Bakunin, these Rakhmetofs had not even the consolation of
believing in the possibility of a revolution, but as they could not
and would not remain passive spectators of the misfortunes of the
people, they resolved to go in among the masses in order to share
with them fraternally their sufferings, and at the same time to
teach and prepare, not theoretically, but practically by their
living example.* This is, I believe, an exaggeration. The
propagandists were, for the most part of incredibly sanguine
temperament.
* Bakunin: "Gosudarstvennost' i Anarkhiya" ("State Organisation and
Anarchy"), Zurich, 1873.
The success of the propaganda and agitation was not at all in
proportion to the numbers and enthusiasm of those who took part in
it. Most of these displayed more zeal than mother-wit and
discretion. Their Socialism was too abstract and scientific to be
understood by rustics, and when they succeeded in making themselves
intelligible they awakened in their hearers more suspicion than
sympathy. The muzhik is a very matter-of-fact practical person,
totally incapable of understanding what Americans call "hifalutin"
tendencies in speech and conduct, and as he listened to the
preaching of the new Gospel doubts and questionings spontaneously
rose in his mind: "What do those young people, who betray their
gentlefolk origin by their delicate white hands, their foreign
phrases, their ignorance of the common things of everyday peasant
life, really want? Why are they bearing hardships and taking so
much trouble? They tell us it is for our good, but we are not such
fools and simpletons as they take us for. They are not doing it
all for nothing. What do they expect from us in return? Whatever
it is, they are evidently evil-doers, and perhaps moshenniki
(swindlers). Devil take them!" and thereupon the cautious muzhik
turns his back upon his disinterested self-sacrificing teachers, or
goes quietly and denounces them to the police! It is not only in
Spain that we encounter Don Quixotes and Sancho Panzas!
Occasionally a worse fate befell the missionaries. If they allowed
themselves, as they sometimes did, to "blaspheme" against religion
or the Tsar, they ran the risk of being maltreated on the spot. I
have heard of one case in which the punishment for blasphemy was
applied by sturdy peasant matrons. Even when they escaped such
mishaps they had not much reason to congratulate themselves on
their success. After three years of arduous labour the hundreds of
apostles could not boast of more than a score or two of converts
among the genuine working classes, and even these few did not all
remain faithful unto death. Some of them, however, it must be
admitted, laboured and suffered to the end with the courage and
endurance of true martyrs.
It was not merely the indifference or hostility of the masses that
the propagandists had to complain of. The police soon got on their
track, and did not confine themselves to persuasion and logical
arguments. Towards the end of 1873 they arrested some members of
the central directory group in St. Petersburg, and in the following
May they discovered in the province of Saratof an affiliated
organisation with which nearly 800 persons were connected, about
one-fifth of them belonging to the female sex. A few came of well-
to-do families--sons and daughters of minor officials or small
landed proprietors--but the great majority were poor students of
humbler origin, a large contingent being supplied by the sons of
the poor parish clergy. In other provinces the authorities made
similar discoveries. Before the end of the year a large proportion
of the propagandists were in prison, and the centralised
organisation, so far as such a thing existed, was destroyed.
Gradually it dawned on the minds even of the Don Quixotes that
pacific propaganda was no longer possible, and that attempts to
continue it could lead only to useless sacrifices.
For a time there was universal discouragement in the revolutionary
ranks; and among those who had escaped arrest there were mutual
recriminations and endless discussions about the causes of failure
and the changes to be made in modes of action. The practical
results of these recriminations and discussions was that the
partisans of a slow, pacific propaganda retired to the background,
and the more impatient revolutionary agitators took possession of
the movement. These maintained stoutly that as pacific propaganda
had become impossible, stronger methods must be adopted. The
masses must be organised so as to offer successful resistance to
the Government. Conspiracies must therefore be formed, local
disorders provoked, and blood made to flow. The part of the
country which seemed best adapted for experiments of this kind was
the southern and southeastern region, inhabited by the descendants
of the turbulent Cossack population which had raised formidable
insurrections under Stenka Razin and Pugatcheff in the seventeenth
and eighteenth centuries. Here, then, the more impatient agitators
began their work. A Kief group called the Buntari (rioters),
composed of about twenty-five individuals, settled in various
localities as small shopkeepers or horse dealers, or went about as
workmen or peddlers. One member of the group has given us in his
reminiscences an amusing account of the experiment. Everywhere the
agitators found the peasants suspicious and inhospitable, and
consequently they had to suffer a great deal of discomfort. Some
of them at once gave up the task as hopeless. The others settled
in a village and began operations. Having made a topographic
survey of the locality, they worked out an ingenious plan of
campaign; but they had no recruits for the future army of
insurrection, and if they had been able to get recruits, they had
no arms for them, and no money wherewith to purchase arms or
anything else. In these circumstances they gravely appointed a
committee to collect funds, knowing very well that no money would
be forthcoming. It was as if a shipwrecked crew in an open boat,
having reached the brink of starvation, appointed a committee to
obtain a supply of fresh water and provisions! In the hope of
obtaining assistance from headquarters, a delegate was sent to St.
Petersburg and Moscow to explain that for the arming of the
population about a quarter of a million of roubles was required.
The delegate brought back thirty second-hand revolvers! The
revolutionist who confesses all this* recognises that the whole
scheme was childishly unpractical: "We chose the path of popular
insurrection because we had faith in the revolutionary spirit of
the masses, in its power and its invincibility. That was the weak
side of our position; and the most curious part of it was that we
drew proofs in support of our theory from history--from the
abortive insurrections of Pazin and Pugatcheff, which took place in
an age when the Government had only a small regular army and no
railways or telegraphs! We did not even think of attempting a
propaganda among the military!" In the district of Tchigirin the
agitators had a little momentary success, but the result was the
same. There a student called Stefanovitch pretended that the Tsar
was struggling with the officials to benefit the peasantry, and he
showed the simple rustics a forged imperial manifesto in which they
were ordered to form a society for the purpose of raising an
insurrection against the officials, the nobles, and the priests.
At one moment (April, 1877), the society had about 600 members, but
a few months later it was discovered by the police, and the leaders
and peasants were arrested.
* Debogorio-Mokrievitch. "Vospominaniya" ("Reminiscences").
Paris, 1894-99.
When it had thus become evident that propaganda and agitation were
alike useless, and when numerous arrests were being made daily, it
became necessary for the revolutionists to reconsider their
position, and some of the more moderate proposed to rally to the
Liberals, as a temporary measure. Hitherto there had been very
little sympathy and a good deal of openly avowed hostility between
Liberals and revolutionists. The latter, convinced that they could
overthrow the Autocratic Power by their own unaided efforts, had
looked askance at Liberalism because they believed that
parliamentary discussions and party struggles would impede rather
than facilitate the advent of the Socialist Millennium, and
strengthen the domination of the bourgeoisie without really
improving the condition of the masses. Now, however, when the need
of allies was felt, it seemed that constitutional government might
be used as a stepping-stone for reaching the Socialist ideal,
because it must grant a certain liberty of the Press and of
association, and it would necessarily abolish the existing
autocratic system of arresting, imprisoning and exiling, on mere
suspicion, without any regular form of legal procedure. As usual,
an appeal was made to history, and arguments were easily found in
favour of this course of action. The past of other nations had
shown that in the march of progress there are no sudden leaps and
bounds, and it was therefore absurd to imagine, as the
revolutionists had hitherto done, that Russian Autocracy could be
swallowed by Socialism at a gulp. There must always be periods of
transition, and it seemed that such a transition period might now
be initiated. Liberalism might be allowed to destroy, or at least
weaken, Autocracy, and then it might be destroyed in its turn by
Socialism of the most advanced type.
Having adopted this theory of gradual historic development, some of
the more practical revolutionists approached the more advanced
Liberals and urged them to more energetic action; but before
anything could be arranged the more impatient revolutionists--
notably the group called the Narodovoltsi (National-will-ists)--
intervened, denounced what they considered an unholy alliance, and
proposed a policy of terrorism by which the Government would be
frightened into a more conciliatory attitude. Their idea was that
the officials who displayed most zeal against the revolutionary
movement should be assassinated, and that every act of severity on
the part of the Administration should be answered by an act of
"revolutionary justice."
As it was evident that the choice between these two courses of
action must determine in great measure the future character and
ultimate fate of the movement, there was much discussion between
the two groups; but the question did not long remain in suspense.
Soon the extreme party gained the upper hand, and the Terrorist
policy was adopted. I shall let the revolutionists themselves
explain this momentous decision. In a long proclamation published
some years later it is explained thus:
"The revolutionary movement in Russia began with the so-called
'going in among the people.' The first Russian revolutionists
thought that the freedom of the people could be obtained only by
the people itself, and they imagined that the only thing necessary
was that the people should absorb Socialistic ideas. To this it
was supposed that the peasantry were naturally inclined, because
they already possess, in the rural Commune, institutions which
contain the seeds of Socialism, and which might serve as a basis
for the reconstruction of society according to Socialist
principles. The propagandists hoped, therefore, that in the
teachings of West European Socialism the people would recognise its
own instinctive creations in riper and more clearly defined forms
and that it would joyfully accept the new teaching.
"But the people did not understand its friends, and showed itself
hostile to them. It turned out that institutions born in slavery
could not serve as a foundation for the new construction, and that
the man who was yesterday a serf, though capable of taking part in
disturbances, is not fitted for conscious revolutionary work. With
pain in their heart the revolutionists had to confess that they
were deceived in their hopes of the people. Around them were no
social revolutionary forces on which they could lean for support,
and yet they could not reconcile themselves with the existing state
of violence and slavery. Thereupon awakened a last hope--the hope
of a drowning man who clutches at a straw: a little group of heroic
and self-sacrificing individuals might accomplish with their own
strength the difficult task of freeing Russia from the yoke of
autocracy. They had to do it themselves, because there was no
other means. But would they be able to accomplish it? For them
that question did not exist. The struggle of that little group
against autocracy was like the heroic means on which a doctor
decides when there is no longer any hope of the patient's recovery.
Terrorism was the only means that remained, and it had the
advantage of giving a natural vent to pent-up feelings, and of
seeming a reaction against the cruel persecutions of the
Government. The party called the Narodnaya Volya (National Will)
was accordingly formed, and during several years the world
witnessed a spectacle that had never been seen before in history.
The Narodnaya Volya, insignificant in numbers but strong in spirit,
engaged in single combat with the powerful Russian Government.
Neither executions, nor imprisonment with hard labour, nor ordinary
imprisonment and exile, destroyed the energy of the revolutionists.
Under their shots fell, one after the other, the most zealous and
typical representatives of arbitrary action and violence. . . ."
It was at this time, in 1877, when propaganda and agitation among
the masses were being abandoned for the system of terrorism, but
before any assassinations had taken place, that I accidentally came
into personal relations with some prominent adherents of the
revolutionary movement. One day a young man of sympathetic
appearance, whom I did not know and who brought no credentials,
called on me in St. Petersburg and suggested to me that I might
make public through the English Press what he described as a
revolting act of tyranny and cruelty committed by General Trepof,
the Prefect of the city. That official, he said, in visiting
recently one of the prisons, had noticed that a young political
prisoner called Bogolubof did not salute him as he passed, and he
had ordered him to be flogged in consequence. To this I replied
that I had no reason to disbelieve the story, but that I had
equally no reason to accept it as accurate, as it rested solely on
the evidence of a person with whom I was totally unacquainted. My
informant took the objection in good part, and offered me the names
and addresses of a number of persons who could supply me with any
proofs that I might desire.
At his next visit I told him I had seen several of the persons he
had named, and that I could not help perceiving that they were
closely connected with the revolutionary movement. I then went on
to suggest that as the sympathisers with that movement constantly
complained that they were systematically misrepresented,
calumniated and caricatured, the leaders ought to give the world an
accurate account of their real doctrines, and in this respect I
should be glad to assist them. Already I knew something of the
subject, because I had many friends and acquaintances among the
sympathisers, and had often had with them interminable discussions.
With their ideas, so far as I knew them, I felt bound to confess
that I had no manner of sympathy, but I flattered myself, and he
himself had admitted, that I was capable of describing accurately
and criticising impartially doctrines with which I did not agree.
My new acquaintance, whom I may call Dimitry Ivan'itch, was pleased
with the proposal, and after he had consulted with some of his
friends, we came to an agreement by which I should receive all the
materials necessary for writing an accurate account of the
doctrinal side of the movement. With regard to any conspiracies
that might be in progress, I warned him that he must be strictly
reticent, because if I came accidentally to know of any terrorist
designs, I should consider it my duty to warn the authorities. For
this reason I declined to attend any secret conclaves, and it was
agreed that I should be instructed without being initiated.
The first step in my instruction was not very satisfactory or
encouraging. One day Dimitri Ivan'itch brought me a large
manuscript, which contained, he said, the real doctrines of the
revolutionists and the explanation of their methods. I was
surprised to find that it was written in English, and I perceived
at a glance that it was not at all what I wanted. As soon as I had
read the first sentence I turned to my friend and said:
"I am very sorry to find, Dimitri Ivan'itch, that you have not kept
your part of the bargain. We agreed, you may remember, that we
were to act towards each other in absolutely good faith, and here I
find a flagrant bit of bad faith in the very first sentence of the
manuscript which you have brought me. The document opens with the
statement that a large number of students have been arrested and
imprisoned for distributing books among the people. That statement
may be true according to the letter, but it is evidently intended
to mislead. These youths have been arrested, as you must know, not
for distributing ordinary books, as the memorandum suggests, but
for distributing books of a certain kind. I have read some of
them, and I cannot feel at all surprised that the Government should
object to their being put into the hands of the ignorant masses.
Take, for example, the one entitled Khitraya Mekhanika, and others
of the same type. The practical teaching they contain is that the
peasants should be ready to rise and cut the throats of the landed
proprietors and officials. Now, a wholesale massacre of the kind
may or may not be desirable in the interests of Society, and
justifiable according to some new code of higher morality. That is
a question into which I do not enter. All I maintain is that the
writer of this memorandum, in speaking of 'books,' meant to mislead
me."
Dimitri Ivan'itch looked puzzled and ashamed. "Forgive me," he
said; "I am to blame--not for having attempted to deceive you, but
for not having taken precautions. I have not read the manuscript,
and I could not if I wished, for it is written in English, and I
know no language but my mother tongue. My friends ought not to
have done this. Give me back the paper, and I shall take care that
nothing of the sort occurs in future."
This promise was faithfully kept, and I had no further reason to
complain. Dimitri Ivan'itch gave me a considerable amount of
information, and lent me a valuable collection of revolutionary
pamphlets. Unfortunately the course of tuition was suddenly
interrupted by unforeseen circumstances, which I may mention as
characteristic of life in St. Petersburg at the time. My servant,
an excellent young Russian, more honest than intelligent, came to
me one morning with a mysterious air, and warned me to be on my
guard, because there were "bad people" going about. On being
pressed a little, he explained to me what he meant. Two strangers
had come to him and, after offering him a few roubles, had asked
him a number of questions about my habits--at what hour I went out
and came home, what persons called on me, and much more of the same
sort. "They even tried, sir, to get into your sitting-room; but of
course I did not allow them. I believe they want to rob you!"
It was not difficult to guess who these "bad people" were who took
such a keen interest in my doings, and who wanted to examine my
apartment in my absence. Any doubts I had on the subject were soon
removed. On the morrow and following days I noticed that whenever
I went out, and wherever I might walk or drive, I was closely
followed by two unsympathetic-looking individuals--so closely that
when I turned round sharp they ran into me. The first and second
times this little accident occurred they received a strong volley
of unceremonious vernacular; but when we became better acquainted
we simply smiled at each other knowingly, as the old Roman Augurs
are supposed to have done when they met in public unobserved.
There was no longer any attempt at concealment or mystification. I
knew I was being shadowed, and the shadowers could not help
perceiving that I knew it. Yet, strange to say, they were never
changed!
The reader probably assumes that the secret police had somehow got
wind of my relations with the revolutionists. Such an assumption
presupposes on the part of the police an amount of intelligence and
perspicacity which they do not usually possess. On this occasion
they were on an entirely wrong scent, and the very day when I first
noticed my shadowers, a high official, who seemed to regard the
whole thing as a good joke, told me confidentially what the wrong
scent was. At the instigation of an ex-ambassador, from whom I had
the misfortune to differ in matters of foreign policy, the Moscow
Gazette had denounced me publicly by name as a person who was in
the habit of visiting daily the Ministry of Foreign Affairs--
doubtless with the nefarious purpose of obtaining by illegal means
secret political information--and the police had concluded that I
was a fit and proper person to be closely watched. In reality, my
relations with the Russian Foreign Office, though inconvenient to
the ex-ambassador, were perfectly regular and above-board--
sanctioned, in fact, by Prince Gortchakoff--but the indelicate
attentions of the secret police were none the less extremely
unwelcome, because some intelligent police-agent might get onto the
real scent, and cause me serious inconvenience. I determined,
therefore, to break off all relations with Dimitri Ivan'itch and
his friends, and postpone my studies to a more convenient season;
but that decision did not entirely extricate me from my
difficulties. The collection of revolutionary pamphlets was still
in my possession, and I had promised to return it. For some little
time I did not see how I could keep my promise without compromising
myself or others, but at last--after having had my shadowers
carefully shadowed in order to learn accurately their habits, and
having taken certain elaborate precautions, with which I need not
trouble the reader, as he is not likely ever to require them--I
paid a visit secretly to Dimitri Ivan'itch in his small room,
almost destitute of furniture, handed him the big parcel of
pamphlets, warned him not to visit me again, and bade him farewell.
Thereupon we went our separate ways and I saw him no more. Whether
he subsequently played a leading part in the movement I never could
ascertain, because I did not know his real name; but if the
conception which I formed of his character was at all accurate, he
probably ended his career in Siberia, for he was not a man to look
back after having put his hand to the plough. That is a peculiar
trait of the Russian revolutionists of the period in question.
Their passion for realising an impossible ideal was incurable.
Many of them were again and again arrested; and as soon as they
escaped or were liberated they almost invariably went back to their
revolutionary activity and worked energetically until they again
fell into the clutches of the police.
From this digression into the sphere of personal reminiscences I
return now and take up again the thread of the narrative.
We have seen how the propaganda and the agitation had failed,
partly because the masses showed themselves indifferent or hostile,
and partly because the Government adopted vigorous repressive
measures. We have seen, too, how the leaders found themselves in
face of a formidable dilemma; either they must abandon their
schemes or they must attack their persecutors. The more energetic
among them, as I have already stated, chose the latter alternative,
and they proceeded at once to carry out their policy. In the
course of a single year (February, 1878, to February, 1879) a whole
series of terrorist crimes was committed; in Kief an attempt was
made on the life of the Public Prosecutor, and an officer of
gendarmerie was stabbed; in St. Petersburg the Chief of the
Political Police of the Empire (General Mezentsef) was assassinated
in broad daylight in one of the central streets, and a similar
attempt was made on his successor (General Drenteln); at Kharkof
the Governor (Prince Krapotkin) was shot dead when entering his
residence. During the same period two members of the revolutionary
organisation, accused of treachery, were "executed" by order of
local Committees. In most cases the perpetrators of the crimes
contrived to escape. One of them became well known in Western
Europe as an author under the pseudonym of Stepniak.
Terrorism had not the desired effect. On the contrary, it
stimulated the zeal and activity of the authorities, and in the
course of the winter of 1878-79 hundreds of arrests--some say as
many as 2,000--were made in St. Petersburg alone. Driven to
desperation, the revolutionists still at large decided that it was
useless to assassinate mere officials; the fons et origo mali must
be reached; a blow must be struck at the Tsar himself! The first
attempt was made by a young man called Solovyoff, who fired several
shots at Alexander II. as he was walking near the Winter Palace,
but none of them took effect.
This policy of aggressive terrorism did not meet with universal
approval among the revolutionists, and it was determined to discuss
the matter at a Congress of delegates from various local circles.
The meetings were held in June, 1879, two months after Solovyoff's
unsuccessful attempt, at two provincial towns, Lipetsk and
Voronezh. It was there agreed in principle to confirm the decision
of the Terrorist Narodovoltsi. As the Liberals were not in a
position to create liberal institutions or to give guarantees for
political rights, which are the essential conditions of any
Socialist agitation, there remained for the revolutionary party no
other course than to destroy the despotic autocracy. Thereupon a
programme of action was prepared, and an Executive Committee
elected. From that moment, though there were still many who
preferred milder methods, the Terrorists had the upper hand, and
they at once proceeded to centralise the organisation and to
introduce stricter discipline, with greater precautions to ensure
secrecy.
The Executive Committee imagined that by assassinating the Tsar
autocracy might be destroyed, and several carefully planned
attempts were made. The first plan was to wreck the train when the
Imperial family were returning to St. Petersburg from the Crimea.
Mines were accordingly laid at three separate points, but they all
failed. At the last of the three points (near Moscow) a train was
blown up, but it was not the one in which the Imperial family was
travelling.
Not at all discouraged by this failure, nor by the discovery of its
secret printing-press by the police, the Executive Committee next
tried to attain its object by an explosion of dynamite in the
Winter Palace when the Imperial family were assembled at dinner.
The execution was entrusted to a certain Halturin, one of the few
revolutionists of peasant origin. As an exceptionally clever
carpenter and polisher, he easily found regular employment in the
palace, and he contrived to make a rough plan of the building.
This plan, on which the dining-hall was marked with an ominous red
cross, fell into the hands of the police, and they made what they
considered a careful investigation; but they failed to unravel the
plot and did not discover the dynamite concealed in the carpenters'
sleeping quarters. Halturin showed wonderful coolness while the
search was going on, and continued to sleep every night on the
explosive, though it caused him excruciating headaches. When he
was assured by the chemist of the Executive Committee that the
quantity collected was sufficient, he exploded the mine at the
usual dinner hour, and contrived to escape uninjured.* In the
guardroom immediately above the spot where the dynamite was
exploded ten soldiers were killed and 53 wounded, and in the
dining-hall the floor was wrecked, but the Imperial family escaped
in consequence of not sitting down to dinner at the usual hour.
* After living some time in Roumania he returned to Russia under
the name of Stepanof, and in 1882 he was tried and executed for
complicity in the assassination of General Strebnekof.
For this barbarous act the Executive Committee publicly accepted
full responsibility. In a proclamation placarded in the streets of
St. Petersburg it declared that, while regretting the death of the
soldiers, it was resolved to carry on the struggle with the
Autocratic Power until the social reforms should be entrusted to a
Constituent Assembly, composed of members freely elected and
furnished with instructions from their constituents.
Finding police-repression so ineffectual, Alexander II. determined
to try the effect of conciliation, and for this purpose he placed
Loris Melikof at the head of the Government, with semi-dictatorial
powers (February, 1880). The experiment did not succeed. By the
Terrorists it was regarded as "a hypocritical Liberalism outwardly
and a veiled brutality within," while in the official world it was
condemned as an act of culpable weakness on the part of the
autocracy. One consequence of it was that the Executive Committee
was encouraged to continue its efforts, and, as the police became
much less active, it was enabled to improve the revolutionary
organisation. In a circular sent to the affiliated provincial
associations it explained that the only source of legislation must
be the national will,* and as the Government would never accept
such a principle, its hand must be forced by a great popular
insurrection, for which all available forces should be organised.
The peasantry, as experience had shown, could not yet be relied on,
but efforts should be made to enrol the workmen of the towns.
Great importance was attached to propaganda in the army; but as few
conversions had been made among the rank and file, attention was to
be directed chiefly to the officers, who would be able to carry
their subordinates with them at the critical moment.
* Hence the designation Narodovoltsi (which, as we have seen, means
literally National-will-ists) adopted by this section.
While thus recommending the scheme of destroying autocracy by means
of a popular insurrection in the distant future, the Committee had
not abandoned more expeditious methods, and it was at that moment
hatching a plot for the assassination of the Tsar. During the
winter months his Majesty was in the habit of holding on Sundays a
small parade in the riding-school near the Michael Square in St.
Petersburg. On Sunday, March 3d, 1881, the streets by which he
usually returned to the Palace had been undermined at two places,
and on an alternative route several conspirators were posted with
hand-grenades concealed under their great coats. The Emperor chose
the alternative route. Here, at a signal given by Sophia Perovski,
the first grenade was thrown by a student called Ryssakoff, but it
merely wounded some members of the escort. The Emperor stopped and
got out of his sledge, and as he was making inquiries about the
wounded soldiers a second grenade was thrown by a youth called
Grinevitski, with fatal effect. Alexander II. was conveyed
hurriedly to the Winter Palace, and died almost immediately.
By this act the members of the Executive Committee proved their
energy and their talent as conspirators, but they at the same time
showed their shortsightedness and their political incapacity; for
they had made no preparations for immediately seizing the power
which they so ardently coveted--with the intention of using it, of
course, entirely for the public good. If the facts were not so
well authenticated, we might dismiss the whole story as incredible.
A group of young people, certainly not more than thirty or forty in
number, without any organised material force behind them, without
any influential accomplices in the army or the official world,
without any prospect of support from the masses, and with no plan
for immediate action after the assassination, deliberately provoked
the crisis for which they were so hopelessly unprepared. It has
been suggested that they expected the Liberals to seize the Supreme
Power, but this explanation is evidently an afterthought, because
they knew that the Liberals were as unprepared as themselves and
they regarded them at that time as dangerous rivals. Besides this,
the explanation is quite irreconcilable with the proclamation
issued by the Executive Committee immediately afterwards. The most
charitable way of explaining the conduct of the conspirators is to
suppose that they were actuated more by blind hatred of the
autocracy and its agents than by political calculations of a
practical kind--that they acted simply like a wounded bull in the
arena, which shuts its eyes and recklessly charges its tormentors.
The murder of the Emperor had not at all the effect which the
Narodovoltsi anticipated. On the contrary, it destroyed their
hopes of success. Many people of liberal convictions who
sympathised vaguely with the revolutionary movement without taking
part in it, and who did not condemn very severely the attacks on
police officials, were horrified when they found that the would-be
reformers did not spare even the sacred person of the Tsar. At the
same time, the police officials, who had become lax and inefficient
under the conciliatory regime of Loris Melikof, recovered their old
zeal, and displayed such inordinate activity that the revolutionary
organisation was paralysed and in great measure destroyed. Six of
the regicides were condemned to death, and five of them publicly
executed, amongst the latter Sophia Perovski, one of the most
active and personally sympathetic personages among the
revolutionists. Scores of those who had taken an active part in
the movement were in prison or in exile. For a short time the
propaganda was continued among military and naval officers, and
various attempts at reorganisation, especially in the southern
provinces, were made, but they all failed. A certain Degaief, who
had taken part in the formation of military circles, turned
informer, and aided the police. By his treachery not only a
considerable number of officers, but also Vera Filipof, a young
lady of remarkable ability and courage, who was the leading spirit
in the attempts at reorganisation, were arrested. There were still
a number of leaders living abroad, and from time to time they sent
emissaries to revive the propaganda, but these efforts were all
fruitless. One of the active members of the revolutionary party,
Leo Deutsch, who has since published his Memoirs, relates how the
tide of revolution ebbed rapidly at this time. "Both in Russia and
abroad," he says, "I had seen how the earlier enthusiasm had given
way to scepticism; men had lost faith, though many of them would
not allow that it was so. It was clear to me that a reaction had
set in for many years." Of the attempts to resuscitate the
movement he says: "The untried and unskilfully managed societies
were run to death before they could undertake anything definite,
and the unity and interdependence which characterised the original
band of members had disappeared." With regard to the want of
unity, another prominent revolutionist (Maslof) wrote to a friend
(Dragomanof) at Geneva in 1882 in terms of bitter complaint. He
accused the Executive Committee of trying to play the part of chief
of the whole revolutionary party, and declared that its
centralising tendencies were more despotic than those of the
Government. Distributing orders among its adherents without
initiating them into its plans, it insisted on unquestioning
obedience. The Socialist youth, ardent adherents of Federalism,
were indignant at this treatment, and began to understand that the
Committee used them simply as chair a canon. The writer described
in vivid colours the mutual hostility which reigned among various
fractions of the party, and which manifested itself in accusations
and even in denunciations; and he predicted that the Narodnaya
Volya, which had organised the various acts of terrorism
culminating in the assassination of the Emperor, would never
develop into a powerful revolutionary party. It had sunk into the
slough of untruth, and it could only continue to deceive the
Government and the public.
In the mutual recriminations several interesting admissions were
made. It was recognised that neither the educated classes nor the
common people were capable of bringing about a revolution: the
former were not numerous enough, and the latter were devoted to the
Tsar and did not sympathise with the revolutionary movement, though
they might perhaps be induced to rise at a moment of crisis. It
was considered doubtful whether such a rising was desirable,
because the masses, being insufficiently prepared, might turn
against the educated minority. In no case could a popular
insurrection attain the object which the Socialists had in view,
because the power would either remain in the hands of the Tsar--
thanks to the devotion of the common people--or it would fall into
the hands of the Liberals, who would oppress the masses worse than
the autocratic Government had done. Further, it was recognised
that acts of terrorism were worse than useless, because they were
misunderstood by the ignorant, and tended to inflame the masses
against the leaders. It seemed necessary, therefore, to return to
a pacific propaganda. Tikhomirof, who was nominally directing the
movement from abroad, became utterly discouraged, and wrote in 1884
to one of his emissaries in Russia (Lopatin): "You now see Russia,
and can convince yourself that it does not possess the material for
a vast work of reorganisation. . . . I advise you seriously not to
make superhuman efforts and not to make a scandal in attempting the
impossible. . . . If you do not want to satisfy yourself with
trifles, come away and await better times."
In examining the material relating to this period one sees clearly
that the revolutionary movement had got into a vicious circle. As
pacific propaganda had become impossible, in consequence of the
opposition of the authorities and the vigilance of the police, the
Government could be overturned only by a general insurrection; but
the general insurrection could not be prepared without pacific
propaganda. As for terrorism, it had become discredited.
Tikhomirof himself came to the conclusion that the terrorist idea
was altogether a mistake, not only morally, but also from the point
of view of political expediency. A party, he explained, has either
the force to overthrow the Government, or it has not; in the former
case it has no need of political assassination, and in the latter
the assassinations have no effect, because Governments are not so
stupid as to let themselves be frightened by those who cannot
overthrow them. Plainly there was nothing to be done but to wait
for better times, as he had suggested, and the better times did not
seem to be within measurable distance. He himself, after
publishing a brochure entitled "Why I Ceased to Be a
Revolutionist," made his peace with the Government, and others
followed his example.* In one prison nine made formal
recantations, among them Emilianof, who held a reserve bomb ready
when Alexander II. was assassinated. Occasional acts of terrorism
showed that there was still fire under the smouldering embers, but
they were few and far between. The last serious incident of the
kind during this period was the regicide conspiracy of Sheviryoff
in March, 1887. The conspirators, carrying the bombs, were
arrested in the principal street of St. Petersburg, and five of
them were hanged. The railway accident of Borki, which happened in
the following year, and in which the Imperial family had a very
narrow escape, ought perhaps to be added to the list, because there
is reason to believe that it was the work of revolutionists.
* Tikhomirof subsequently worked against the Social Democrats in
Moscow in the interests of the Government.
By this time all the cooler heads among the revolutionists,
especially those who were living abroad in personal safety, had
come to understand that the Socialist ideal could not be attained
by popular insurrection, terrorism, or conspiracies, and
consequently that further activity on the old lines was absurd.
Those of them who did not abandon the enterprise in despair
reverted to the idea that Autocratic Power, impregnable against
frontal attacks, might be destroyed by prolonged siege operations.
This change of tactics is reflected in the revolutionary
literature. In 1889, for example, the editor of the Svobodnaya
Rossia declared that the aim of the movement now was political
freedom--not only as a stepping-stone to social reorganisation, but
as a good in itself. This is, he explains, the only possible
revolution at present in Russia. "For the moment there can be no
other immediate practical aim. Ulterior aims are not abandoned,
but they are not at present within reach. . . The revolutionists
of the seventies and the eighties did not succeed in creating among
the peasantry or the town workmen anything which had even the
appearance of a force capable of struggling with the Government;
and the revolutionists of the future will have no greater success
until they have obtained such political rights as personal
inviolability. Our immediate aim, therefore, is a National
Assembly controlled by local self-government, and this can be
brought about only by a union of all the revolutionary forces."
There were still indications, it is true, that the old spirit of
terrorism was not yet quite extinct: Captain Zolotykhin, for
example, an officer of the Moscow secret police, was assassinated
by a female revolutionist in 1890. But such incidents were merely
the last fitful sputterings of a lamp that was going out for want
of oil. In 1892 Stepniak declared it evident to all that the
professional revolutionists could not alone overthrow autocracy,
however great their energy and heroism; and he arrived at the same
conclusion as the writer just quoted. Of course, immediate success
was not to be expected. "It is only from the evolutionist's point
of view that the struggle with autocracy has a meaning. From any
other standpoint it must seem a sanguinary farce--a mere exercise
in the art of self-sacrifice!" Such are the conclusions arrived at
in 1892 by a man who had been in 1878 one of the leading
terrorists, and who had with his own hand assassinated General
Mezentsef, Chief of the Political Police.
Thus the revolutionary movement, after passing through four stages,
which I may call the academic, the propagandist, the
insurrectionary, and the terrorist, had failed to accomplish its
object. One of those who had taken an active part in it, and who,
after spending two years in Siberia as a political exile, escaped
and settled in Western Europe, could write thus: "Our revolutionary
movement is dead, and we who are still alive stand by the grave of
our beautiful departed and discuss what is wanting to her. One of
us thinks that her nose should be improved; another suggests a
change in her chin or her hair. We do not notice the essential
that what our beautiful departed wants is life; that it is not a
matter of hair or eyebrows, but of a living soul, which formerly
concealed all defects, and made her beautiful, and which now has
flown away. However we may invent changes and improvements, all
these things are utterly insignificant in comparison with what is
really wanting, and what we cannot give; for who can breathe a
living soul into a corpse?"
In truth, the movement which I have endeavoured to describe was at
an end; but another movement, having the same ultimate object, was
coming into existence, and it constitutes one of the essential
factors of the present situation. Some of the exiles in
Switzerland and Paris had become acquainted with the social-
democratic and labour movements in Western Europe, and they
believed that the strategy and tactics employed in these movements
might be adopted in Russia. How far they have succeeded in
carrying out this policy I shall relate presently; but before
entering on this subject, I must explain how the application of
such a policy had been rendered possible by changes in the economic
conditions. Russia had begun to create rapidly a great
manufacturing industry and an industrial proletariat. This will
form the subject of the next chapter.
CHAPTER XXXVI
INDUSTRIAL PROGRESS AND THE PROLETARIAT
Russia till Lately a Peasant Empire--Early Efforts to Introduce
Arts and Crafts--Peter the Great and His Successors--Manufacturing
Industry Long Remains an Exotic--The Cotton Industry--The Reforms
of Alexander II.--Protectionists and Free Trade--Progress under
High Tariffs--M. Witte's Policy--How Capital Was Obtained--Increase
of Exports--Foreign Firms Cross the Customs Frontier--Rapid
Development of Iron Industry--A Commercial Crisis--M. Witte's
Position Undermined by Agrarians and Doctrinaires--M. Plehve a
Formidable Opponent--His Apprehensions of Revolution--Fall of M.
Witte--The Industrial Proletariat.
Fifty years ago Russia was still essentially a peasant empire,
living by agriculture of a primitive type, and supplying her other
wants chiefly by home industries, as was the custom in Western
Europe during the Middle Ages.
For many generations her rulers had been trying to transplant into
their wide dominions the art and crafts of the West, but they had
formidable difficulties to contend with, and their success was not
nearly as great as they desired. We know that as far back as the
fourteenth century there were cloth-workers in Moscow, for we read
in the chronicles that the workshops of these artisans were sacked
when the town was stormed by the Tartars. Workers in metal had
also appeared in some of the larger towns by that time, but they do
not seem to have risen much above the level of ordinary
blacksmiths. They were destined, however, to make more rapid
progress than other classes of artisans, because the old Tsars of
Muscovy, like other semi-barbarous potentates, admired and envied
the industries of more civilised countries mainly from the military
point of view. What they wanted most was a plentiful supply of
good arms wherewith to defend themselves and attack their
neighbours, and it was to this object that their most strenuous
efforts were directed.
As early as 1475 Ivan III., the grandfather of Ivan the Terrible,
sent a delegate to Venice to seek out for him an architect who, in
addition to his own craft, knew how to make guns; and in due course
appeared in the Kremlin a certain Muroli, called Aristotle by his
contemporaries on account of his profound learning. He undertook
"to build churches and palaces, to cast big bells and cannons, to
fire off the said cannons, and to make every sort of castings very
cunningly"; and for the exercise of these various arts it was
solemnly stipulated in a formal document that he should receive the
modest salary of ten roubles monthly. With regard to the military
products, at least, the Venetian faithfully fulfilled his contract,
and in a short time the Tsar had the satisfaction of possessing a
"cannon-house," subsequently dignified with the name of "arsenal."
Some of the natives learned the foreign art, and exactly a century
later (1856) a Russian, or at least a Slav, called Tchekhof,
produced a famous "Tsar-cannon," weighing as much as 96,000 lbs.
The connection thus established with the mechanical arts of the
West was always afterwards maintained, and we find frequent notices
of the fact in contemporary writers. In the reign of the
grandfather of Peter the Great, for example, two paper-works were
established by an Italian; and velvet for the Tsar and his Boyars,
gold brocades for ecclesiastical vestments, and rude kinds of glass
for ordinary purposes were manufactured under the august patronage
of the enlightened ruler. His son Alexis went a good many steps
further, and scandalised his God-fearing orthodox subjects by his
love of foreign heretical inventions. It was in his German suburb
of Moscow that young Peter, who was to be crowned "the Great," made
his first acquaintance with the useful arts of the West.
When the great reformer came to the throne he found in his Tsardom,
besides many workshops, some ten foundries, all of which were under
orders "to cast cannons, bombs, and bullets, and to make arms for
the service of the State." This seemed to him only a beginning,
especially for the mining and iron industry, in which he was
particularly interested. By importing foreign artificers and
placing at their disposal big estates, with numerous serfs, in the
districts where minerals were plentiful, and by carefully
stipulating that these foreigners should teach his subjects well,
and conceal from them none of the secrets of the craft, he created
in the Ural a great iron industry, which still exists at the
present day. Finding by experience that State mines and State
ironworks were a heavy drain on his insufficiently replenished
treasury, he transferred some of them to private persons, and this
policy was followed occasionally by his successors. Hence the
gigantic fortunes of the Demidofs and other families. The
Shuvalovs, for example, in 1760 possessed, for the purpose of
working their mines and ironworks, no less than 33,000 serfs and a
corresponding amount of land. Unfortunately the concessions were
generally given not to enterprising business-men, but to
influential court-dignitaries, who confined their attention to
squandering the revenues, and not a few of the mines and works
reverted to the Government.
The army required not only arms and ammunition, but also uniforms
and blankets. Great attention, therefore, was paid to the woollen
industry from the reign of Peter downwards. In the time of
Catherine there were already 120 cloth factories, but they were on
a very small scale, according to modern conceptions. Ten factories
in Moscow, for example, had amongst them only 104 looms, 130
workers, and a yearly output for 200,000 roubles.
While thus largely influenced in its economic policy by military
considerations, the Government did not entirely neglect other
branches of manufacturing industry. Ever since Russia had
pretensions to being a civilised power its rulers have always been
inclined to pay more attention to the ornamental than the useful--
to the varnish rather than the framework of civilisation--and we
need not therefore be surprised to find that long before the native
industry could supply the materials required for the ordinary wants
of humble life, attempts were made to produce such things as
Gobelin tapestries. I mention this merely as an illustration of a
characteristic trait of the national character, the influence of
which may be found in many other spheres of official activity.
If Russia did not attain the industrial level of Western Europe, it
was not from want of ambition and effort on the part of the rulers.
They worked hard, if not always wisely, for this end.
Manufacturers were exempted from rates and taxes, and even from
military service, and some of them, as I have said, received large
estates from the Crown on the understanding that the serfs should
be employed as workmen. At the same time they were protected from
foreign competition by prohibitive tariffs. In a word, the
manufacturing industry was nursed and fostered in a way to satisfy
the most thorough-going protectionist, especially those branches
which worked up native raw material such as ores, flax, hemp, wool,
and tallow. Occasionally the official interference and anxiety to
protect public interests went further than the manufacturers
desired. On more than one occasion the authorities fixed the price
of certain kinds of manufactured goods, and in 1754 the Senate,
being anxious to protect the population from fires, ordered all
glass and iron works within a radius of 200 versts around Moscow to
be destroyed! In spite of such obstacles, the manufacturing
industry as a whole made considerable progress. Between 1729 and
1762 the number of establishments officially recognised as
factories rose from 26 to 335.
These results did not satisfy Catherine II., who ascended the
throne in 1762. Under the influence of her friends, the French
Encyclopedistes, she imagined for a time that the official control
might be relaxed, and that the system of employing serfs in the
factories and foundries might be replaced by free labour, as in
Western Europe; monopolies might be abolished, and all liege
subjects, including the peasants, might be allowed to embark in
industrial undertakings as they pleased, "for the benefit of the
State and the nation." All this looked very well on paper, but
Catherine never allowed her sentimental liberalism to injure
seriously the interests of her Empire, and she accordingly
refrained from putting the laissez-faire principle largely into
practice. Though a good deal has been written about her economic
policy, it is hardly distinguishable from that of her predecessors.
Like them, she maintained high tariffs, accorded large subsidies,
and even prevented the export of raw material, in the hope that it
might be worked up at home; and when the prices in the woollen
market rose very high, she compelled the manufacturers to supply
the army with cloth at a price fixed by the authorities. In short,
the old system remained practically unimpaired, and notwithstanding
the steady progress made during the reign of Nicholas I. (1825-55),
when the number of factory hands rose from 210,000 to 380,000, the
manufacturing industry as a whole continued to be, until the serfs
were emancipated in 1861, a hothouse plant which could flourish
only in an officially heated atmosphere.
There was one branch of it, however, to which this remark does not
apply. The art of cotton-spinning and cotton-weaving struck deep
root in Russian soil. After remaining for generations in the
condition of a cottage industry--the yarn being distributed among
the peasants and worked up by them in their own homes--it began,
about 1825, to be modernised. Though it still required to be
protected against foreign competition, it rapidly outgrew the
necessity for direct official support. Big factories driven by
steam-power were constructed, the number of hands employed rose to
110,000, and the foundations of great fortunes were laid. Strange
to say, many of the future millionaires were uneducated serfs.
Sava Morozof, for example, who was to become one of the industrial
magnates of Moscow, was a serf belonging to a proprietor called
Ryumin; most of the others were serfs of Count Sheremetyef--the
owner of a large estate on which the industrial town of Ivanovo had
sprung up--who was proud of having millionaires among his serfs,
and who never abused his authority over them. The great movement,
however, was not effected without the assistance of foreigners.
Foreign foremen were largely employed, and in the work of
organisation a leading part was played by a German called Ludwig
Knoop. Beginning life as a commercial traveller for an English
firm, he soon became a large cotton importer, and when in 1840 a
feverish activity was produced in the Russian manufacturing world
by the Government's permission to import English machines, his firm
supplied these machines to the factories on condition of obtaining
a share in the business. It has been calculated that it obtained
in this way a share in no less than 122 factories, and hence arose
among the peasantry a popular saying:
"Where there is a church, there you find a pope,
And where there is a factory, there you find a Knoop."*
The biggest creation of the firm was a factory built at Narva in
1856, with nearly half a million spindles driven by water-power.
* Gdye tserkov--tam pop;
A gdye fabrika--tam Knop.
In the second half of last century a revolution was brought about
in the manufacturing industry generally by the emancipation of the
serfs, the rapid extension of railways, the facilities for creating
limited liability companies, and by certain innovations in the
financial policy of the Government. The emancipation put on the
market an unlimited supply of cheap labour; the construction of
railways in all directions increased a hundredfold the means of
communication; and the new banks and other credit institutions,
aided by an overwhelming influx of foreign capital, encouraged the
foundation and extension of industrial and commercial enterprise of
every description. For a time there was great excitement. It was
commonly supposed that in all matters relating to trade and
industry Russia had suddenly jumped up to the level of Western
Europe, and many people in St. Petersburg, carried away by the
prevailing enthusiasm for liberalism in general and the doctrines
of Free Trade in particular, were in favour of abolishing
protectionism as an antiquated restriction on liberty and an
obstacle to economic progress.
At one moment the Government was disposed to yield to the current,
but it was restrained by an influential group of conservative
Political Economists, who appealed to patriotic sentiment, and by
the Moscow manufacturers, who declared that Free Trade would ruin
the country. After a little hesitation it proceeded to raise,
instead of lowering, the protectionist tariff. In 1869-76 the ad
valorem duties were, on an average, under thirteen per cent., but
from that time onwards they rose steadily, until the last five
years of the century, when they averaged thirty-three per cent.,
and were for some articles very much higher. In this way the
Moscow industrial magnates were protected against the influx of
cheap foreign goods, but they were not saved from foreign
competition, for many foreign manufacturers, in order to enjoy the
benefit of the high duties, founded factories in Russia. Even the
firmly established cotton industry suffered from these intruders.
Industrial suburbs containing not a few cotton factories sprang up
around St. Petersburg; and a small Polish village called Lodz, near
the German frontier, grew rapidly into a prosperous town of 300,000
inhabitants, and became a serious rival to the ancient Muscovite
capital. So severely was the competition of this young upstart
felt, that the Moscow merchants petitioned the Emperor to protect
them by drawing a customs frontier round the Polish provinces, but
their petition was not granted.
Under the shelter of the high tariffs the manufacturing industry as
a whole has made rapid progress, and the cotton trade has kept well
to the front. In that branch, between 1861 and 1897, the number of
hands employed rose from 120,000 to 325,000, and the estimated
value of the products from 72 to 478 millions of roubles. In 1899
the number of spindles was considerably over six millions, and the
number of automatic weaving machines 145,000.
The iron industry has likewise progressed rapidly, though it has
not yet outgrown the necessity for Government support, and it is
not yet able to provide for all home wants. About forty years ago
it received a powerful impulse from the discovery that in the
provinces to the north of the Crimea and the Sea of Azof there were
enormous quantities of iron ore and beds of good coal in close
proximity to each other. Thanks to this discovery and to other
facts of which I shall have occasion to speak presently, this
district, which had previously been agricultural and pastoral, has
outstripped the famous Ural region, and has become the Black
Country of Russia. The vast lonely steppe, where formerly one saw
merely the peasant-farmer, the shepherd, and the Tchumak,* driving
along somnolently with his big, long-horned, white bullocks, is now
dotted over with busy industrial settlements of mushroom growth,
and great ironworks--some of them unfinished; while at night the
landscape is lit up with the lurid flames of gigantic blast-
furnaces. In this wonderful transformation, as in the history of
Russian industrial progress generally, a great part was played by
foreigners. The pioneer who did most in this district was an
Englishman, John Hughes, who began life as the son and pupil of a
Welsh blacksmith, and whose sons are now directors of the biggest
of the South Russian ironworks.
* The Tchumak, a familiar figure in the songs and legends of Little
Russia, was the carrier who before the construction of railways
transported the grain to the great markets, and brought back
merchandise to the interior. He is gradually disappearing.
Much as the South has progressed industrially in recent years, it
still remains far behind those industrial portions of the country
which were thickly settled at an earlier date. From this point of
view the most important region is the group of provinces clustering
round Moscow; next comes the St. Petersburg region, including
Livonia; and thirdly Poland. As for the various kinds of industry,
the most important category is that of textile fabrics, the second
that of articles of nutrition, and the third that of ores and
metals. The total production, if we may believe certain
statistical authorities, places Russia now among the industrial
nations of the world in the fifth place, immediately after the
United States, England, Germany, and France, and a little before
Austria.
The man who has in recent times carried out most energetically the
policy of protecting and fostering native industries is M. Witte, a
name now familiar to Western Europe. An avowed disciple of the
great German economist, Friedrich List, about whose works he
published a brochure in 1888, he held firmly, from his youth
upwards, the doctrine that "each nation should above all things
develop harmoniously its natural resources to the highest possible
degree of independence, protecting its own industries and
preferring the national aim to the pecuniary advantage of
individuals." As a corollary to this principle he declared that
purely agricultural countries are economically backward and
intellectually stagnant, being condemned to pay tribute to the
nations who have learned to work up their raw products into more
valuable commodities. The good old English doctrine that certain
countries were intended by Providence to be eternally agricultural,
and that their function in the economy of the universe is to supply
raw material for the industrial nations, was always in his eyes an
abomination--an ingenious, nefarious invention of the Manchester
school, astutely invented for the purpose of keeping the younger
nations permanently in a state of economic bondage for the benefit
of English manufacturers. To emancipate Russia from this thraldom
by enabling her to create a great native industry, sufficient to
supply all her own wants, was the aim of his policy and the
constant object of his untiring efforts. Those who have had the
good fortune to know him personally must have often heard him
discourse eloquently on this theme, supporting his views by
quotations from the economists of his own school, and by
illustrations drawn from the history of his own and other
countries.
A necessary condition of realising this aim was that there should
be high tariffs. These already existed, and they might be raised
still higher, but in themselves they were not enough. For the
rapid development of the native industry an enormous capital was
required, and the first problem to be solved was how this capital
could be obtained. At one moment the energetic minister conceived
the project of creating a fictitious capital by inflating the paper
currency; but this idea proved unpopular. When broached in the
Council of State it encountered determined opposition. Some of the
members of that body, especially M. Bunge, who had been himself
Minister of Finance, and who remembered the evil effects of the
inordinate inflation of the currency on foreign exchanges during
the Turkish War, advocated strongly the directly opposite course--a
return to gold monometallism, for which M. Vishnegradski, M.
Witte's immediate predecessor, had made considerable preparations.
Being a practical man without inveterate prejudices, M. Witte gave
up the scheme which he could not carry through, and adopted the
views of his opponents. He would introduce the gold currency as
recommended; but how was the requisite capital to be obtained? It
must be procured from abroad, somehow, and the simplest way seemed
to be to stimulate the export of native products. For this purpose
the railways were extended,* the traffic rates manipulated, and the
means of transport improved generally.
* In 1892, when M. Witte undertook the financial administration,
there were 30,620 versts of railway, and at the end of 1900 there
were 51,288 versts.
A certain influx of gold was thus secured, but not nearly enough
for the object in view.* Some more potent means, therefore, had to
be employed, and the inventive minister evolved a new scheme. If
he could only induce foreign capitalists to undertake manufacturing
industries in Russia, they would, at one and the same time, bring
into the country the capital required, and they would cooperate
powerfully in that development of the national industry which he so
ardently wished. No sooner had he roughly sketched out his plan--
for he was not a man to let the grass grow under his feet--than he
set himself to put it into execution by letting it be known in the
financial world that the Government was ready to open a great field
for lucrative investments, in the form of profitable enterprises
under the control of those who subscribed the capital.
* In 1891 the total value of the exports was roughly 70,000,000
pounds. It then fell, in consequence of bad harvests, to 45
millions, and did not recover the previous maximum until 1897, when
it stood at 73 millions. Thereafter there was a steady rise till
1901, when the total was estimated at 76 millions.
Foreign capitalists responded warmly to the call. Crowds of
concession-hunters, projectors, company promoters, et hoc genus
omne, collected in St. Petersburg, offering their services on the
most tempting terms; and all of them who could make out a plausible
case were well received at the Ministry of Finance. It was there
explained to them that in many branches of industry, such as the
manufacture of textile fabrics, there was little or no room for
newcomers, but that in others the prospects were most brilliant.
Take, for example, the iron industries of Southern Russia. The
boundless mineral wealth of that region was still almost intact,
and the few works which had been there established were paying very
large dividends. The works founded by John Hughes, for example,
had repeatedly divided considerably over twenty per cent., and
there was little fear for the future, because the Government had
embarked on a great scheme of railway extension, requiring an
unlimited amount of rails and rolling-stock. What better opening
could be desired? Certainly the opening seemed most attractive,
and into it rushed the crowd of company promoters, followed by
stock-jobbers and brokers, playing lively pieces of what the
Germans call Zukunftsmusik. An unwary and confiding public,
especially in Belgium and France, listened to the enchanting
strains of the financial syrens, and invested largely. Quickly the
number of completed ironworks in that region rose from nine to
seventeen, and in the short space of three years the output of pig-
iron was nearly doubled. In 1900 there were 44 blast furnaces in
working order, and ten more were in course of construction. And
all this time the Imperial revenue increased by leaps and bounds,
so that the introduction of the gold currency was effected without
difficulty. M. Witte was declared to be the greatest minister of
his time--a Russian Colbert or Turgot, or perhaps the two rolled
into one.
Then came a change. Competition and over-production led naturally
to a fall in prices, and at the same time the demand decreased,
because the railway-building activity of the Government slackened.
Alarmed at this state of things, the banks which had helped to
start and foster the huge and costly enterprises contracted their
credits. By the end of 1899 the disenchantment was general and
widespread. Some of the companies were so weighted by the
preliminary financial obligations, and had conducted their affairs
in such careless, reckless fashion, that they had soon to shut down
their mines and close their works. Even solid undertakings
suffered. The shares of the Briansk works, for example, which had
given dividends as high as 30 per cent., fell from 500 to 230. The
Mamontof companies--supposed to be one of the strongest financial
groups in the country--had to suspend payment, and numerous other
failures occurred. Nearly all the commercial banks, having
directly participated in the industrial concerns, were rudely
shaken. M. Witte, who had been for a time the idol of a certain
section of the financial world, became very unpopular, and was
accused of misleading the investing public. Among the accusations
brought against him some at least could easily be refuted. He may
have made mistakes in his policy, and may have been himself over-
sanguine, but surely, as he subsequently replied to his accusers,
it was no part of his duty to warn company promoters and directors
that they should refrain from over-production, and that their
enterprises might not be as remunerative as they expected. As to
whether there is any truth in the assertion that he held out
prospects of larger Government orders than he actually gave, I
cannot say. That he cut down prices, and showed himself a hard man
to deal with, there seems no doubt.
The reader may naturally be inclined to jump to the conclusion that
the commercial crisis just referred to was the cause of M. Witte's
fall. Such a conclusion would be entirely erroneous. The crisis
happened in the winter of 1899-1900, and M. Witte remained Finance
Minister until the autumn of 1903. His fall was the result of
causes of a totally different kind, and these I propose now to
explain, because the explanation will throw light on certain very
curious and characteristic conceptions at present current in the
Russian educated classes.
Of course there were certain causes of a purely personal kind, but
I shall dismiss them in a very few words. I remember once asking a
well-informed friend of M. Witte's what he thought of him as an
administrator and a statesman. The friend replied: "Imagine a
negro of the Gold Coast let loose in modern European civilisation!"
This reply, like most epigrammatic remarks, is a piece of gross
exaggeration, but it has a modicum of truth in it. In the eyes of
well-trained Russian officials M. Witte was a titanic, reckless
character, capable at any moment of playing the part of the bull in
the china-shop. As a masterful person, brusque in manner and
incapable of brooking contradiction, he had made for himself many
enemies; and his restless, irrepressible energy had led him to
encroach on the provinces of all his colleagues. Possessing as he
did the control of the purse, his interference could not easily be
resisted. The Ministers of Interior, War, Agriculture, Public
Works, Public Instruction, and Foreign Affairs had all occasion to
complain of his incursions into their departments. In contrast to
his colleagues, he was not only extremely energetic, but he was
ever ready to assume an astounding amount of responsibility; and as
he was something of an opportunist, he was perhaps not always
quixotically scrupulous in the choice of expedients for attaining
his ends.
Altogether M. Witte was an inconvenient personage in an
administration in which strong personality is regarded as entirely
out of place, and in which personal initiative is supposed to
reside exclusively in the Tsar. In addition to all this he was a
man who felt keenly, and when he was irritated he did not always
keep the unruly member under strict control. If I am correctly
informed, it was some imprudent and not very respectful remarks,
repeated by a subordinate and transmitted by a Grand Duke to the
Tsar, which were the immediate cause of his transfer from the
influential post of Minister of Finance to the ornamental position
of President of the Council of Ministers; but that was merely the
proverbial last straw that broke the camel's back. His position
was already undermined, and it is the undermining process which I
wish to describe.
The first to work for his overthrow were the Agrarian
Conservatives. They could not deny that, from the purely fiscal
point of view, his administration was a marvellous success; for he
was rapidly doubling the revenue, and he had succeeded in replacing
the fluctuating depreciated paper currency by a gold coinage; but
they maintained that he was killing the goose that laid the golden
eggs. Evidently the tax-paying power of the rural classes was
being overstrained, for they were falling more and more into
arrears in the payment of their taxes, and their impoverishment was
yearly increasing. All their reserves had been exhausted, as was
shown by the famines of 1891-92, when the Government had to spend
hundreds of millions to feed them. Whilst the land was losing its
fertility, those who had to live by it were increasing in numbers
at an alarming rate. Already in some districts one-fifth of the
peasant households had no longer any land of their own, and of
those who still possessed land a large proportion had no longer the
cattle and horses necessary to till and manure their allotments.
No doubt M. Witte was beginning to perceive his mistake, and had
done something to palliate the evils by improving the system of
collecting the taxes and abolishing the duty on passports, but such
merely palliative remedies could have little effect. While a few
capitalists were amassing gigantic fortunes, the masses were slowly
and surely advancing to the brink of starvation. The welfare of
the agriculturists, who constitute nine-tenths of the whole
population, was being ruthlessly sacrificed, and for what? For the
creation of a manufacturing industry which rested on an artificial,
precarious basis, and which had already begun to decline.
So far the Agrarians, who champion the interests of the
agricultural classes. Their views were confirmed and their
arguments strengthened by an influential group of men whom I may
call, for want of a better name, the philosophers or doctrinaire
interpreters of history, who have, strange to say, more influence
in Russia than in any other country.
The Russian educated classes desire that the nation should be
wealthy and self-supporting, and they recognise that for this
purpose a large manufacturing industry is required; but they are
reluctant to make the sacrifices necessary to attain the object in
view, and they imagine that, somehow or other, these sacrifices may
be avoided. Sympathising with this frame of mind, the doctrinaires
explain that the rich and prosperous countries of Europe and
America obtained their wealth and prosperity by so-called
"Capitalism"--that is to say, by a peculiar social organisation in
which the two main factors are a small body of rich capitalists and
manufacturers and an enormous pauper proletariat living from hand
to mouth, at the mercy of the heartless employers of labour.
Russia has lately followed in the footsteps of those wealthy
countries, and if she continues to do so she will inevitably be
saddled with the same disastrous results--plutocracy, pauperism,
unrestrained competition in all spheres of activity, and a greatly
intensified struggle for life, in which the weaker will necessarily
go to the wall.*
* Free competition in all spheres of activity, leading to social
inequality, plutocracy, and pauperism, is the favourite bugbear of
Russian theorists; and who is not a theorist in Russia? The fact
indicates the prevalence of Socialist ideas in the educated
classes.
Happily there is, according to these theorists, a more excellent
way, and Russia can adopt it if she only remains true to certain
mysterious principles of her past historic development. Without
attempting to expound those mysterious principles, to which I have
repeatedly referred in previous chapters, I may mention briefly
that the traditional patriarchal institutions on which the
theorists found their hopes of a happy social future for their
country are the rural Commune, the native home-industries, and the
peculiar co-operative institutions called Artels. How these
remnants of a semi-patriarchal state of society are to be
practically developed in such a way as to withstand the competition
of manufacturing industry organised on modern "capitalist" lines,
no one has hitherto been able to explain satisfactorily, but many
people indulge in ingenious speculations on the subject, like
children planning the means of diverting with their little toy
spades a formidable inundation. In my humble opinion, the whole
theory is a delusion; but it is held firmly--I might almost say
fanatically--by those who, in opposition to the indiscriminate
admirers of West-European and American civilisation, consider
themselves genuine Russians and exceptionally good patriots. M.
Witte has never belonged to that class. He believes that there is
only one road to national prosperity--the road by which Western
Europe has travelled--and along this road he tried to drive his
country as rapidly as possible. He threw himself, therefore, heart
and soul into what his opponents call "Capitalism," by raising
State loans, organising banks and other credit institutions,
encouraging the creation and extension of big factories, which must
inevitably destroy the home industry, and even--horribile dictu!--
undermining the rural Commune, and thereby adding to the ranks of
the landless proletariat, in order to increase the amount of cheap
labour for the benefit of the capitalists.
With the arguments thus supplied by Agrarians and doctrinaires,
quite honest and well-meaning, according to their lights, it was
easy to sap M. Witte's position. Among his opponents, the most
formidable was the late M. Plehve, Minister of Interior--a man of a
totally different stamp. A few months before his tragic end I had
a long and interesting conversation with him, and I came away
deeply impressed. Having repeatedly had conversations of a similar
kind with M. Witte, I could compare, or rather contrast, the two
men. Both of them evidently possessed an exceptional amount of
mental power and energy, but in the one it was volcanic, and in the
other it was concentrated and thoroughly under control. In
discussion, the one reminded me of the self-taught, slashing
swordsman; the other of the dexterous fencer, carefully trained in
the use of the foils, who never launches out beyond the point at
which he can quickly recover himself. As to whether M. Plehve was
anything more than a bold, energetic, clever official there may be
differences of opinion, but he certainly could assume the airs of a
profound and polished statesman, capable of looking at things from
a much higher point of view than the ordinary tchinovnik, and he
had the talent of tacitly suggesting that a great deal of genuine,
enlightened statesmanship lay hidden under the smooth surface of
his cautious reserve. Once or twice I could perceive that when
criticising the present state of things he had his volcanic
colleague in his mind's eye; but the covert allusions were so vague
and so carefully worded that the said colleague, if he had been
present, would hardly have been justified in entering a personal
protest. A statesman of the higher type, I was made to feel,
should deal not with personalities, but with things, and it would
be altogether unbecoming to complain of a colleague in presence of
an outsider. Thus his attitude towards his opponent was most
correct, but it was not difficult to infer that he had little
sympathy with the policy of the Ministry of Finance.
From other sources I learned the cause of this want of sympathy.
Being Minister of Interior, and having served long in the Police
Department, M. Plehve considered that his first duty was the
maintenance of public order and the protection of the person and
autocracy of his august master. He was therefore the determined
enemy of revolutionary tendencies, in whatever garb or disguise
they might appear; and as a statesman he had to direct his
attention to everything likely to increase those tendencies in the
future. Now it seemed that in the financial policy which had been
followed for some years there were germs of future revolutionary
fermentation. The peasantry were becoming impoverished, and were
therefore more likely to listen to the insidious suggestions of
Socialist agitators; and already agrarian disturbances had occurred
in the provinces of Kharkof and Poltava. The industrial
proletariat which was being rapidly created was being secretly
organised by the revolutionary Social Democrats, and already there
had been serious labour troubles in some of the large towns. For
any future revolutionary movement the proletariat would naturally
supply recruits. Then, at the other end of the social scale, a
class of rich capitalists was being created, and everybody who has
read a little history knows that a rich and powerful tiers etat
cannot be permanently conciliated with autocracy. Though himself
neither an agrarian nor a Slavophil doctrinaire, M. Plehve could
not but have a certain sympathy with those who were forging
thunderbolts for the official annihilation of M. Witte. He was too
practical a man to imagine that the hands on the dial of economic
progress could be set back and a return made to moribund
patriarchal institutions; but he thought that at least the pace
might be moderated. The Minister of Finance need not be in such a
desperate, reckless hurry, and it was desirable to create
conservative forces which might counteract the revolutionary forces
which his impulsive colleague was inadvertently calling into
existence.
Some of the forgers of thunderbolts went a great deal further, and
asserted or insinuated that M. Witte was himself consciously a
revolutionist, with secret, malevolent intentions. In support of
their insinuations they cited certain cases in which well-known
Socialists had been appointed professors in academies under the
control of the Ministry of Finance, and they pointed to the Peasant
Bank, which enjoyed M. Witte's special protection. At first it had
been supposed that the bank would have an anti-revolutionary
influence by preventing the formation of a landless proletariat and
increasing the number of small land-owners, who are always and
everywhere conservative so far as the rights of private property
are concerned.
Unfortunately its success roused the fears of the more conservative
section of the landed proprietors. These gentlemen, as I have
already mentioned, pointed out that the estates of the nobles were
rapidly passing into the hands of the peasantry, and that if this
process were allowed to continue the hereditary Noblesse, which had
always been the civilising element in the rural population, and the
surest support of the throne, would drift into the towns and there
sink into poverty or amalgamate with the commercial plutocracy, and
help to form a tiers etat which would be hostile to the Autocratic
Power.
In these circumstances it was evident that the headstrong Minister
of Finance could maintain his position only so long as he enjoyed
the energetic support of the Emperor, and this support, for reasons
which I have indicated above, failed him at the critical moment.
When his work was still unfinished he was suddenly compelled, by
the Emperor's command, to relinquish his post and accept a position
in which, it was supposed, he would cease to have any influence in
the administration.
Thus fell the Russian Colbert-Turgot, or whatever else he may be
called. Whether financial difficulties in the future will lead to
his reinstatement as Minister of Finance remains to be seen; but in
any case his work cannot be undone. He has increased manufacturing
industry to an unprecedented extent, and, as M. Plehve perceived,
the industrial proletariat which manufacturing industry on
capitalist lines always creates has provided a new field of
activity for the revolutionists. I return, therefore, to the
evolution of the revolutionary movement in order to describe its
present phase, the first-fruits of which have been revealed in the
labour disturbances in St. Petersburg and other industrial centres.
CHAPTER XXXVII
THE REVOLUTIONARY MOVEMENT IN ITS LATEST PHASE
Influence of Capitalism and Proletariat on the Revolutionary
Movement--What is to be Done?--Reply of Plekhanof--A New Departure--
Karl Marx's Theories Applied to Russia--Beginnings of a Social
Democratic Movement--The Labour Troubles of 1894-96 in St.
Petersburg--The Social Democrats' Plan of Campaign--Schism in the
Party--Trade-unionism and Political Agitation--The Labour Troubles
of 1902--How the Revolutionary Groups are Differentiated from Each
Other--Social Democracy and Constitutionalism--Terrorism--The
Socialist Revolutionaries--The Militant Organisation--Attitude of
the Government--Factory Legislation--Government's Scheme for
Undermining Social Democracy--Father Gapon and His Labour
Association--The Great Strike in St. Petersburg--Father Gapon goes
over to the Revolutionaries.
The development of manufacturing industry on capitalist lines, and
the consequent formation of a large industrial proletariat,
produced great disappointment in all the theorising sections of the
educated classes. The thousands of men and women who had, since
the accession of the Tsar-Emancipator in 1855, taken a keen,
enthusiastic interest in the progress of their native country, all
had believed firmly that in some way or other Russia would escape
"the festering sores of Western civilisation." Now experience had
proved that the belief was an illusion, and those who had tried to
check the natural course of industrial progress were constrained to
confess that their efforts had been futile. Big factories were
increasing in size and numbers, while cottage industries were
disappearing or falling under the power of middlemen, and the
Artels had not advanced a step in their expected development. The
factory workers, though all of peasant origin, were losing their
connection with their native villages and abandoning their
allotments of the Communal land. They were becoming, in short, a
hereditary caste in the town population, and the pleasant Slavophil
dream of every factory worker having a house in the country was
being rudely dispelled. Nor was there any prospect of a change for
the better in the future. With the increase of competition among
the manufacturers, the uprooting of the muzhik from the soil must
go on more and more rapidly, because employers must insist more and
more on having thoroughly trained operatives ready to work steadily
all the year round.
This state of things had a curious effect on the course of the
revolutionary movement.
Let me recall very briefly the successive stages through which the
movement had already passed. It had been inaugurated, as we have
seen, by the Nihilists, the ardent young representatives of a
"storm-and-stress" period, in which the venerable traditions and
respected principles of the past were rejected and ridiculed, and
the newest ideas of Western Europe were eagerly adopted and
distorted. Like the majority of their educated countrymen, they
believed that in the race of progress Russia was about to overtake
and surpass the nations of the West, and that this desirable result
was to be attained by making a tabula rasa of existing
institutions, and reconstructing society according to the plans of
Proudhon, Fourier, and the other writers of the early Socialist
school.
When the Nihilists had expended their energies and exhausted the
patience of the public in theorising, talking, and writing, a party
of action came upon the scene. Like the Nihilists, they desired
political, social, and economic reforms of the most thorough-going
kind, but they believed that such things could not be effected by
the educated classes alone, and they determined to call in the co-
operation of the people. For this purpose they tried to convert
the masses to the gospel of Socialism. Hundreds of them became
missionaries and "went in among the people." But the gospel of
Socialism proved unintelligible to the uneducated, and the more
ardent, incautious missionaries fell into the hands of the police.
Those of them who escaped, perceiving the error of their ways, but
still clinging to the hope of bringing about a political, social,
and economic revolution, determined to change their tactics. The
emancipated serf had shown himself incapable of "prolonged
revolutionary activity," but there was reason to believe that he
was, like his forefathers in the time of Stenka Razin and
Pugatcheff, capable of rising and murdering his oppressors. He
must be used, therefore, for the destruction of the Autocratic
Power and the bureaucracy, and then it would be easy to reorganise
society on a basis of universal equality, and to take permanent
precautions against capitalism and the creation of a proletariat.
The hopes of the agitators proved as delusive as those of the
propagandists. The muzhik turned a deaf ear to their instigations,
and the police soon prevented their further activity. Thus the
would-be root-and-branch reforms found themselves in a dilemma.
Either they must abandon their schemes for the moment or they must
strike immediately at their persecutors. They chose, as we have
seen, the latter alternative, and after vain attempts to frighten
the Government by acts of terrorism against zealous officials, they
assassinated the Tsar himself; but before they had time to think of
the constructive part of their task, their organisation was
destroyed by the Autocratic Power and the bureaucracy, and those of
them who escaped arrest had to seek safety in emigration to
Switzerland and Paris.
Then arose, all along the line of the defeated, decimated
revolutionists, the cry, "What is to be done?" Some replied that
the shattered organisation should be reconstructed, and a number of
secret agents were sent successively from Switzerland for this
purpose. But their efforts, as they themselves confessed, were
fruitless, and despondency seemed to be settling down permanently
on all, except a few fanatics, when a voice was heard calling on
the fugitives to rally round a new banner and carry on the struggle
by entirely new methods. The voice came from a revolutionologist
(if I may use such a term) of remarkable talent, called M.
Plekhanof, who had settled in Geneva with a little circle of
friends, calling themselves the "Labour Emancipation Group." His
views were expounded in a series of interesting publications, the
first of which was a brochure entitled "Socialism and the Political
Struggle," published in 1883.
According to M. Plekhanof and his group the revolutionary movement
had been conducted up to that moment on altogether wrong lines.
All previous revolutionary groups had acted on the assumption that
the political revolution and the economic reorganisation of society
must be effected simultaneously, and consequently they had rejected
contemptuously all proposals for reforms, however radical, of a
merely political kind. These had been considered, as I have
mentioned in a previous chapter, not only as worthless, but as
positively prejudicial to the interests of the working classes,
because so-called political liberties and parliamentary government
would be sure to consolidate the domination of the bourgeoisie.
That such has generally been the immediate effect of parliamentary
institutions is undeniable, but it did not follow that the creation
of such institutions should be opposed. On the contrary, they
ought to be welcomed, not merely because, as some revolutionists
had already pointed out, propaganda and agitation could be more
easily carried on under a constitutional regime, but because
constitutionalism is certainly the most convenient, and perhaps the
only, road by which the socialistic ideal can ultimately be
attained. This is a dark saying, but it will become clearer when I
have explained, according to the new apostles, a second error into
which their predecessors had fallen.
That second error was the assumption that all true friends of the
people, whether Conservatives, Liberals, or revolutionaries, ought
to oppose to the utmost the development of capitalism. In the
light of Karl Marx's discoveries in economic science every one must
recognise this to be an egregious mistake. That great authority,
it was said, had proved that the development of capitalism was
irresistible, and his conclusions had been confirmed by the recent
history of Russia, for all the economic progress made during the
last half century had been on capitalist lines.
Even if it were possible to arrest the capitalist movement, it is
not desirable from the revolutionary point of view. In support of
this thesis Karl Marx is again cited. He has shown that
capitalism, though an evil in itself, is a necessary stage of
economic and social progress. At first it is prejudicial to the
interests of the working classes, but in the long run it benefits
them, because the ever-growing proletariat must, whether it desires
it or not, become a political party, and as a political party it
must one day break the domination of the bourgeoisie. As soon as
it has obtained the predominant political power, it will
confiscate, for the public good, the instruments of production--
factories, foundries, machines, etc.--by expropriating the
capitalist. In this way all the profits which accrue from
production on a large scale, and which at present go into the
pockets of the capitalists, will be distributed equally among the
workmen.
Thus began a new phase of the revolutionary movement, and, like all
previous phases, it remained for some years in the academic stage,
during which there were endless discussions on theoretical and
practical questions. Lavroff, the prophet of the old propaganda,
treated the new ideas "with grandfatherly severity," and
Tikhomirof, the leading representative of the moribund Narodnaya
Volya, which had prepared the acts of terrorism, maintained stoutly
that the West European methods recommended by Plekhanof were
inapplicable to Russia. The Plekhanof group replied in a long
series of publications, partly original and partly translations
from Marx and Engels, explaining the doctrines and aims of the
Social Democrats.
Seven years were spent in this academic literary activity--a period
of comparative repose for the Russian secret police--and about 1890
the propagandists of the new school began to work cautiously in St.
Petersburg. At first they confined themselves to forming little
secret circles for making converts, and they found that the ground
had been to some extent prepared for the seed which they had to
sow. The workmen were discontented, and some of the more
intelligent amongst them who had formerly been in touch with the
propagandists of the older generation had learned that there was an
ingenious and effective means of getting their grievances
redressed. How was that possible? By combination and strikes.
For the uneducated workers this was an important discovery, and
they soon began to put the suggested remedy to a practical test.
In the autumn of 1894 labour troubles broke out in the Nevski
engineering works and the arsenal, and in the following year in the
Thornton factory and the cigarette works. In all these strikes the
Social Democratic agents took part behind the scenes. Avoiding the
main errors of the old propagandists, who had offered the workmen
merely abstract Socialist theories which no uneducated person could
reasonably be expected to understand, they adopted a more rational
method. Though impervious to abstract theories, the Russian
workman is not at all insensible to the prospect of bettering his
material condition and getting his everyday grievances redressed.
Of these grievances the ones he felt most keenly were the long
hours, the low wages, the fines arbitrarily imposed by the
managers, and the brutual severity of the foreman. By helping him
to have these grievances removed the Social Democratic agents might
gain his confidence, and when they had come to be regarded by him
as his real friends they might widen his sympathies and teach him
to feel that his personal interests were identical with the
interests of the working classes as a whole. In this way it would
be possible to awaken in the industrial proletariat generally a
sort of esprit de corps, which is the first condition of political
organisation.
On these lines the agents set to work. Having formed themselves
into a secret association called the "Union for the Emancipation of
the Working Classes," they gradually abandoned the narrow limits of
coterie-propaganda, and prepared the way for agitation on a larger
scale. Among the discontented workmen they distributed a large
number of carefully written tracts, in which the material
grievances were formulated, and the whole political system, with
its police, gendarmes, Cossacks, and tax-gathers, was criticised in
no friendly spirit, but without violent language. In introducing
into the programme this political element, great caution had to be
exercised, because the workmen did not yet perceive clearly any
close connection between their grievances and the existing
political institutions, and those of them who belonged to the older
generation regarded the Tsar as the incarnation of disinterested
benevolence. Bearing this in mind, the Union circulated a pamphlet
for the enlightenment of the labouring population, in which the
writer refrained from all reference to the Autocratic Power, and
described simply the condition of the labouring classes, the heavy
burdens they had to bear, the abuses of which they were the
victims, and the inconsiderate way in which they were treated by
their employers. This pamphlet was eagerly read, and from that
moment whenever labour troubles arose the men applied to the Social
Democratic agents to assist them in formulating their grievances.
Of course, the assistance had to be given secretly, because there
were always police spies in the factories, and all persons
suspected of aiding the labour movement were liable to be arrested
and exiled. In spite of this danger the work was carried on with
great energy, and in the summer of 1896 the field of operations was
extended. During the coronation ceremonies of that year the
factories and workshops in St. Petersburg were closed, and the men
considered that for these days they ought to receive wages as
usual. When their demand was refused, 40,000 of them went out on
strike. The Social Democratic Union seized the opportunity and
distributed tracts in large quantities. For the first time such
tracts were read aloud at workmen's meetings and applauded by the
audience. The Union encouraged the workmen in their resistance,
but advised them to refrain from violence, so as not to provoke the
intervention of the police and the military, as they had
imprudently done on some previous occasions. When the police did
intervene and expelled some of the strike-leaders from St.
Petersburg, the agitators had an excellent opportunity of
explaining that the authorities were the protectors of the
employers and the enemies of the working classes. These
explanations counteracted the effect of an official proclamation to
the workmen, in which M. Witte tried to convince them that the Tsar
was constantly striving to improve their condition. The struggle
was decided, not by arguments and exhortations, but by a more
potent force; having no funds for continuing the strike, the men
were compelled by starvation to resume work.
This is the point at which the labour movement began to be
conducted on a large scale and by more systematic methods. In the
earlier labour troubles the strikers had not understood that the
best means of bringing pressure on employers was simply to refuse
to work, and they had often proceeded to show their dissatisfaction
by ruthlessly destroying their employers' property. This had
brought the police, and sometimes the military, on the scene, and
numerous arrests had followed. Another mistake made by the
inexperienced strikers was that they had neglected to create a
reserve fund from which they could draw the means of subsistence
when they no longer received wages and could no longer obtain
credit at the factory provision store. Efforts were now made to
correct these two mistakes, and with regard to the former they were
fairly successful, for wanton destruction of property ceased to be
a prominent feature of labour troubles; but strong reserve funds
have not yet been created, so that the strikes have never been of
long duration.
Though the strikes had led, so far, to no great practical, tangible
results, the new ideas and aspirations were spreading rapidly in
the factories and workshops, and they had already struck such deep
root that some of the genuine workmen wished to have a voice in the
managing committee of the Union, which was composed exclusively of
educated men. When a request to that effect was rejected by the
committee a lengthy discussion took place, and it soon became
evident that underneath the question of organisation lay a most
important question of principle. The workmen wished to concentrate
their efforts on the improvement of their material condition, and
to proceed on what we should call trade-unionist lines, whereas the
committee wished them to aim also at the acquisition of political
rights. Great determination was shown on both sides. An attempt
of the workmen to maintain a secret organ of their own with the
view of emancipating themselves from the "Politicals" ended in
failure; but they received sympathy and support from some of the
educated members of the party, and in this way a schism took place
in the Social Democrat camp. After repeated ineffectual attempts
to find a satisfactory compromise, the question was submitted to a
Congress which was held in Switzerland in 1900; but the discussions
merely accentuated the differences of opinion, and the two parties
constituted themselves into separate independent groups. The one
under the leadership of Plekhanof, and calling itself the
Revolutionary Social Democrats, held to the Marx doctrines in all
their extent and purity, and maintained the necessity of constant
agitation in the political sense. The other, calling itself the
Union of Foreign Social Democrats, inclined to the trade-unionism
programme, and proclaimed the necessity of being guided by
political expediency rather than inflexible dogmas. Between the
two a wordy warfare was carried on for some time in pedantic,
technical language; but though habitually brandishing their weapons
and denouncing their antagonists in true Homeric style, they were
really allies, struggling towards a common end--two sections of the
Social Democratic party differing from each other on questions of
tactics.
The two divergent tendencies have often reappeared in the
subsequent history of the movement. During ordinary peaceful times
the economic or trade-unionist tendency can generally hold its own,
but as soon as disturbances occur and the authorities have to
intervene, the political current quickly gains the upper hand.
This was exemplified in the labour troubles which took place at
Rostoff-on-the-Don in 1902. During the first two days of the
strike the economic demands alone were put forward, and in the
speeches which were delivered at the meetings of workmen no
reference was made to political grievances. On the third day one
orator ventured to speak disrespectfully of the Autocratic Power,
but he thereby provoked signs of dissatisfaction in the audiences.
On the fifth and following days, however, several political
speeches were made, ending with the cry of "Down with Tsarism!" and
a crowd of 30,000 workmen agreed with the speakers. Thereafter
occurred similar strikes in Odessa, the Caucasus, Kief, and Central
Russia, and they had all a political rather than a purely economic
character.
I must now endeavour to explain clearly the point of view and plan
of campaign of this new movement, which I may call the
revolutionary Renaissance.
The ultimate aim of the new reformers was the same as that of all
their predecessors--the thorough reorganisation of Society on
Socialistic principles. According to their doctrines, Society as
at present constituted consists of two great classes, called
variously the exploiters and the exploited, the shearers and the
shorn, the capitalists and the workers, the employers and the
employed, the tyrants and the oppressed; and this unsatisfactory
state of things must go on so long as the so-called bourgeois or
capitalist regime continues to exist. In the new heaven and the
new earth of which the Socialist dreams this unjust distinction is
to disappear; all human beings are to be equally free and
independent, all are to cooperate spontaneously with brains and
hands to the common good, and all are to enjoy in equal shares the
natural and artificial good things of this life.
So far there has never been any difference of opinion among the
various groups of Russian thorough-going revolutionists. All of
them, from the antiquated Nihilist down to the Social Democrat of
the latest type, have held these views. What has differentiated
them from each other is the greater or less degree of impatience to
realise the ideal.
The most impatient were the Anarchists, who grouped themselves
around Bakunin. They wished to overthrow immediately by a frontal
attack all existing forms of government and social organisation, in
the hope that chance, or evolution, or natural instinct, or sudden
inspiration or some other mysterious force, would create something
better. They themselves declined to aid this mysterious force even
by suggestions, on the ground that, as one of them has said, "to
construct is not the business of the generation whose duty is to
destroy." Notwithstanding the strong impulsive element in the
national character, the reckless, ultra-impatient doctrinaires
never became numerous, and never succeeded in forming an organised
group, probably because the young generation in Russia were too
much occupied with the actual and future condition of their own
country to embark on schemes of cosmopolitan anarchism such as
Bakunin recommended.
Next in the scale of impatience came the group of believers in
Socialist agitation among the masses, with a view to overturning
the existing Government and putting themselves in its place as soon
as the masses were sufficiently organised to play the part destined
for them. Between them and the Anarchists the essential points of
difference were that they admitted the necessity of some years of
preparation, and they intended, when the Government was overturned,
not to preserve indefinitely the state of anarchy, but to put in
the place of autocracy, limited monarchy, or the republic, a
strong, despotic Government thoroughly imbued with Socialistic
principles. As soon as it had laid firmly the foundations of the
new order of things it was to call a National Assembly, from which
it was to receive, I presume, a bill of indemnity for the
benevolent tyranny which it had temporarily exercised.
Impatience a few degrees less intense produced the next group, the
partisans of pacific Socialist propaganda. They maintained that
there was no necessity for overthrowing the old order of things
till the masses had been intellectually prepared for the new, and
they objected to the foundation of the new regime being laid by
despots, however well-intentioned in the Socialist sense. The
people must be made happy and preserved in a state of happiness by
the people themselves.
In the last place came the least impatient of all, the Social
Democrats, who differ widely from all the preceding categories.
All previous revolutionary groups had systematically rejected the
idea of a gradual transition from the bourgeois to the Socialist
regime. They would not listen to any suggestion about a
constitutional monarchy or a democratic republic even as a mere
intermediate stage of social development. All such things, as part
and parcel of the bourgeois system, were anathematised. There must
be no half-way houses between present misery and future happiness;
for many weary travellers might be tempted to settle there in the
desert, and fail to reach the promised land. "Ever onward" should
be the watchword, and no time should be wasted on the foolish
struggles of political parties and the empty vanities of political
life.
Not thus thought the Social Democrat. He was much wiser in his
generation. Having seen how the attempts of the impatient groups
had ended in disaster, and knowing that, if they had succeeded, the
old effete despotism would probably have been replaced by a young,
vigorous one more objectionable than its predecessor, he determined
to try a more circuitous but surer road to the goal which the
impatient people had in view. In his opinion the distance from the
present Russian regime protected by autocracy to the future
Socialist paradise was far too great to be traversed in a single
stage, and he knew of one or two comfortable rest-houses on the
way. First there was the rest-house of Constitutionalism, with
parliamentary institutions. For some years the bourgeoisie would
doubtless have a parliamentary majority, but gradually, by
persistent effort, the Fourth Estate would gain the upper hand, and
then the Socialist millennium might be proclaimed. Meanwhile, what
had to be done was to gain the confidence of the masses, especially
of the factory workers, who were more intelligent and less
conservative than the peasantry, and to create powerful labour
organisations as material for a future political party.
This programme implied, of course, a certain unity of action with
the constitutionalists, from whom, as I have said, the
revolutionists of the old school had stood sternly aloof. There
was now no question of a formal union, and certainly no idea of a
"union of hearts," because the Socialists knew that their ultimate
aim would be strenuously opposed by the Liberals, and the Liberals
knew that an attempt was being made to use them as a cat's-paw; but
there seemed to be no reason why they of the two groups should not
observe towards each other a benevolent neutrality, and march side
by side as far as the half-way house, where they could consider the
conditions of the further advance.
When I first became acquainted with the Russian Social Democrats I
imagined that their plan of campaign was of a purely pacific
character; and that they were, unlike their predecessors, an
evolutionary, as distinguished from a revolutionary, party.
Subsequently I discovered that this conception was not quite
accurate. In ordinary quiet times they use merely pacific methods,
and they feel that the Proletariat is not yet sufficiently
prepared, intellectually and politically, to assume the great
responsibilities which are reserved for it in the future.
Moreover, when the moment comes for getting rid of the Autocratic
Power, they would prefer a gradual process of liquidation to a
sudden cataclysm. So far they may be said to be evolutionaries
rather than revolutionaries, but their plan of campaign does not
entirely exclude violence. They would not consider it their duty
to oppose the use of violence on the part of the more impatient
sections of the revolutionists, and they would have no scruples
about utilising disturbances for the attainment of their own end.
Public agitation, which is always likely in Russia to provoke
violent repression by the authorities, they regard as necessary for
keeping alive and strengthening the spirit of opposition; and when
force is used by the police they approve of the agitators using
force in return. To acts of terrorism, however, they are opposed
on principle.
Who, then, are the Terrorists, who have assassinated so many great
personages, including the Grand Duke Serge? In reply to this
question I must introduce the reader to another group of the
revolutionists who have usually been in hostile, rather than
friendly, relations with the Social Democrats, and who call
themselves the Socialist-Revolutionaries (Sotsialisty-
Revolutsionery).
It will be remembered that the terrorist group, commonly called
Narodnaya Volya, or Narodovoltsi, which succeeded in assassinating
Alexander II., were very soon broken up by the police and most of
the leading members were arrested. A few escaped, of whom some
remained in the country and others emigrated to Switzerland or
Paris, and efforts at reorganisation were made, especially in the
southern and western provinces, but they proved ineffectual. At
last, sobered by experience and despairing of further success, some
of the prisoners and a few of the exiles--notably Tikhomirof, who
was regarded as the leader--made their peace with the Government,
and for some years terrorism seemed to be a thing of the past.
Passing through Russia on my way home from India and Central Asia
at that time, I came to the conclusion that the young generation
had recovered from its prolonged attack of brain-fever, and had
entered on a more normal, tranquil, and healthy period of
existence.
My expectations proved too optimistic. About 1894 the Narodnaya
Volya came to life again, with all its terrorist traditions intact;
and shortly afterwards appeared the new group which I have just
mentioned, the Socialist-Revolutionaries, with somewhat similar
principles and a better organisation. For some seven or eight
years the two groups existed side by side, and then the Narodnaya
Volya disappeared, absorbed probably by its more powerful rival.
During the first years of their existence neither group was strong
enough to cause the Government serious inconvenience, and it was
not till 1897-98 that they found means of issuing manifestos and
programmes. In these the Narodovoltsi declared that their
immediate aims were the annihilation of Autocracy, the convocation
of a National Assembly and the reorganisation of the Empire on the
principles of federation and local self-government, and that for
the attainment of these objects the means to be employed should
include popular insurrections, military conspiracies, bombs and
dynamite.
Very similar, though ostensibly a little more eclectic, was the
programme of the Socialist-Revolutionaries. Their ultimate aim was
declared to be the transfer of political authority from the
Autocratic Power to the people, the abolition of private property
in the means of production, and in general the reorganisation of
national life on Socialist principles. On certain points they were
at one with the Social Democrats. They recognised, for example,
that the social reorganisation must be preceded by a political
revolution, that much preparatory work was necessary, and that
attention should be directed first to the industrial proletariat as
the most intelligent section of the masses. On the other hand they
maintained that it was a mistake to confine the revolutionary
activity to the working classes of the towns, who were not strong
enough to overturn the Autocratic Power. The agitation ought,
therefore, to be extended to the peasantry, who were quite
"developed" enough to understand at least the idea of land-
nationalisation; and for the carrying out of this part of the
programme a special organisation was created.
With so many opinions in common, it seemed at one moment as if the
Social Democrats and the Socialist-Revolutionaries might unite
their forces for a combined attack on the Government; but apart
from the mutual jealousy and hatred which so often characterise
revolutionary as well as religious sects, they were prevented from
coalescing, or even cordially co-operating, by profound differences
both in doctrine and in method.
The Social Democrats are essentially doctrinaires. Thorough-going
disciples of Karl Marx, they believed in what they consider the
immutable laws of social progress, according to which the
Socialistic ideal can be reached only through capitalism; and the
intermediate political revolution, which is to substitute the will
of the people for the Autocratic Power, must be effected by the
conversion and organisation of the industrial proletariat. With
the spiritual pride of men who feel themselves to be the
incarnations or avatars of immutable law, they are inclined to look
down with something very like contempt on mere empirics who are
ignorant of scientific principles and are guided by considerations
of practical expediency. The Social-Revolutionaries seem to them
to be empirics of this kind because they reject the tenets, or at
least deny the infallibility, of the Marx school, cling to the idea
of partially resisting the overwhelming influence of capitalism in
Russia, hope that the peasantry will play at least a secondary part
in bringing about the political revolution, and are profoundly
convinced that the advent of political liberty may be greatly
accelerated by the use of terrorism. On this last point they
stated their views very frankly in a pamphlet which they published
in 1902 under the title of "Our Task" (Nasha Zadatcha). It is
there said:
"One of the powerful means of struggle, dictated by our
revolutionary past and present, is political terrorism, consisting
of the annihilation of the most injurious and influential
personages of Russian autocracy in given conditions. Systematic
terrorism, in conjunction with other forms of open mass-struggle
(industrial riots and agrarian risings, demonstrations, etc.),
which receive from terrorism an enormous, decisive significance,
will lead to the disorganisation of the enemy. Terrorist activity
will cease only with the victory over autocracy and the complete
attainment of political liberty. Besides its chief significance as
a means of disorganising, terrorist activity will serve at the same
time as a means of propaganda and agitation, a form of open
struggle taking place before the eyes of the whole people,
undermining the prestige of Government authority, and calling into
life new revolutionary forces, while the oral and literary
propaganda is being continued without interruption. Lastly, the
terrorist activity serves for the whole secret revolutionary party
as a means of self-defence and of protecting the organisation
against the injurious elements of spies and treachery."
In accordance with this theory a "militant organisation" (Boevaga
Organisatsia) was formed and soon set to work with revolvers and
bombs. First an attempt was made on the life of Pobedonostsef;
then the Minister of the Interior, Sipiagin, was assassinated; next
attempts were made on the lives of the Governors of Vilna and
Kharkof, and the Kharkof chief of police; and since that time the
Governor of Ufa, the Vice-Governor of Elizabetpol, the Minister of
the Interior, M. Plehve, and the Grand Duke Serge have fallen
victims to the terrorist policy.*
* In this list I have not mentioned the assassination of M.
Bogolyepof, Minister of Public Instruction, in 1901, because I do
not know whether it should be attributed to the Socialist-
Revolutionaries or to the Narodovoltsi, who had not yet amalgamated
with them.
Though the Social Democrats have no sentimental squeamishness about
bloodshed, they objected to this policy on the ground that acts of
terrorism were unnecessary and were apt to prove injurious rather
than beneficial to the revolutionist cause. One of the main
objects of every intelligent revolutionary party should be to
awaken all classes from their habitual apathy and induce them to
take an active part in the political movement; but terrorism must
have a contrary effect by suggesting that political freedom is to
be attained, not by the steady pressure and persevering cooperation
of the people, but by startling, sensational acts of individual
heroism.
The efforts of these two revolutionary parties, as well as of minor
groups, to get hold of the industrial proletariat did not escape
the notice of the authorities; and during the labour troubles of
1896, on the suggestion of M. Witte, the Government had considered
the question as to what should be done to counteract the influence
of the agitators. On that question it had no difficulty in coming
to a decision; the condition of the working classes must be
improved. An expert official was accordingly instructed to write a
report on what had already been done in that direction. In his
report it was shown that the Government had long been thinking
about the subject. Not to speak of a still-born law about a ten-
hour day for artisans, dating from the time of Catherine II., an
Imperial commission had been appointed as early as 1859, but
nothing practical came of its deliberations until 1882, when
legislative measures were taken for the protection of women and
children in factories. A little later (1886) other grievances were
dealt with and partly removed by regulating contracts of hire,
providing that the money derived from deductions and fines should
not be appropriated by the employers, and creating a staff of
factory inspectors who should take care that the benevolent
intentions of the Government were duly carried out. Having
reviewed all these official efforts in 1896, the Government passed
in the following year a law prohibiting night work and limiting the
working day to eleven and a half hours.
This did not satisfy the workmen. Their wages were still low, and
it was difficult to get them increased because strikes and all
forms of association were still, as they had always been, criminal
offences. On this point the Government remained firm so far as the
law was concerned, but it gradually made practical concessions by
allowing the workmen to combine for certain purposes. In 1898, for
example, in Kharkof, the Engineers' Mutual Aid Society was
sanctioned, and gradually it became customary to allow the workmen
to elect delegates for the discussion of their grievances with the
employers and inspectors.
Finding that these concessions did not check the growing influence
of the Social Democratic agitators among the operatives, the
Government resolved to go a step further; it would organise the
workers on purely trade-unionist lines, and would thereby combat
the Social Democrats, who always advised the strikers to mix up
political demands with their material grievances. The project
seemed to have a good prospect of success, because there were many
workmen, especially of the older generation, who did not at all
like the mixing up of politics, which so often led to arrest,
imprisonment and exile, with the practical concerns of every day
life.
The first attempt of the kind was made in Moscow under the
direction of a certain Zubatof, chief of the secret police, who had
been himself a revolutionary in his youth, and afterwards an agent
provocateur. Aided by Tikhomirof, the repentant terrorist whom I
have already mentioned, Zubatof organised a large workmen's
association, with reading-rooms, lectures, discussions and other
attractions, and sought to convince the members that they should
turn a deaf ear to the Social Democratic agents, and look only to
the Government for the improvement of their condition. In order to
gain their sympathy and confidence, he instructed his subordinates
to take the side of the workmen in all labour disputes, while he
himself brought official pressure to bear on the employers. By
this means he made a considerable number of converts, and for a
time the association seemed to prosper, but he did not possess the
extraordinary ability and tact required to play the complicated
game successfully, and he committed the fatal mistake of using the
office-bearers of the association as detectives for the discovery
of the "evil-intentioned." This tactical error had its natural
consequences. As soon as the workmen perceived that their
professed benefactors were police spies, who did not obtain for
them any real improvement of their condition, the popularity of the
association rapidly declined. At the same time, the factory owners
complained to the Minister of Finance that the police, who ought to
be guardians of public order, and who had accused the factory
inspectors of stirring up discontent in the labouring population,
were themselves creating troubles by inciting the workmen to make
inordinate demands. The Minister of Finance at the moment was M.
Witte, and the Minister of Interior, responsible for the acts of
the police, was M. Plehve, and between these two official
dignitaries, who were already in very strained relations, Zubatof's
activity formed a new base of contention. In these circumstances
it is not surprising that the very risky experiment came to an
untimely end.
In St. Petersburg a similar experiment was made, and it ended much
more tragically. There the chief r le was played by a mysterious?
personage called Father Gapon, who acquired great momentary
notoriety. Though a genuine priest, he did not belong by birth, as
most Russian priests do, to the ecclesiastical caste. The son of a
peasant in Little Russia, where the ranks of the clergy are not
hermetically sealed against the other social classes, he aspired to
take orders, and after being rusticated from a seminary for
supposed sympathy with revolutionary ideas, he contrived to finish
his studies and obtain ordination. During a residence in Moscow he
took part in the Zubatof experiment, and when that badly conducted
scheme collapsed he was transferred to St. Petersburg and appointed
chaplain to a large convict prison. His new professional duties
did not prevent him from continuing to take a keen interest in the
welfare of the working classes, and in the summer of 1904 he
became, with the approval of the police authorities, president of a
large labour union called the Society of Russian Workmen, which had
eleven sections in the various industrial suburbs of the capital.
Under his guidance the experiment proceeded for some months very
successfully. He gained the sympathy and confidence of the
workmen, and so long as no serious questions arose he kept his hold
on them; but a storm was brewing and he proved unequal to the
occasion.
In the first days of 1905, when the economic consequences of the
war had come to be keenly felt, a spirit of discontent appeared
among the labouring population of St. Petersburg, and on Sunday,
January 15th--exactly a week before the famous Sunday when the
troops were called into play--a strike began in the Putilof
ironworks and spread like wildfire to the other big works in the
neighbourhood. The immediate cause of the disturbance was the
dismissal of some workmen and a demand on the part of the labour
union that they should be reinstated. A deputation, composed
partly of genuine workmen and partly of Social Democratic
agitators, and led by Gapon, negotiated with the managers of the
Putilof works, and failed to effect an arrangement. At this moment
Gapon tried hard to confine the negotiations to the points in
dispute, whereas the agitators put forward demands of a wider kind,
such as the eight-hour working day, and they gradually obtained his
concurrence on condition that no political demands should be
introduced into the programme. In defending this condition he was
supported by the workmen, so that when agitators tried to make
political speeches at the meetings they were unceremoniously
expelled.
A similar struggle between the "Economists" and the "Politicals"
was going on in the other industrial suburbs, notably in the Nevski
quarter, where 45,000 operatives had struck work, and the Social
Democrats were particularly active. In this section of the Labour
Union the most influential member was a young workman called
Petroff, who was a staunch Gaponist in the sense that he wished the
workers to confine themselves to their own grievances and to resist
the introduction of political demands. At first he succeeded in
preventing the agitators from speaking at the meetings, but they
soon proved too much for him. At one of the meetings on Tuesday,
when he happened to be absent, a Social Democrat contrived to get
himself elected chairman, and from that moment the political
agitators had a free hand. They had a regular organisation
composed of an organiser, three "oratorical agitators," and several
assistant-organisers who attended the small meetings in the
operatives' sleeping-quarters. Besides these there were a certain
number of workmen already converted to Social Democratic principles
who had learned the art of making political speeches.
The reports of the agitators to the central organisation, written
hurriedly during this eventful week, are extremely graphic and
interesting. They declared that there is a frightful amount of
work to be done and very few to do it. Their stock of Social
Democratic pamphlets is exhausted and they are hoarse from speech-
making. In spite of their superhuman efforts the masses remain
frightfully "undeveloped." The men willingly collect to hear the
orators, listen to them attentively, express approval or dissent,
and even put questions; but with all this they remain obstinately
on the ground of their own immediate wants, such as the increase of
wages and protection against brutal foremen, and they only hint
vaguely at more serious demands. The agitators, however, are
equally obstinate, and they make a few converts. To illustrate how
conversions are made, the following incident is related. At one
meeting the cry of "Stop the war!" is raised by an orator without
sufficient preparation, and at once a voice is heard in the
audience saying. "No, no! The little Japs (Yaposhki) must be
beaten!" Thereupon a more experienced orator comes forward and a
characteristic conversation takes place:
"Have we much land of our own, my friends?" asks the orator.
"Much!" replies the crowd.
"Do we require Manchuria?"
"No!"
"Who pays for the war?"
"We do!"
"Are our brothers dying, and do your wives and children remain
without a bit of bread?"
"So it is!" say many, with a significant shake of the head.
Having succeeded so far, the orator tries to turn the popular
indignation against the Tsar by explaining that he is to blame for
all this misery and suffering, but Petroff suddenly appears on the
scene and maintains that for the misery and suffering the Tsar is
not at all to blame, for he knows nothing about it. It is all the
fault of his servants, the tchinovniks.
By this device Petroff suppresses the seditious cry of "Down with
autocracy!" which the Social Democrats were anxious to make the
watchword of the movement, but he has thereby been drawn from his
strong position of "No politics," and he is standing, as we shall
see presently, on a slippery incline.
On Thursday and Friday the activity of the leaders and the
excitement of the masses increase. While the Gaponists speak
merely of local grievances and material wants, the Social Democrats
incite their hearers to a political struggle, advising them to
demand a Constituent Assembly, and explaining the necessity for all
workmen to draw together and form a powerful political party. The
haranguing goes on from morning to night, and agitators drive about
from one factory to another to keep the excitement at fever-heat.
The police, usually so active on such occasions, do not put in an
appearance. Prince Sviatopolk Mirski, the honest, well-
intentioned, liberal Minister of the Interior, cannot make up his
mind to act with energy, and lets things drift. The agitators
themselves are astonished at this extraordinary inactivity. One of
them, writing a few days afterwards, says: "The police was
paralysed. It would have been easy to arrest Gapon, and discover
the orators. On Friday the clubs might have been surrounded and
the orators arrested. . . . In a word, decided measures might have
been taken, but they were not."
It is not only Petroff that has abandoned his strong position of
"No politics"; Gapon is doing likewise. The movement has spread
far beyond what he expected, and he is being carried away by the
prevailing excitement. With all his benevolent intentions, he is
of a nervous, excitable nature, and his besetting sin is vanity.
He perceives that by resisting the Social Democrats he is losing
his hold on the masses. Early in the week, as we have seen, he
began to widen his programme in the Social Democratic sense, and
every day he makes new concessions. Before the week is finished a
Social Democratic orator can write triumphantly: "In three days we
have transformed the Gaponist assemblies into political meetings!"
Like Petroff, Gapon seeks to defend the Tsar, and he falls into
Petroff's strategical mistake of pretending that the Tsar knows
nothing of the sufferings of his people. From that admission to
the resolution that the Tsar must somehow be informed personally
and directly, by some means outside of the regular official
channel, there is but one step, and that step is quickly taken. On
Friday morning Gapon has determined to present with his own hands a
petition to his Majesty, and the petition is already drafted,
containing demands which go far beyond workmen's grievances. After
resisting the Social Democratic agitators so stoutly, he is now
going over, bag and baggage, to the Social Democratic camp.
This wonderful change was consummated on Friday evening at a
conference which he held with some delegates of the Social
Democrats. From an account written by one of these delegates
immediately after the meeting we get an insight into the worthy
priest's character and motives. In the morning he had written to
them: "I have 100,000 workmen, and I am going with them to the
Palace to present a petition. If it is not granted, we shall make
a revolution. Do you agree?" They did not like the idea, because
the Social Democratic policy is to extort concessions, not to ask
favours, and to refrain from anything that might increase the
prestige of the Autocratic Power. In their reply, therefore, they
consented simply to discuss the matter. I proceed now to quote
from the delegate's account of what took place at the conference:
"The company consisted of Gapon, with two adherents, and five
Social Democrats. All sat round a table, and the conversation
began. Gapon is a good-looking man, with dark complexion and
thoughtful, sympathetic face. He is evidently very tired, and,
like the other orators, he is hoarse. To the questions addressed
to him, he replies: 'The masses are at present so electrified that
you may lead them wherever you like. We shall go on Sunday to the
Palace, and present a petition. If we are allowed to pass without
hindrance, we shall march to the Palace Square, and summon the Tsar
from Tsarskoe Selo. We shall wait for him till the evening. When
he arrives, I shall go to him with a deputation, and in presenting
to him the petition, I shall say: "Your Majesty! Things cannot go
on like this; it is time to give the people liberty." (Tak nelzya!
Para dat' narodu svobodu.) If he consents, we shall insist that he
take an oath before the people. Only then we shall come away, and
when we begin to work, it will only be for eight hours a day. If,
on the other hand, we are prevented from entering the city, we
shall request and beg, and if they do not let us pass, we shall
force our way. In the Palace Square we shall find troops, and we
shall entreat them to come over to our side. If they beat us, we
shall strike back. There will be sacrifices, but part of the
troops will come over to us, and then, being ourselves strong in
numbers, we shall make a revolution. We shall construct
barricades, pillage the armourers' shops, break open the prisons,
and seize the telephones and telegraphs. The Socialist-
Revolutionaries have promised us bombs, and the Democrats money:
and we shall be victorious!*
* This confirms the information which comes to me from other
quarters that Gapon was already in friendly relations with other
revolutionary groups.
"Such, in a few words, were the ideas which Gapon expounded. The
impression he made on us was that he did not clearly realise where
he was going. Acting with sincerity, he was ready to die, but he
was convinced that the troops would not fire, and that the
deputation would be received by the Emperor. He did not
distinguish between different methods. Though not at all a
partisan of violent means, he had become infuriated against
autocracy and the Tsar, as was shown by his language when he said:
'If that blockhead of a Tsar comes out' (Yesli etot durak Tsar
vuidet) . . . Burning with the desire to attain his object, he
looked on revolution like a child, as if it could be accomplished
in a day with empty hands!"
Knowing that no previous preparations had been made for a
revolution such as Gapon talked of, the Social Democratic agents
tried to dissuade him from carrying out his idea on Sunday, but he
stood firm. He had already committed himself publicly to the
project. At a workmen's meeting in another quarter (Vassiliostrof)
earlier in the day he had explained the petition, and said: "Let us
go to the Winter Palace and summon the Emperor, and let us tell him
our wants; if he does not listen to us we do not require him any
longer." To a Social Democrat who shook him warmly by the hand and
expressed his astonishment that there should be such a man among
the clergy, he replied: "I am no longer a priest; I am a fighter
for liberty! They want to exile me, and for some nights I have not
slept at home." When offered assistance to escape arrest, he
answered laconically: "Thanks; I have already a place of refuge."
After his departure from the meeting one of his friends, to whom he
had confided a copy of the petition, rose and said: "Now has
arrived the great historical moment! Now we can and must demand
rights and liberty!" After hearing the petition read the meeting
decided that if the Tsar did not come out at the demand of the
people strong measures should be taken, and one orator indicated
pretty plainly what they should be: "We don't require a Tsar who is
deaf to the woes of the people; we shall perish ourselves, but we
shall kill him. Swear that you will all come to the Palace on
Sunday at twelve o'clock!" The audience raised their hands in
token of assent.
Finding it impossible to dissuade Gapon from his purpose, the
Social Democrats told him that they would take advantage of the
circumstances independently, and that if he was allowed to enter
the city with his deputation they would organise monster meetings
in the Palace Square.
The imperious tone used by Gapon at the public meetings and private
consultations was adopted by him also in his letters to the
Minister of the Interior and to the Emperor. To the former he
wrote:
"The workmen and inhabitants of St. Petersburg of various classes
desire to see the Tsar at two o'clock on Sunday in the Winter
Palace Square, in order to lay before him personally their needs
and those of the whole Russian people. . . . Tell the Tsar that I
and the workmen, many thousands in number, have peacefully, with
confidence in him, but irrevocably, resolved to proceed to the
Winter Palace. Let him show his confidence by deeds, and not by
manifestos."
To the Tsar himself his language was not more respectful:
"Sovereign,--I fear the Ministers have not told you the truth about
the situation. The whole people, trusting in you, has resolved to
appear at the Winter Palace at two o'clock in the afternoon, in
order to inform you of its needs. If you hesitate, and do not
appear before the people, then you tear the moral bonds between you
and them. Trust in you will disappear, because innocent blood will
flow. Appear to-morrow before your people and receive our address
of devotion in a courageous spirit! I and the labour
representatives, my brave comrades, guarantee the inviolability of
your person."
Gapon was no longer merely the president of the Workmen's Union:
inebriated with the excitement he had done so much to create, he
now imagined himself the representative of the oppressed Russian
people, and the heroic leader of a great political revolution. In
the petition which he had prepared he said little about the
grievances of the St. Petersburg workmen whose interests he had a
right to advocate, and preferred to soar into much higher regions:
"The bureaucracy has brought the country to the verge of ruin, and,
by a shameful war, is bringing it to its downfall. We have no
voice in the heavy burdens imposed on us; we do not even know for
whom or why this money is wrung from the impoverished people, and
we do not know how it is expended. This state of things is
contrary to the Divine laws, and renders life unbearable.
Assembled before your palace, we plead for our salvation. Refuse
not your aid; raise your people from the tomb, and give them the
means of working out their own destiny. Rescue them from the
intolerable yoke of officialdom; throw down the wall that separates
you from them, in order that they may rule with you the country
that was created for their happiness--a happiness which is being
wrenched from us, leaving nothing but sorrow and humiliation."
With an innate sentiment of autocratic dignity the Emperor declined
to obey the imperious summons, and he thereby avoided an unseemly
altercation with the excited priest, as well as the boisterous
public meetings which the Social Democrats were preparing to hold
in the Palace Square. Orders were given to the police and the
troops to prevent the crowds of workmen from penetrating into the
centre of the city from the industrial suburbs. The rest need not
be described in detail. On Sunday the crowds tried to force their
way, the troops fired, and many of the demonstrators were killed or
wounded. How many it is impossible to say; between the various
estimates there is an enormous discrepancy. At one of the first
volleys Father Gapon fell, but he turned out to be quite unhurt,
and was spirited away to his place of refuge, whence he escaped
across the frontier.
As soon as he had an opportunity of giving public expression to his
feelings, he indulged in very strong language. In his letters and
proclamations the Tsar is called a miscreant and an assassin, and
is described as traitorous, bloodthirsty, and bestial. To the
ministers he is equally uncomplimentary. They appear to him an
accursed band of brigands, Mamelukes, jackals, monsters. Against
the Tsar, "with his reptilian brood," and the ministers alike, he
vows vengeance--"death to them all!" As for the means for
realising his sacred mission, he recommends bombs, dynamite,
individual and wholesale terrorism, popular insurrection, and
paralysing the life of the cities by destroying the water-mains,
the gas-pipes, the telegraph and telephone wires, the railways and
tram-ways, the Government buildings and the prisons. At some
moments he seems to imagine himself invested with papal powers, for
he anathematises the soldiers who did their duty on the eventful
day, whilst he blesses and absolves from their oath of allegiance
those who help the nation to win liberty.
So far I have spoken merely of the main currents in the
revolutionary movement. Of the minor currents--particularly those
in the outlying provinces, where the Socialist tendencies were
mingled with nationalist feeling--I shall have occasion to speak
when I come to deal with the present political situation as a
whole. Meanwhile, I wish to sketch in outline the foreign policy
which has powerfully contributed to bring about the present crisis.
CHAPTER XXXVIII
TERRITORIAL EXPANSION AND FOREIGN POLICY
Rapid Growth of Russia--Expansive Tendency of Agricultural Peoples--
The Russo-Slavonians--The Northern Forest and the Steppe--
Colonisation--The Part of the Government in the Process of
Expansion--Expansion towards the West--Growth of the Empire
Represented in a Tabular Form--Commercial Motive for Expansion--The
Expansive Force in the Future--Possibilities of Expansion in
Europe--Persia, Afghanistan, and India--Trans-Siberian Railway and
Weltpolitik--A Grandiose Scheme--Determined Opposition of Japan--
Negotiations and War--Russia's Imprudence Explained--Conclusion.
The rapid growth of Russia is one of the most remarkable facts of
modern history. An insignificant tribe, or collection of tribes,
which, a thousand years ago, occupied a small district near the
sources of the Dnieper and Western Dvina, has grown into a great
nation with a territory stretching from the Baltic to the Northern
Pacific, and from the Polar Ocean to the frontiers of Turkey,
Persia, Afghanistan, and China. We have here a fact well deserving
of investigation, and as the process is still going on and is
commonly supposed to threaten our national interests, the
investigation ought to have for us more than a mere scientific
interest. What is the secret of this expansive power? Is it a
mere barbarous lust of territorial aggrandisement, or is it some
more reasonable motive? And what is the nature of the process? Is
annexation followed by assimilation, or do the new acquisitions
retain their old character? Is the Empire in its present extent a
homogeneous whole, or merely a conglomeration of heterogenous units
held together by the outward bond of centralised administration?
If we could find satisfactory answers to these questions, we might
determine how far Russia is strengthened or weakened by her
annexations of territory, and might form some plausible conjectures
as to how, when, and where the process of expansion is to stop.
By glancing at her history from the economic point of view we may
easily detect one prominent cause of expansion.
An agricultural people, employing merely the primitive methods of
agriculture, has always a strong tendency to widen its borders.
The natural increase of population demands a constantly increasing
production of grain, whilst the primitive methods of cultivation
exhaust the soil and steadily diminish its productivity. With
regard to this stage of economic development, the modest assertion
of Malthus, that the supply of food does not increase so rapidly as
the population, often falls far short of the truth. As the
population increases, the supply of food may decrease not only
relatively, but absolutely. When a people finds itself in this
critical position, it must adopt one of two alternatives: either it
must prevent the increase of population, or it must increase the
production of food. In the former case it may legalise the custom
of "exposing" infants, as was done in ancient Greece; or it may
regularly sell a large portion of the young women and children, as
was done until recently in Circassia; or the surplus population may
emigrate to foreign lands, as the Scandinavians did in the ninth
century, and as we ourselves are doing in a more peaceable fashion
at the present day. The other alternative may be effected either
by extending the area of cultivation or by improving the system of
agriculture.
The Russo-Slavonians, being an agricultural people, experienced
this difficulty, but for them it was not serious. A convenient way
of escape was plainly indicated by their peculiar geographical
position. They were not hemmed in by lofty mountains or stormy
seas. To the south and east--at their very doors, as it were--lay
a boundless expanse of thinly populated virgin soil, awaiting the
labour of the husbandman, and ready to repay it most liberally.
The peasantry therefore, instead of exposing their infants, selling
their daughters, or sweeping the seas as Vikings, simply spread out
towards the east and south. This was at once the most natural and
the wisest course, for of all the expedients for preserving the
equilibrium between population and food-production, increasing the
area of cultivation is, under the circumstances just described, the
easiest and most effective. Theoretically the same result might
have been obtained by improving the method of agriculture, but
practically this was impossible. Intensive culture is not likely
to be adopted so long as expansion is easy. High farming is a
thing to be proud of when there is a scarcity of land, but it would
be absurd to attempt it where there is abundance of virgin soil in
the vicinity.
The process of expansion, thus produced by purely economic causes,
was accelerated by influences of another kind, especially during
the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries. The increase in the
number of officials, the augmentation of the taxes, the merciless
exactions of the Voyevods and their subordinates, the
transformation of the peasants and "free wandering people" into
serfs, the ecclesiastical reforms and consequent persecution of the
schismatics, the frequent conscriptions and violent reforms of
Peter the Great--these and other kinds of oppression made thousands
flee from their homes and seek a refuge in the free territory,
where there were no officials, no tax-gatherers, and no
proprietors. But the State, with its army of tax-gatherers and
officials, followed close on the heels of the fugitives, and those
who wished to preserve their liberty had to advance still further.
Notwithstanding the efforts of the authorities to retain the
population in the localities actually occupied, the wave of
colonisation moved steadily onwards.
The vast territory which lay open to the colonists consisted of two
contiguous regions, separated from each other by no mountains or
rivers, but widely differing from each other in many respects. The
one, comprising all the northern part of Eastern Europe and of
Asia, even unto Kamchatka, may be roughly described as a land of
forests, intersected by many rivers, and containing numerous lakes
and marshes; the other, stretching southwards to the Black Sea, and
eastwards far away into Central Asia, is for the most part what
Russians call "the Steppe," and Americans would call the prairies.
Each of these two regions presented peculiar inducements and
peculiar obstacles to colonisation. So far as the facility of
raising grain was concerned, the southern region was decidedly
preferable. In the north the soil had little natural fertility,
and was covered with dense forests, so that much time and labour
had to be expended in making a clearing before the seed could be
sown.* In the south, on the contrary, the squatter had no trees to
fell, and no clearing to make. Nature had cleared the land for
him, and supplied him with a rich black soil of marvellous
fertility, which has not yet been exhausted by centuries of
cultivation. Why, then, did the peasant often prefer the northern
forests to the fertile Steppe where the land was already prepared
for him?
* The modus operandi has been already described; vide supra, pp.
104 et seq.
For this apparent inconsistency there was a good and valid reason.
The muzhik had not, even in those good old times, any passionate
love of labour for its own sake, nor was he by any means insensible
to the facilities for agriculture afforded by the Steppe. But he
could not regard the subject exclusively from the agricultural
point of view. He had to take into consideration the fauna as well
as the flora of the two regions. At the head of the fauna in the
northern forests stood the peace-loving, laborious Finnish tribes,
little disposed to molest settlers who did not make themselves
obnoxiously aggressive; on the Steppe lived the predatory, nomadic
hordes, ever ready to attack, plunder, and carry off as slaves the
peaceful agricultural population. These facts, as well as the
agricultural conditions, were known to intending colonists, and
influenced them in their choice of a new home. Though generally
fearless and fatalistic in a higher degree, they could not entirely
overlook the dangers of the Steppe, and many of them preferred to
encounter the hard work of the forest region.
These differences in the character and population of the two
regions determined the character of the colonisation. Though the
colonisation of the northern regions was not effected entirely
without bloodshed, it was, on the whole, of a peaceful kind, and
consequently received little attention from the contemporary
chroniclers. The colonisation of the Steppe, on the contrary,
required the help of the Cossacks, and forms, as I have already
shown, one of the bloodiest pages of European history.
Thus, we see, the process of expansion towards the north, east, and
south may be described as a spontaneous movement of the
agricultural population. It must, however, be admitted that this
is an imperfect and one-sided representation of the phenomenon.
Though the initiative unquestionably came from the people, the
Government played an important part in the movement.
In early times when Russia was merely a conglomeration of
independent principalities, the Princes were under the moral and
political obligation of protecting their subjects, and this
obligation coincided admirably with their natural desire to extend
their dominions. When the Grand Princes of Muscovy, in the
fifteenth century, united the numerous principalities and
proclaimed themselves Tsars, they accepted this obligation for the
whole country, and conceived much grander schemes of territorial
aggrandisement. Towards the north and northeast no strenuous
efforts were required. The Republic of Novgorod easily gained
possession of Northern Russia as far as the Ural Mountains, and
Siberia was conquered by a small band of Cossacks without the
authorisation of Muscovy, so that the Tsars had merely to annex the
already conquered territory. In the southern region the part
played by the Government was very different. The agricultural
population had to be constantly protected along a frontier of
enormous length, lying open at all points to the incursions of
nomadic tribes. To prevent raids it was necessary to keep up a
military cordon, and this means did not always ensure protection to
those living near the frontier. The nomads often came in
formidable hordes, which could be successfully resisted only by
large armies, and sometimes the armies were not large enough to
cope with them. Again and again during the thirteenth and
fourteenth centuries Tartar hordes swept over the country--burning
the villages and towns, and spreading devastation wherever they
appeared--and during more than two centuries Russia had to pay a
heavy tribute to the Khans.
Gradually the Tsars threw off this galling yoke. Ivan the Terrible
annexed the three Khanates of the Lower Volga--Kazan, Kipttchak,
and Astrakhan--and in that way removed the danger of a foreign
domination. But permanent protection was not thereby secured to
the outlying provinces. The nomadic tribes living near the
frontier continued their raids, and in the slave markets of the
Crimea the living merchandise was supplied by Russia and Poland.
To protect an open frontier against the incursions of nomadic
tribes three methods are possible: the construction of a great
wall, the establishment of a strong military cordon, and the
permanent subjugation of the marauders. The first of these
expedients, adopted by the Romans in Britain and by the Chinese on
their northwestern frontier, is enormously expensive, and was
utterly impossible in a country like Southern Russia, where there
is no stone for building purposes; the second was constantly tried,
and constantly found wanting; the third alone proved practicable
and efficient. Though the Government has long since recognised
that the acquisition of barren, thinly populated steppes is a
burden rather than an advantage, it has been induced to go on
making annexations for the purpose of self-defence, as well as for
other reasons.
In consequence of this active part which the Government took in the
extension of the territory, the process of political expansion
sometimes got greatly ahead of the colonisation. After the Turkish
wars and consequent annexations in the time of Catherine II., for
example, a great part of Southern Russia was almost uninhabited,
and the deficiency had to be corrected, as we have seen, by
organised emigration. At the present day, in the Asiatic
provinces, there are still immense tracts of unoccupied land, some
of which are being gradually colonised.
If we turn now from the East to the West we shall find that the
expansion in this direction was of an entirely different kind. The
country lying to the westward of the early Russo-Slavonian
settlements had a poor soil and a comparatively dense population,
and consequently held out little inducement to emigration. Besides
this, it was inhabited by warlike agricultural races, who were not
only capable of defending their own territory, but even strongly
disposed to make encroachments on their eastern neighbours.
Russian expansion to the westward was, therefore, not a spontaneous
movement of the agricultural population, but the work of the
Government, acting slowly and laboriously by means of diplomacy and
military force; it had, however, a certain historical
justification.
No sooner had Russia freed herself, in the fifteenth century, from
the Tartar domination, than her political independence, and even
her national existence, were threatened from the West. Her western
neighbours, were like herself, animated with that tendency to
national expansion which I have above described; and for a time it
seemed doubtful who should ultimately possess the vast plains of
Eastern Europe. The chief competitors were the Tsars of Moscow and
the Kings of Poland, and the latter appeared to have the better
chance. In close connection with Western Europe, they had been
able to adopt many of the improvements which had recently been made
in the art of war, and they already possessed the rich valley of
the Dnieper. Once, with the help of the free Cossacks, they
succeeded in overrunning the whole of Muscovy, and a son of the
Polish king was elected Tsar in Moscow. By attempting to
accomplish their purpose in a too hasty and reckless fashion, they
raised a storm of religious and patriotic fanaticism, which very
soon drove them out of their newly acquired possessions. The
country remained, however, in a very precarious position, and its
more intelligent rulers perceived plainly that, in order to carry
on the struggle successfully, they must import something of that
Western civilisation which gave such an advantage to their
opponents.
Some steps had already been taken in that direction. In the year
1553 an English navigator, whilst seeking for a short route to
China and India, had accidentally discovered the port of Archangel
on the White Sea, and since that time the Tsars had kept up an
intermittent diplomatic and commercial intercourse with England.
But this route was at all times tedious and dangerous, and during a
great part of the year it was closed by the ice. In view of these
difficulties the Tsars tried to import "cunning foreign
artificers," by way of the Baltic; but their efforts were hampered
by the Livonian Order, who at that time held the east coast, and
who considered, like the Europeans on the coast of Africa at the
present day, that the barbarous natives of the interior should not
be supplied with arms and ammunition. All the other routes to the
West traversed likewise the territory of rivals, who might at any
time become avowed enemies. Under these circumstances the Tsars
naturally desired to break through the barrier which hemmed them
in, and the acquisition of the eastern coast of the Baltic became
one of the chief objects of Russia's foreign policy.
After Poland, Russia's most formidable rival was Sweden. That
power early acquired a large amount of territory to the east of the
Baltic--including the mouths of the Neva, where St. Petersburg now
stands--and long harboured ambitious schemes of further conquest.
In the troublous times when the Poles overran the Tsardom of
Muscovy, she took advantage of the occasion to annex a considerable
amount of territory, and her expansion in this direction went on in
intermittent fashion until it was finally stopped by Peter the
Great.
In comparison with these two rivals Russia was weak in all that
regarded the art of war; but she had two immense advantages: she
had a very large population, and a strong, stable Government that
could concentrate the national forces for any definite purpose.
All that she required for success in the competition was an army on
the European model. Peter the Great created such an army, and won
the prize. After this the political disintegration of Poland
proceeded rapidly, and when that unhappy country fell to pieces
Russia naturally took for herself the lion's share of the spoil.
Sweden, too, sank to political insignificance, and gradually lost
all her trans-Baltic possessions. The last of them--the Grand
Duchy of Finland, which stretches from the Gulf of Finland to the
Polar Ocean--was ceded to Russia by the peace of Friederichshamm in
1809.
The territorial extent of all these acquisitions will be best shown
in a tabular form. The following table represents the process of
expansion from the time when Ivan III. united the independent
principalities and threw off the Tartar yoke, down to the accession
of Peter the Great in 1682:
English
Sq. Miles.
In 1505 the Tsardom of Muscovy contained about 784,000
" 1583 " " " " 996,000
" 1584 " " " " 2,650,000
" 1598 " " " " 3,328,000
" 1676 " " " " 5,448,000
" 1682 " " " " 5,618,000
Of these 5,618,000 English square miles about 1,696,000 were in
Europe and about 3,922,000 in Asia. Peter the Great, though famous
as a conqueror, did not annex nearly so much territory as many of
his predecessors and successors. At his death, in 1752, the Empire
contained, in round numbers, 1,738,000 square miles in Europe and
4,092,000 in Asia. The following table shows the subsequent
expansion:
In Europe and
the Caucasus In Asia.
Eng. sq. m Eng. sq. m.
In 1725 the Russian Empire contained about 1,738,000 4,092,000
" 1770 " " " " 1,780,000 4,452,000
" 1800 " " " " 2,014,000 4,452,000
" 1825 " " " " 2,226,000 4,452,000
" 1855 " " " " 2,261,250 5,194,000
" 1867 " " " " 2,267,360 5,267,560
" 1897 " " " " 2,267,360 6,382,321
In this table is not included the territory in the North-west of
America--containing about 513,250 English square miles--which was
annexed to Russia in 1799 and ceded to the United States in 1867.
When once Russia has annexed she does not readily relax her grasp.
She has, however, since the death of Peter the Great, on four
occasions ceded territory which had come into her possession. To
Persia she ceded, in 1729, Mazanderan and Astrabad, and in 1735 a
large portion of the Caucasus; in 1856, by the Treaty of Paris, she
gave up the mouths of the Danube and part of Bessarabia; in 1867
she sold to the United States her American possessions; in 1881 she
retroceded to China the greater part of Kuldja, which she had
occupied for ten years; and now she is releasing her hold on
Manchuria under the pressure of Japan.
The increase in the population--due in part to territorial
acquisitions--since 1722, when the first census was taken, has been
as follows:--
In 1722 the Empire contained about 14 million inhabitants.
" 1742 " " " 16 "
" 1762 " " " 19 "
" 1782 " " " 28 "
" 1796 " " " 36 "
" 1812 " " " 41 "
" 1815 " " " 45 "
" 1835 " " " 60 "
" 1851 " " " 68 "
" 1858 " " " 44 "
" 1897 " " " 129 "
So much for the past. To sum up, we may say that, if we have read
Russian history aright, the chief motives of expansion have been
spontaneous colonisation, self-defence against nomadic tribes, and
high political aims, such as the desire to reach the sea-coast; and
that the process has been greatly facilitated by peculiar
geographical conditions and the autocratic form of government.
Before passing to the future, I must mention another cause of
expansion which has recently come into play, and which has already
acquired very great importance.
Russia is rapidly becoming, as I have explained in a previous
chapter, a great industrial and commercial nation, and is anxious
to acquire new markets for her manufactured goods. Though her
industries cannot yet supply her own wants, she likes to peg out
claims for the future, so as not to be forestalled by more advanced
nations. I am not sure that she ever makes a conquest exclusively
for this purpose, but whenever it happens that she has other
reasons for widening her borders, the idea of acquiring commercial
advantages acts as a subsidiary incentive, and as soon as the
territory is annexed she raises round it a line of commercial
fortifications in the shape of custom-houses, through which foreign
goods have great difficulty in forcing their way.
This policy is quite intelligible from the patriotic point of view,
but Russians like to justify it, and condemn English competition,
on higher ground. England, they say, is like a successful
manufacturer who has oustripped his rivals and who seeks to prevent
any new competitors from coming into the field. By her mercantile
policy she has become the great blood-sucker of other nations.
Haying no cause to fear competition, she advocates the insidious
principles of Free Trade, and deluges foreign countries with her
manufactures to such an extent that unprotected native industries
are inevitably ruined. Thus all nations have long paid tribute to
England, but the era of emancipation had dawned. The fallacies of
Free Trade have been detected and exposed, and Russia, like other
nations, has found in the beneficent power of protective tariffs a
means of escape from British economic thraldom. Henceforth, not
only the muzhiks of European Russia, but also the populations of
Central Asia, will be saved from the heartless exploitation of
Manchester and Birmingham--and be handed over, I presume, to the
tender mercies of the manufacturers of Moscow and St. Petersburg,
who sell their goods much dearer than their English rivals.
Having thus analysed the expansive tendency, let us endeavour to
determine how the various factors of which it is composed are
acting in the present and are likely to act in the future. In this
investigation it will be well to begin with the simpler, and
proceed gradually to the more complex parts of the problem.
Towards the north and the west the history of Russian expansion may
almost be regarded as closed. Northwards there is nothing to be
annexed but the Arctic Ocean and the Polar regions; and, westwards,
annexations at the expense of Germany are not to be thought of.
There remain, therefore, only Sweden and Norway. They may
possibly, at some future time, come within the range of Russia's
territorial appetite, but at present the only part of the
Scandinavian Peninsula on which she is supposed to cast longing
eyes is a barren district in the extreme north, which is said to
contain an excellent warm-water port.
Towards the south-west there are possibilities of future expansion,
and already some people talk of Austrian Galicia being
geographically and ethnographically a part of Russia; but so long
as the Austro-Hungarian Empire holds together such possibilities do
not come within the sphere of practical politics.
Farther east, towards the Balkan Peninsula, the expansive tendency
is much more complicated and of very ancient date. The Russo-Slavs
who held the valley of the Dnieper from the ninth to the thirteenth
century belonged to those numerous frontier tribes which the
tottering Byzantine Empires attempted to ward off by diplomacy and
rich gifts, and by giving to the troublesome chiefs, on condition
of their accepting Christianity, princesses of the Imperial family
as brides. Vladimir, Prince of Kief, now recognised as a Saint by
the Russian Church, accepted Christianity in this way (A. D. 988),
and his subjects followed his example. Russia thus became
ecclesiastically a part of the Patriarchate of Constantinople, and
the people learned to regard Tsargrad--that is, the City of the
Tsar, as the Byzantine Emperor was then called--with peculiar
veneration.
All through the long Tartar domination, when the nomadic hordes
held the valley of the Dnieper and formed a barrier between Russia
and the Balkan Peninsula, the capital of the Greek Orthodox world
was remembered and venerated by the Russian people, and in the
fifteenth century it acquired in their eyes a new significance. At
that time the relative positions of Constantinople and Moscow were
changed. Constantinople fell under the power of the Mahometan
Turks, whilst Moscow threw off the yoke of the Mahometan Tartars,
the northern representatives of the Turkish race. The Grand Prince
of Moscow thereby became the Protector of the Faith, and in some
sort the successor of the Byzantine Tsars. To strengthen this
claim, Ivan III. married a niece of the last Byzantine Emperor, and
his successors went further in the same direction by assuming the
title of Tsar, and inventing a fable about their ancestor Rurik
having been a descendant of Caesar Augustus.
All this would seem to a lawyer, or even to a diplomatist, a very
shadowy title, and none of the Russian monarchs--except perhaps
Catherine II., who conceived the project of resuscitating the
Byzantine Empire, and caused one of her grandsons to learn modern
Greek, in view of possible contingencies--ever thought seriously of
claiming the imaginary heritage; but the idea that the Tsars ought
to reign in Tsargrad, and that St. Sophia, polluted by Moslem
abominations, should be restored to the Orthodox Christians, struck
deep root in the minds of the Russian people, and is still by no
means extinct. As soon as serious disturbances break out in the
East the peasantry begin to think that perhaps the time has come
for undertaking a crusade for the recovery of the Holy City on the
Bosphorus, and for the liberation of their brethren in the faith
who groan under Turkish bondage.
Essentially different from this religious sentiment, but often
blended with it, is a vague feeling of racial affinity, which has
long existed among the various Slav nationalities, and which was
greatly developed during last century by writers of the Panslavist
school. When Germans and Italians were striving after political
independence and unity, it naturally occurred to the Slavs that
they might do likewise. The idea became popular among the subject
Slav nationalities of Austria and Turkey, and it awoke a certain
amount of enthusiasm in Moscow, where it was hoped that "all the
Slav streams would unite in the great Russian Sea." It required no
great political perspicacity to foresee that in any confederation
of Slav nationalities the hegemony must necessarily devolve on
Russia, the only Slav State which has succeeded in becoming a Great
Power.
Those two currents of national feeling ran parallel to, and
intermingled with, the policy of the Government. Desirous of
becoming a great naval Power, Russia has always striven to reach
the sea-coast and obtain good harbours. In the north and north-
west she succeeded in a certain degree, but neither the White Sea
nor the Baltic satisfied her requirements, and she naturally turned
her eyes to the Mediterranean. With difficulty she gained
possession of the northern shores of the Black Sea, but her designs
were thereby only half realised, because the Turks held the only
outlet to the Mediterranean, and could effectually blockade, so far
as the open sea is concerned, all her Black Sea ports, without
employing a single ship of war. Thus the possession of the
Straits, involving necessarily the possession of Constantinople,
became a cardinal point of Russia's foreign policy. Any
description of the various methods adopted by her at different
times for the attainment of this end does not enter into my present
programme, but I may say briefly that the action of the three
factors above mentioned--the religious feeling, the Panslavist
sentiment, and the political aims--has never been better
exemplified than in the last struggle with Turkey, culminating in
the Treaty of San Stefano and the Congress of Berlin.
For all classes in Russia the result of that struggle was a feeling
of profound disappointment. The peasantry bewailed the fact that
the Crescent on St. Sophia had not been replaced by the Cross; the
Slavophil patriots were indignant that the "little brothers" had
shown themselves unworthy of the generous efforts and sacrifices
made on their behalf, and that a portion of the future Slav
confederation had passed under the domination of Austria; and the
Government recognised that the acquisition of the Straits must be
indefinitely postponed. Then history repeated itself. After the
Crimean War, in accordance with Prince Gortchakoff's famous
epigram, La Russie ne boude pas elle se recueille, the Government
had for some years abandoned an active policy in Europe, and
devoted itself to the work of internal reorganisation; whilst the
military party had turned their attention to making new
acquisitions of territory and influence in Asia. In like manner,
after the Turkish campaign of 1877-78, Alexander III., turning his
back on the Slav brethren, inaugurated an era of peace in Europe
and of territorial expansion in the east. In this direction the
expansive force was not affected by religious feeling, or
Panslavist sentiment, and was controlled and guided by purely
political considerations. It is consequently much easier to
determine in this field of action what the political aims really
are.
In Asia, as in Europe, the dominant factor in the policy of the
Government has been the desire to reach the sea-coast; and in both
continents the ports first acquired were in northern latitudes
where the coasts are free from ice during only a part of the year.
In this respect, Nikolaefsk and Vladivostok in the Far East
correspond to Archangel and St. Petersburg in Europe. Such ports
could not fulfil all the requirements, and consequently the
expansive tendency turned southwards--in Europe towards the Black
Sea and the Mediterranean, and in Asia towards the Persian Gulf,
the Indian Ocean and the Gulf of Pechili.
In Persia the Russian Government pursues the policy of pacific
infiltration, and already the northern half of the Shah's dominions
is pretty well permeated with Russian influence, commercial and
political. In the southern half the infiltration is to some extent
checked by physical obstacles and British influence, but it is
steadily advancing, and the idea of obtaining a port on the Persian
Gulf is coming within the range of practical politics.
In Afghanistan also the pressure is felt, and here too the
expansive tendency meets with opposition from England. More than
once the two great Powers have come dangerously near to war--
notably in 1885, at the moment of the Penjdeh incident, when the
British Parliament voted 11,000,000 pounds for military
preparations. Fortunately on that occasion the problem was solved
by diplomacy. The northern frontier of Afghanistan was demarcated
by a joint commission, and an agreement was come to by which this
line should form the boundary of the British and Russian spheres of
influence. For some years Russia scrupulously respected this
agreement, but during our South African difficulties she showed
symptoms of departing from it, and at one moment orders were issued
from St. Petersburg for a military demonstration on the Afghan
frontier. Strange to say, the military authorities, who are
usually very bellicose, deprecated such a movement, on the ground
that a military demonstration in a country like Afghanistan might
easily develop into a serious campaign, and that a serious campaign
ought not to be undertaken in that region until after the
completion of the strategical railways from Orenburg to Tashkent.
As this important line has now been completed, and other strategic
lines are in contemplation, the question arises whether Russia
meditates an attack on India. It is a question which is not easily
answered. No doubt there are many Russians who think it would be a
grand thing to annex our Indian Empire, with its teeming millions
and its imaginary fabulous treasures, and not a few young officers
imagine that it would be an easy task. Further, it is certain that
the problem of an invasion has been studied by the Headquarters
Staff in St. Petersburg, just as the problem of an invasion of
England has been studied by the Headquarters Staff in Berlin. It
may be pretty safely asserted, however, that the idea of a conquest
of India has never been seriously entertained in the Russian
official world. What has been seriously entertained, not only in
the official world, but by the Government itself, is the idea--
strongly recommended by the late General Skobelef--that Russia
should, as quickly as possible, get within striking distance of our
Indian possessions, so that she may always be able to bring strong
diplomatic pressure on the British Government, and in the event of
a conflict immobilise a large part of the British army.
The expansive tendency in the direction of the Persian Gulf and the
Indian Ocean was considerably weakened by the completion of the
Trans-Siberian Railway and the rapid development of an aggressive
policy in the Far east. Never, perhaps, has the construction of a
single line produced such deep and lasting changes in the sphere of
Weltpolitik.
As soon as the Trans-Siberian was being rapidly constructed a
magnificent prospect opened up to the gaze of imaginative
politicians in St. Petersburg. The foreground was Manchuria a
region of 364,000 square miles, endowed by nature with enormous
mineral resources, and presenting a splendid field for agricultural
colonisation and commercial enterprise. Beyond was seen Korea,
geographically an appendix of Manchuria, possessing splendid
harbours, and occupied by an effete, unwarlike population, wholly
incapable of resisting a European Power. That was quite enough to
inflame the imagination of patriotic Russians; but there was
something more, dimly perceived in the background. Once in
possession of Manchuria, supplied with a network of railways,
Russia would dominate Peking and the whole of Northern China, and
she would thus be able to play a decisive part in the approaching
struggle of the European Powers for the Far-Eastern Sick Man's
inheritance.
Of course there were obstacles in the way of realising this
grandiose scheme, and there were some cool heads in St. Petersburg
who were not slow to point them out. In the first place the
undertaking must be extremely costly, and the economic condition of
Russia proper was not such as to justify the expenditure of an
enormous capital which must be for many years unproductive. Any
superfluous capital which the country might possess was much more
urgently required for purposes of internal development, and the
impoverished agricultural population ought not to be drained of
their last meagre reserves for the sake of gigantic political
schemes which did not directly contribute to their material
welfare. To this the enthusiastic advocates of the forward policy
replied that the national finances had never been in such a
prosperous condition, that the revenue was increasing by leaps and
bounds, that the money invested in the proposed enterprise would
soon be repaid with interest; and that if Russia did not at once
seize the opportunity she would find herself forestalled by
energetic rivals. There was still, however, one formidable
objection. Such an enormous increase of Russia's power in the Far
East would inevitably arouse the jealousy and opposition of other
Powers, especially of Japan, for whom the future of Korea and
Manchuria was a question of life and death. Here again these
advocates of the forward policy had their answer ready. They
declared that the danger was more apparent than real. In Far-
Eastern diplomacy the European Powers could not compete with
Russia, and they might easily be bought off by giving them a very
modest share of the spoil; as for Japan, she was not formidable,
for she was just emerging from Oriental barbarism, and all her
boasted progress was nothing more than a thin veneer of European
civilisation. As the Moscow patriots on the eve of the Crimean War
said contemptuously of the Allies, "We have only to throw our hats
at them," so now the believers in Russia's historic mission in the
Far East spoke of their future opponents as "monkeys" and
"parrots."
The war between China and Japan in 1894-5, terminating in the
Treaty of Shimonoseki, which ceded to Japan the Liaotung Peninsula,
showed Russia that if she was not to be forestalled she must be up
and doing. She accordingly formed a coalition with France and
Germany, and compelled Japan to withdraw from the mainland, on the
pretext that the integrity of China must be maintained. In this
way China recovered, for a moment, a bit of lost territory, and
further benefits were conferred on her by a guarantee for a foreign
loan, and by the creation of the Russo-Chinese Bank, which would
assist her in her financial affairs. For these and other favours
she was expected to be grateful, and it was suggested to her that
her gratitude might take the form of facilitating the construction
of the Trans-Siberian Railway. If constructed wholly on Russian
territory the line would have to make an enormous bend to the
northward, whereas if it went straight from Lake Baikal to
Vladivostok it would be very much shorter, and would confer a very
great benefit on the north-eastern provinces of the Celestial
Empire. This benefit, moreover, might be greatly increased by
making a branch line to Talienwan and Port Arthur, which would some
day be united with Peking. Gradually Li-Hung-Chang and other
influential Chinese officials were induced to sympathise with the
scheme, and a concession was granted for the direct line to
Vladivostok through Chinese territory.
The retrocession of the Liaotung Peninsula had not been effected by
Russia alone. Germany and France had co-operated, and they also
expected from China a mark of gratitude in some tangible form. On
this point the statesmen of Berlin held very strong views, and they
thought it advisable to obtain a material guarantee for the
fulfilment of their expectations by seizing Kiaochau, on the ground
that German missionaries had been murdered by Chinese fanatics.
For Russia this was a most unwelcome incident. She had earmarked
Kiaochau for her own purposes, and had already made an agreement
with the authorities in Peking that the harbour might be used
freely by her fleet. And this was not the worst. The incident
might inaugurate an era of partition for which she was not yet
prepared, and another port which she had earmarked for her own use
might be seized by a rival. Already English ships of war were
reported to be prowling about in the vicinity of the Liaotung
Peninsula. She hastened to demand, therefore, as a set-off for the
loss of Kiaochau, a lease of Port Arthur and Talienwan, and a
railway concession to unite these ports with the Trans-Siberian
Railway. The Chinese Government was too weak to think of refusing
the demands, and the process of gradually absorbing Manchuria
began, in accordance with a plan already roughly sketched out in
St. Petersburg.
In the light of a few authentic documents and many subsequent
events, the outline of this plan can be traced with tolerable
accuracy. In the region through which the projected railways were
to run there was a large marauding population, and consequently the
labourers and the works would have to be protected; and as Chinese
troops can never be thoroughly relied on, the protecting force must
be Russian. Under this rather transparent disguise a small army of
occupation could be gradually introduced, and in establishing a
modus vivendi between it and the Chinese civil and military
authorities a predominant influence in the local administration
could be established. At the same time, by energetic diplomatic
action at Peking, which would be brought within striking-distance
by the railways, all rival foreign influences might be excluded
from the occupied provinces, and the rest might be left to the
action of "spontaneous infiltration." Thus, while professing to
uphold the principle of the territorial integrity of the Celestial
Empire, the Cabinet of St. Petersburg might practically annex the
whole of Manchuria and transform Port Arthur into a great naval
port and arsenal, a far more effectual "Dominator of the East" than
Vladivostok, which was intended, as its name implies, to fulfil
that function. From Manchuria the political influence and the
spontaneous infiltration would naturally extend to Korea, and on
the deeply indented coast of the Hermit Kingdom new ports and
arsenals, far more spacious and strategically more important than
Port Arthur, might be constructed.
The grandiose scheme was carefully laid, and for a time it was
favoured by circumstances. In 1900 the Boxer troubles justified
Russia in sending a large force into Manchuria, and enabled her
subsequently to play the part of China's protector against the
inordinate demands of the Western Powers for compensation and
guarantees. For a moment it seemed as if the slow process of
gradual infiltration might be replaced by a more expeditious mode
of annexation. As the dexterous diplomacy of Ignatief in 1858 had
induced the Son of Heaven to cede to Russia the rich Primorsk
provinces between the Amur and the sea, as compensation for Russian
protection against the English and French, who had burnt his Summer
Palace, so his successor might now perhaps be induced to cede
Manchuria to the Tsar for similar reasons.
No such cession actually took place, but the Russian diplomatists
in Peking could use the gratitude argument in support of their
demands for an extension of the rights and privileges of the
"temporary" occupation; and when China sought to resist the
pressure by leaning on the rival Powers she found them to be little
better than broken reeds. France could not openly oppose her ally,
and Germany had reasons of her own for conciliating the Tsar,
whilst England and the United States, though avowedly opposing the
scheme as dangerous to their commercial interests, were not
prepared to go to war in defence of their policy. It seemed,
therefore, that by patience, tenacity and diplomatic dexterity
Russia might ultimately attain her ends; but a surprise was in
store for her. There was one Power which recognised that her own
vital interests were at stake, and which was ready to undertake a
life-and-death struggle in defence of them.
Though still smarting under the humiliation of her expulsion from
the Liaotung Peninsula in 1895, and watching with the keenest
interest every move in the political game, Japan had remained for
some time in the background, and had confined her efforts to
resisting Russian influence in Korea and supporting diplomatically
the Powers who were upholding the policy of the open door. Now,
when it had become evident that the Western Powers would not
prevent the realisation of the Russian scheme, she determined to
intervene energetically, and to stake her national existence on the
result. Ever since 1895 she had been making military and naval
preparations for the day of the revanche, and now that day was at
hand. Against the danger of a coalition such as had checkmated her
on the previous occasion she was protected by the alliance which
she had concluded with England in 1902, and she felt confident that
with Russia alone she was quite capable of dealing single-handed.
Her position is briefly and graphically described in a despatch,
telegraphed at that time (28th July, 1903) by the Japanese
Government to its representative at St. Petersburg, instructing him
to open negotiations:
"The recent conduct of Russia in making new demands at Peking and
tightening her hold upon Manchuria has led the Imperial Government
to believe that she must have abandoned her intention of retiring
from that province. At the same time, her increased activity upon
the Korean frontier is such as to raise doubts as to the limits of
her ambition. The unconditional and permanent occupation of
Manchuria by Russia would create a state of things prejudicial to
the security and interests of Japan. The principle of equal
opportunity (the open door) would thereby be annulled, and the
territorial integrity of China impaired. There is, however, a
still more serious consideration for the Japanese Government. If
Russia were established on the flank of Korea she would constantly
menace the separate existence of that Empire, or at least exercise
in it a predominant influence; and as Japan considers Korea an
important outpost in her line of defence, she regards its
independence as absolutely essential to her own repose and safety.
Moreover, the political as well as commercial and industrial
interests and influence which Japan possesses in Korea are
paramount over those of other Powers; she cannot, having regard to
her own security, consent to surrender them to, or share them with,
another Power."
In accordance with this view of the situation the Japanese
Government informed Count Lamsdorff that, as it desired to remove
from the relations of the two Empires every cause of future
misunderstanding, it would be glad to enter with the Imperial
Russian Government upon an examination of the condition of affairs
in the Far East, with a view to defining the respective special
interests of the two countries in those regions.
Though Count Lamsdorff accepted the proposal with apparent
cordiality and professed to regard it as a means of preventing any
outsider from sowing the seeds of discord between the two
countries, the idea of a general discussion was not at all welcome.
Careful definition of respective interests was the last thing the
Russian Government desired. Its policy was to keep the whole
situation in a haze until it had consolidated its position in
Manchuria and on the Korean frontier to such an extent that it
could dictate its own terms in any future arrangement. It could
not, however, consistently with its oft-repeated declarations of
disinterestedness and love of peace, decline to discuss the
subject. It consented, therefore, to an exchange of views, but in
order to ensure that the tightening of its hold on the territories
in question should proceed pari passu with the diplomatic action,
it made an extraordinary departure from ordinary procedure,
entrusting the conduct of the affair, not to Count Lamsdorff and
the Foreign Office, but to Admiral Alexeyef, the newly created
Viceroy of the Far East, in whom was vested the control of all
civil, military, naval, and diplomatic affairs relating to that
part of the world.
From the commencement of the negotiations, which lasted from August
12th, 1903, to February 6th, 1904, the irreconcilable differences
of the two rivals became apparent, and all through the
correspondence, in which a few apparent concessions were offered by
Japan, neither Power retreated a step from the positions originally
taken up. What Japan suggested was, roughly speaking, a mutual
engagement to uphold the independence and integrity of the Chinese
and Korean empires, and at the same time a bilateral arrangement by
which the special interests of the two contracting parties in
Manchuria and in Korea should be formally recognised, and the means
of protecting them clearly defined. The scheme did not commend
itself to the Russians. They systematically ignored the interests
of Japan in Manchuria, and maintained that she had no right to
interfere in any arrangements they might think fit to make with the
Chinese Government with regard to that province. In their opinion,
Japan ought to recognise formally that Manchuria lay outside her
sphere of interest, and the negotiations should be confined to
limiting her freedom of action in Korea.
With such a wide divergence in principle the two parties were not
likely to agree in matters of detail. Their conflicting aims came
out most clearly in the question of the open door. The Japanese
insisted on obtaining the privileges of the open door, including
the right of settlement in Manchuria, and Russia obstinately
refused. Having marked out Manchuria as a close reserve for her
own colonisation, trade, and industry, and knowing that she could
not compete with the Japanese if they were freely admitted, she
could not adopt the principle of "equal opportunity" which her
rivals recommended. A fidus achates of Admiral Alexeyef explained
to me quite frankly, during the negotiations, why no concessions
could be made on that point. In the work of establishing law and
order in Manchuria, constructing roads, bridges, railways, and
towns, Russia had expended an enormous sum--estimated by Count
Cassini at 60,000,000 pounds--and until that capital was recovered,
or until a reasonable interest was derived from the investment,
Russia could not think of sharing with any one the fruits of the
prosperity which she had created.
We need not go further into the details of the negotiations. Japan
soon convinced herself that the onward march of the Colossus was
not to be stopped by paper barricades, and knowing well that her
actual military and naval superiority was being rapidly diminished
by Russia's warlike preparations,* she suddenly broke off
diplomatic relations and commenced hostilities.
* According to an estimate made by the Japanese authorities,
between April, 1903, and the outbreak of the war, Russia increased
her naval and military forces in the Far East by nineteen war
vessels, aggregating 82,415 tons, and 40,000 soldiers. In addition
to this, one battleship, three cruisers, seven torpedo destroyers,
and four torpedo boats, aggregating about 37,040 tons, were on
their way to the East, and preparations had been made for
increasing the land forces by 200,000 men. For further details,
see Asakawa, "The Russo-Japanese Conflict" (London, 1904), pp. 352-
54.
Russia thus found herself engaged in a war of the first magnitude,
of which no one can predict the ultimate consequences, and the
question naturally arises as to why, with an Emperor who lately
aspired to play in politics the part of a great peacemaker, she
provoked a conflict, for which she was very imperfectly prepared--
imposing on herself the obligation of defending a naval fortress,
hastily constructed on foreign territory, and united with her base
by a single line of railway 6,000 miles long. The question is
easily answered: she did not believe in the possibility of war.
The Emperor was firmly resolved that he would not attack Japan, and
no one would admit for a moment that Japan could have the audacity
to attack the great Russian Empire. In the late autumn of 1903, it
is true, a few well-informed officials in St. Petersburg,
influenced by the warnings of Baron Rosen, the Russian Minister in
Tokio, began to perceive that perhaps Japan would provoke a
conflict, but they were convinced that the military and naval
preparations already made were quite sufficient to repel the
attack. One of these officials--probably the best informed of all--
said to me quite frankly: "If Japan had attacked us in May or
June, we should have been in a sorry plight, but now [November,
1903] we are ready."
The whole past history of territoral expansion in Asia tended to
confirm the prevailing illusions. Russia had advanced steadily
from the Ural and the Caspian to the Hindu Kush and the Northern
Pacific without once encountering serious resistance. Not once had
she been called on to make a great national effort, and the armed
resistance of the native races had never inflicted on her anything
worse than pin-pricks. From decrepit China, which possessed no
army in the European sense of the term, a more energetic resistance
was not to be expected. Had not Muravieff Amurski with a few
Cossacks quietly occupied her Amur territories without provoking
anything more dangerous than a diplomatic protest; and had not
Ignatief annexed her rich Primorsk provinces, including the site of
Vladivostok, by purely diplomatic means? Why should not Count
Cassini, a diplomatist of the same type as Ignatief, imitate his
adroit predecessor, and secure for Russia, if not the formal
annexation, at least the permanent occupation, of Manchuria?
Remembering all this, we can perceive that the great mistake of the
Russian Government is not so very difficult to explain. It
certainly did not want war--far from it--but it wanted to obtain
Manchuria by a gradual, painless process of absorption, and it did
not perceive that this could not be attained without a life-and-
death struggle with a young, vigorous nationality, which has
contrived to combine the passions and virtues of a primitive race
with the organising powers and scientific appliances of the most
advanced civilisation.
Russian territorial expansion has thus been checked, for some years
to come, on the Pacific coast; but the expansive tendency will re-
appear soon in other regions, and it behooves us to be watchful,
because, whatever direction it may take, it is likely to affect our
interests directly or indirectly. Will it confine itself for some
years to a process of infiltration in Mongolia and Northern Thibet,
the line of least resistance? Or will it impinge on our Indian
frontier, directed by those who desire to avenge themselves on
Japan's ally for the reverses sustained in Manchuria? Or will it
once more take the direction of the Bosphorous, where a campaign
might be expected to awaken religious and warlike enthusiasm among
the masses? To these questions I cannot give any answer, because
so much depends on the internal consequences of the present war,
and on accidental circumstances which no one can at present
foresee. I have always desired, and still desire, that we should
cultivate friendly relations with our great rival, and that we
should learn to appreciate the many good qualities of her people;
but I have at the same time always desired that we should keep a
watchful eye on her irrepressible tendency to expand, and that we
should take timely precautions against any unprovoked aggression,
however justifiable it may seem to her from the point of view of
her own national interests.
CHAPTER XXXIX
THE PRESENT SITUATION
Reform or Revolution?--Reigns of Alexander II. and Nicholas II.
Compared and Contrasted--The Present Opposition--Various Groups--
The Constitutionalists--Zemski Sobors--The Young Tsar Dispels
Illusions--Liberal Frondeurs--Plehve's Repressive Policy--
Discontent Increased by the War--Relaxation and Wavering under
Prince Mirski--Reform Enthusiasm--The Constitutionalists Formulate
their Demands--The Social Democrats--Father Gapon's Demonstration--
The Socialist-Revolutionaries--The Agrarian Agitators--The Subject-
Nationalities--Numerical Strength of the Various Groups--All United
on One Point--Their Different Aims--Possible Solutions of the
Crisis--Difficulties of Introducing Constitutional Regime--A Strong
Man Wanted--Uncertainty of the Future.
Is history about to repeat itself, or are we on the eve of a
cataclysm? Is the reign of Nicholas II. to be, in its main lines,
a repetition of the reign of Alexander II., or is Russia about to
enter on an entirely new phase of her political development?
To this momentous question I do not profess to give a categorical
answer. If it be true, even in ordinary times, that "of all forms
of human folly, prediction is the most gratuitous," it is
especially true at a moment like the present, when we are
constantly reminded of the French proverb that there is nothing
certain but the unforeseen. All I can hope to do is to throw a
little light on the elements of the problem, and allow the reader
to draw his own conclusions.
Between the present situation and the early part of Alexander II.'s
reign there is undoubtedly a certain analogy. In both cases we
find in the educated classes a passionate desire for political
liberty, generated by long years of a stern, autocratic regime, and
stimulated by military disasters for which autocracy is held
responsible; and in both cases we find the throne occupied by a
Sovereign of less accentuated political convictions and less
energetic character than his immediate predecessor. In the earlier
case, the autocrat, showing more perspicacity and energy than were
expected of him, guides and controls the popular enthusiasm, and
postpones the threatened political crisis by effecting a series of
far reaching and beneficent reforms. In the present case . . . the
description of the result must be left to future historians. For
the moment, all we can say is that between the two situations there
are as many points of difference as of analogy. After the Crimean
War the enthusiasm was of a vague, eclectic kind, and consequently
it could find satisfaction in practical administrative reforms not
affecting the essence of the Autocratic Power, the main pivot round
which the Empire has revolved for centuries. Now, on the contrary,
it is precisely on this pivot that the reform enthusiasm is
concentrated. Mere bureaucratic reforms can no longer give
satisfaction. All sections of the educated classes, with the
exception of a small group of Conservative doctrinaires, insist on
obtaining a controlling influence in the government of the country,
and demand that the Autocratic Power, if not abolished, shall be
limited by parliamentary institutions of a democratic type.
Another difference between the present and the past, is that those
who now clamour for radical changes are more numerous, more
courageous, and better organised than their predecessors, and they
are consequently better able to bring pressure to bear on the
Government. Formerly the would-be reformers were of two
categories; on the one hand, the Constitutionalists, who remained
within the bounds of legality, and confined themselves to inserting
vague hints in loyal addresses to the Tsar and making mild
political demonstrations; and on the other hand, the so-called
Nihilists, who talked about organising society on Socialistic
principles, and who hoped to attain their object by means of secret
associations. With both of these groups, as soon as they became
aggressive, the Government had no difficulty in dealing
effectually. The leading Constitutionalists were simply
reprimanded or ordered to remain for a time in their country
houses, while the more active revolutionaries were exiled,
imprisoned, or compelled to take refuge abroad. All this gave the
police a good deal of trouble, especially when the Nihilists took
to Socialist propaganda among the common people, and to acts of
terrorism against the officials; but the existence of the
Autocratic Power was never seriously endangered. Nowadays the
Liberals have no fear of official reprimands, and openly disregard
the orders of the authorities about holding meetings and making
speeches, while a large section of the Socialists proclaim
themselves a Social Democratic party, enrol large numbers of
working men, organise formidable strikes, and make monster
demonstrations leading to bloodshed.
Let us now examine this new Opposition a little more closely. We
can perceive at a glance that it is composed of two sections,
differing widely from each other in character and aims. On the one
hand, there are the Liberals, who desire merely political reforms
of a more or less democratic type; on the other, there are the
Socialists, who aim at transforming thoroughly the existing
economic organisation of Society, and who, if they desire
parliamentary institutions at all, desire them simply as a stepping
stone to the realisation of the Socialist ideal. Behind the
Socialists, and to some extent mingling with them, stand a number
of men belonging to the various subject-nationalities, who have
placed themselves under the Socialist banner, but who hold, more or
less concealed, their little national flags, ready to be unfurled
at the proper moment.
Of these three sections of the Opposition, the most numerous and
the best prepared to undertake the functions and responsibilities
of government is that of the Liberals. The movement which they
represent began immediately after the Crimean War, when the upper
ranks of society, smarting under defeat and looking about for the
cause of the military disasters, came to the conclusion that
Autocracy had been put to a crucial test, and found wanting. The
outburst of patriotic indignation at that time and the eager desire
for a more liberal regime have been described in previous chapters.
For a moment the more sanguine critics of the Government imagined
that the Autocratic Power, persuaded of its own inefficiency, would
gladly accept the assistance of the educated classes, and would
spontaneously transform itself into a Constitutional Monarchy. In
reality Alexander II. had no such intentions. He was resolved to
purify the administration and to reform as far as possible all
existing abuses, and he seemed ready at first to listen to the
advice and accept the co-operation of his faithful subjects; but he
had not the slightest intention of limiting his supreme authority,
which he regarded as essential to the existence of the Empire. As
soon as the landed proprietors began to complain that the great
question of serf emancipation was being taken out of their hands by
the bureaucracy, he reminded them that "in Russia laws are made by
the Autocratic Power," and when the more courageous Marshals of
Noblesse ventured to protest against the unceremonious manner in
which the nobles were being treated by the tchinovniks, some of
them were officially reprimanded and others were deposed.
The indignation produced by this procedure, in which the Tsar
identified himself with the bureaucracy, was momentarily appeased
by the decision of the Government to entrust to the landed
proprietors the carrying out of the Emancipation law, and by the
confident hope that political rights would be granted them as
compensation for the material sacrifices they had made for the good
of the State; but when they found that this confident hope was an
illusion, the indignation and discontent reappeared.
There was still, however, a ray of hope. Though the Autocratic
Power was evidently determined not to transform itself at once into
a limited Constitutional Monarchy, it might make concessions in the
sphere of local self-government. At that moment it was creating
the Zemstvo, and the Constitutionalists hoped that these new
institutions, though restricted legally to the sphere of purely
economic wants, might gradually acquire a considerable political
influence. Learned Germans had proved that in England, "the mother
of modern Constitutionalism," it was on local self-government that
the political liberties were founded, and the Slavophils now
suggested that by means of an ancient institution called the Zemski
Sobor, the Zemstvo might gradually and naturally acquire a
political character in accordance with Russian historic
development. As this idea has often been referred to in recent
discussions, I may explain briefly what the ancient institution in
question was.
In the Tsardom of Muscovy during the sixteenth and seventeenth
centuries representative assemblies were occasionally called
together to deal with matters of exceptional importance, such as
the election of a Tsar when the throne became vacant, a declaration
of war, the conclusion of a peace, or the preparation of a new code
of laws. Some fifteen assemblies of the kind were convoked in the
space of about a century (1550-1653). They were composed largely
of officials named by the Government, but they contained also some
representatives of the unofficial classes. Their procedure was
peculiar. When a speech from the throne had been read by the Tsar
or his representative, explaining the question to be decided, the
assembly transformed itself into a large number of commissions, and
each commission had to give in writing its opinion regarding the
questions submitted to it. The opinions thus elicited were
codified by the officials and submitted to the Tsar, and he was
free to adopt or reject them, as he thought fit. We may say,
therefore, that the Zemski Sobor was merely consultative and had no
legislative power; but we must add that it was allowed a certain
initiative, because it was permitted to submit to the Tsar humble
petitions regarding anything which it considered worthy of
attention.
Alexander II. might have adopted this Slavophil idea and used the
Zemski Sobor as a means of transition from pure autocracy to a more
modern system of government, but he had no sooner created the
Zemstvo than he thought it necessary, as we have seen, to clip its
wings, and dispel its political ambition. By this repressive
policy the frondeur spirit of the Noblesse was revived, and it has
continued to exist down to the present time. On each occasion when
I revisited Russia and had an opportunity of feeling the pulse of
public opinion, between 1876 and 1903, I noticed that the
dissatisfaction with the traditional methods of government, and the
desire of the educated classes to obtain a share of the political
power, notwithstanding short periods of apparent apathy, were
steadily spreading in area and increasing in intensity, and I often
heard predictions that a disastrous foreign war like the Crimean
campaign would probably bring about the desired changes. Of those
who made such predictions not a few showed clearly that, though
patriotic enough in a certain sense, they would not regret any
military disaster which would have the effect they anticipated.
Progress in the direction of political emancipation, accompanied by
radical improvements in the administration, was evidently regarded
as much more important and desirable than military prestige or
extension of territory.
During the first part of the Turkish campaign of 1877-78, when the
Russian armies were repulsed in Bulgaria and Asia Minor, the
hostility to autocracy was very strong, and the famous acquittal of
Vera Zasulitch, who had attempted to assassinate General Trepof,
caused widespread satisfaction among people who were not themselves
revolutionaries and who did not approve of such violent methods of
political struggle. Towards the end of the war, when the tide of
fortune had turned both in Europe and in Asia, and the Russian army
was encamped under the walls of Constantinople, within sight of St.
Sophia, the Chauvinist feelings gained the upper hand, and they
were greatly intensified by the Congress of Berlin, which deprived
Russia of some fruits of her victories.
This change in public feeling and the horror excited by the
assassination of Alexander II. prepared the way for Alexander
III.'s reign (1881-94), which was a period of political stagnation.
He was a man of strong character, and a vigorous ruler who believed
in Autocracy as he did in the dogmas of his Church; and very soon
after his accession he gave it clearly to be understood that he
would permit no limitations of the Autocratic Power. The men with
Liberal aspirations knew that nothing would make him change his
mind on that subject, and that any Liberal demonstrations would
merely confirm him in his reactionary tendencies. They accordingly
remained quiet and prudently waited for better times.
The better times were supposed to have come when Nicholas II.
ascended the throne in November, 1894, because it was generally
assumed that the young Tsar, who was known to be humane and well-
intentioned, would inaugurate a more liberal policy. Before he had
been three months on the throne he summarily destroyed these
illusions. On 17th (29th) January, 1895, when receiving deputies
from the Noblesse, the Zemstvo, and the municipalities, who had
come to St. Petersburg to congratulate him on his marriage, he
declared his confidence in the sincerity of the loyal feelings
which the delegates expressed; and then, to the astonishment of all
present, he added: "It is known to me that recently, in some
Zemstvo assemblies, were heard the voices of people who had let
themselves be carried away by absurd dreams of the Zemstvo
representatives taking part in the affairs of internal
administration; let them know that I, devoting all my efforts to
the prosperity of the nation, will preserve the principles of
autocracy as firmly and unswervingly as my late father of
imperishable memory."
These words, pronounced by the young ruler at the commencement of
his reign, produced profound disappointment and dissatisfaction in
all sections of the educated classes, and from that moment the
frondeur spirit began to show itself more openly than at any
previous period. In the case of some people of good social
position it took the unusual form of speaking disrespectfully of
his Majesty. Others supposed that the Emperor had simply repeated
words prepared for him by the Minister of the Interior, and this
idea spread rapidly, till hostility to the bureaucracy became
universal.
This feeling reached its climax when the Ministry of the Interior
was confided to M. Plehve. His immediate predecessors, though
sincere believers in autocracy and very hostile to Liberalism of
all kinds, considered that the Liberal ideas might be rendered
harmless by firm passive resistance and mild reactionary measures.
He, on the contrary, took a more alarmist view of the situation.
His appointment coincided with the revival of terrorism, and he
believed that autocracy was in danger. To save it, the only means
was, in his opinion, a vigorous, repressive police administration,
and as he was a man of strong convictions and exceptional energy,
he screwed up his system of police supervision to the sticking-
point and applied it to the Liberals as well as to the terrorists.
In the year 1903, if we may credit information which comes from an
apparently trustworthy source, no less than 1,988 political affairs
were initiated by the police, and 4,867 persons were condemned
inquisitorially to various punishments without any regular trial.
Whilst this unpopular rigorism was in full force the war
unexpectedly broke out, and added greatly to the existing
discontent.
Very few people in Russia had been following closely the recent
developments of the Far Eastern Question, and still fewer
understood their importance. There seemed to be nothing abnormal
in what was taking place. Russia was expanding, and would continue
to expand indefinitely, in that direction, without any strenuous
effort on her part. Of course the English would try to arrest her
progress as usual by diplomatic notes, but their efforts would be
as futile as they had been on all previous occasions. They might
incite the Japanese to active resistance, but Japan would not
commit the insane folly of challenging her giant rival to mortal
combat. The whole question could be settled in accordance with
Russian interests, as so many similar questions had been settled in
the past, by a little skilful diplomacy; and Manchuria could be
absorbed, as the contiguous Chinese provinces had been forty years
ago, without the necessity of going to war.
When these comforting illusions were suddenly destroyed by the
rupture of diplomatic relations and the naval attack on Port
Arthur, there was an outburst of indignant astonishment. At first
the indignation was directed against Japan and England, but it soon
turned against the home Government, which had made no adequate
preparations for the struggle, and it was intensified by current
rumours that the crisis had been wantonly provoked by certain
influential personages for purely personal reasons.
How far the accounts of the disorders in the military organisation
and the rumours about pilfering in high quarters were true, we need
not inquire. True or false, they helped greatly to make the war
unpopular, and to stimulate the desire for political changes.
Under a more liberal and enlightened regime such things were
supposed to be impossible, and, as at the time of the Crimean War,
public opinion decided that autocracy was being tried, and found
wanting.
So long as the stern, uncompromising Plehve was at the Ministry of
the Interior, enjoying the Emperor's confidence and directing the
police administration, public opinion was prudent and reserved in
its utterances, but when he was assassinated by a terrorist (July
28th, 1904), and was succeeded by Prince Sviatopolk Mirski, a
humane man of Liberal views, the Constitutionalists thought that
the time had come for making known their grievances and demands,
and for bringing pressure to bear on the Emperor. First came
forward the leading members of the Zemstvos. After some
preliminary consultation they assembled in St. Petersburg, with the
consent of the authorities, in the hope that they would be allowed
to discuss publicly the political wants of the country, and prepare
the draft of a Constitution. Their wishes were only partially
acceded to. They were informed semi-officially that their meetings
must be private, but that they might send their resolutions to the
Minister of the Interior for transmission to his Majesty. A
memorandum was accordingly drawn up and signed on November 21st by
102 out of the 104 representatives present.
This hesitating attitude on the part of the Government encouraged
other sections of the educated classes to give expression to their
long pent-up political aspirations. On the heels of the Zemstvo
delegates appeared the barristers, who discussed the existing evils
from the juridical point of view, and prescribed what they
considered the necessary remedies. Then came municipalities of the
large towns, corporations of various kinds, academic leagues,
medical faculties, learned societies, and miscellaneous gatherings,
all demanding reforms. Great banquets were organised, and very
strong speeches, which would have led in Plehve's time to the
immediate arrest of the orators, were delivered and published
without provoking police intervention.
In the memorandum presented to the Minister of the Interior by the
Zemstvo Congress, and in the resolutions passed by the other
corporate bodies, we see reflected the grievances and aspirations
of the great majority of the educated classes.
The theory propounded in these documents is that a lawless,
arbitrary bureaucracy, which seeks to exclude the people from all
participation in the management of public affairs, has come between
the nation and the Supreme Power, and that it is necessary to
eliminate at once this baneful intermediary and inaugurate the so-
called "reign of law." For this purpose the petitioners and
orators demanded:
(1) Inviolability of person and domicile, so that no one should be
troubled by the police without a warrant from an independent
magistrate, and no one punished without a regular trial;
(2) Freedom of conscience, of speech, and of the Press, together
with the right of holding public meetings and forming associations;
(3) Greater freedom and increased activity of the local self-
government, rural and municipal;
(4) An assembly of freely elected representatives, who should
participate in the legislative activity and control the
administration in all its branches;
(5) The immediate convocation of a constituent assembly, which
should frame a Constitution on these lines.
Of these requirements the last two are considered by far the most
important. The truth is that the educated classes have come to be
possessed of an ardent desire for genuine parliamentary
institutions on a broad, democratic basis, and neither improvements
in the bureaucratic organisation, nor even a Zemski Sobor in the
sense of a Consultative Assembly, would satisfy them. They imagine
that with a full-fledged constitution they would be guaranteed, not
only against administrative oppression, but even against military
reverses such as they have recently experienced in the Far East--an
opinion in which those who know by experience how military
unreadiness and inefficiency can be combined with parliamentary
institutions will hardly feel inclined to concur.
It may surprise English readers to learn that the corruption and
venality of the civil and military administration, of which we have
recently heard so much, are nowhere mentioned in the complaints and
remonstrances; but the fact is easily accounted for. Though
corrupt practices undoubtedly exist in some branches of the public
service, they are not so universal as is commonly supposed in
Western Europe; and the Russian reformers evidently consider that
the purifying of the administration is less urgent than the
acquisition of political liberties, or that under an enlightened
democratic regime the existing abuses would spontaneously
disappear.
The demands put forward in St. Petersburg did not meet with
universal approval in Moscow. There they seemed excessive and un-
Russian, and an attempt was made to form a more moderate party. In
the ancient Capital of the Tsars even among the Liberals there are
not a few who have a sentimental tenderness for the Autocratic
Power, and they argue that parliamentary government would be very
dangerous in a country which is still far from being homogeneous or
compact. To maintain the integrity of the Empire, and to hold the
balance equally between the various races and social classes of
which the population is composed, it is necessary, they think, to
have some permanent authority above the sphere of party spirit and
electioneering strife. While admitting that the Government in its
present bureaucratic form is unsatisfactory and stands in need of
being enlightened by the unofficial classes, they think that a
Consultative Assembly on the model of the old Zemski Sobors would
be infinitely better suited to Russian wants than a Parliament such
as that which sits at Westminster.
For a whole month the Government took little notice of the
unprecedented excitement and demonstrations. It was not till
December 25th that a reply was given to the public demands. On
that day the Emperor signed an ukaz in which he enumerated the
reforms which he considered most urgent, and instructed the
Committee of Ministers to prepare the requisite legislation. The
list of reforms coincided to a certain extent with the demands
formulated by the Zemstvos, but the document as a whole produced
profound disappointment, because it contained no mention of a
National Assembly. To those who could read between the lines the
attitude of the Emperor seemed perfectly clear. He was evidently
desirous of introducing very considerable reforms, but he was
resolved that they must be effected by the unimpaired Autocratic
Power in the old bureaucratic fashion, without any participation of
the unofficial world.
To obviate any misconception on this point, the Government
published, simultaneously with the ukaz, an official communication
in which it condemned the agitation and excitement, and warned the
Zemstvos, municipalities, and other corporate bodies that in
discussing political questions they were overstepping the limits of
their legally-defined functions and exposing themselves to the
rigours of the law.
As might have been foreseen, the ukaz and the circular had not at
all the desired effect of "introducing the necessary tranquillity
into public life, which has lately been diverted from its normal
course." On the contrary, they increased the excitement, and
evoked a new series of public demonstrations. On December 27th,
the very day on which the two official documents were published--
the Provincial Zemstvo of Moscow, openly disregarding the
ministerial warnings, expressed the conviction that the day was
near when the bureaucratic regime, which had so long estranged the
Supreme Power from the people, would be changed, and when freely-
elected representatives of the people would take part in
legislation. The same evening, at St. Petersburg, a great Liberal
banquet was held, at which a resolution was voted condemning the
war, and declaring that Russia could be extricated from her
difficulties only by the representatives of the nation, freely
elected by secret ballot. As an encouragement to the organs of
local administration to persevere in their disregard of ministerial
instructions, the St. Petersburg Medical Society, after adopting
the programme of the Zemstvo Congress, sent telegrams of
congratulation to the Mayor of Moscow and the President of the
Tchernigof Zemstvo bureau, both of whom had incurred the
displeasure of the Government. A similar telegram was sent by a
Congress of 496 engineers to the Moscow Town Council, in which the
burning political questions had been freely discussed. In other
large towns, when the mayor prevented such discussions, a
considerable number of the town councillors resigned.
From the Zemstvos and municipalities the spirit of opposition
spread to the provincial assemblies of the Noblesse. The nobles of
the province of St. Petersburg, for example, voted by a large
majority an address to the Tsar recommending the convocation of a
freely-elected National Assembly; and in Moscow, usually regarded
as the fortress of Conservatism, eighty members of the Assembly
entered a formal protest against a patriotic Conservative address
which had been voted two days before. Even the fair sex considered
it necessary to support the opposition movement. The matrons of
Moscow, in a humble petition to the Empress, declared that they
could not continue to bring up their children properly in the
existing state of unconstitutional lawlessness, and their view was
endorsed in several provincial towns by the schoolboys, who marched
through the streets in procession, and refused to learn their
lessons until popular liberties had been granted!
Again, for more than a month the Government remained silent on the
fundamental questions which were exercising the public mind. At
last, on the morning of March 3d, appeared an Imperial manifesto of
a very unexpected kind. In it the Emperor deplored the outbreak of
internal disturbances at a moment when the glorious sons of Russia
were fighting with self-sacrificing bravery and offering their
lives for the Faith, the Tsar, and the Fatherland; but he drew
consolation and hope from remembering that, with the help of the
prayers of the Holy Orthodox Church, under the banner of the Tsar's
autocratic might, Russia had frequently passed through great wars
and internal troubles, and had always issued from them with fresh
strength. He appealed, therefore, to all right-minded subjects, to
whatever class they might belong, to join him in the great and
sacred task of overcoming the stubborn foreign foe, and eradicating
revolt at home. As for the manner in which he hoped this might be
accomplished, he gave a pretty clear indication, at the end of the
document, by praying to God, not only for the welfare of his
subjects, but also for "the consolidation of autocracy."
This extraordinary pronouncement, couched in semi-ecclesiastical
language, produced in the Liberal world feelings of surprise,
disappointment, and dismay. No one was more astonished and
dismayed than the Ministers, who had known nothing of the manifesto
until they saw it in the official Gazette. In the course of the
forenoon they paid their usual weekly visit to Tsarskoe Selo, and
respectfully submitted to the Emperor that such a document must
have a deplorable effect on public opinion. In consequence of
their representations his Majesty consented to supplement the
manifesto by a rescript to the Minister of the Interior, in which
he explained that in carrying out his intentions for the welfare of
his people the Government was to have the co-operation of "the
experienced elements of the community." Then followed the
memorable words: "I am resolved henceforth, with the help of God,
to convene the most worthy men, possessing the confidence of the
people and elected by them, in order that they may participate in
the preparation and consideration of legislative measures." For
the carrying out of this resolution a commission, or "special
conference," was to be at once convened, under the presidency of M.
Bulyghin, the Minister of the Interior.
The rescript softened the impression produced by the manifesto, but
it did not give general satisfaction, because it contained
significant indications that the Emperor, while promising to create
an assembly of some kind, was still determined to maintain the
Autocratic Power. So at least the public interpreted a vague phase
about the difficulty of introducing reforms "while preserving
absolutely the immutability of the fundamental laws of the Empire."
And this impression seemed to be confirmed by the fact that the
task of preparing the future representative institutions was
confided, not to a constituent assembly, but to a small commission
composed chiefly or entirely of officials.
In these circumstances the Liberals determined to continue the
agitation. The Bulyghin Commission was accordingly inundated with
petitions and addresses explaining the wants of the nation in
general, and of various sections of it in particular; and when the
Minister declined to receive deputations and discuss with them the
aforesaid wants, the reform question was taken up by a new series
of congresses, composed of doctors, lawyers, professors,
journalists, etc. Even the higher ecclesiastical dignitaries woke
up for a moment from their accustomed lethargy, remembered how they
had lived for so many years under the rod of M. Pobedonostsef,
recognised as uncanonical such subordination to a layman, and
petitioned for the resurrection of the Patriarchate, which had been
abolished by Peter the Great.
On May 9th a new Zemstvo Congress was held in Moscow, and it at
once showed that since their November session in St. Petersburg the
delegates had made a decided movement to the Left. Those of them
who had then led the movement were now regarded as too
Conservative. The idea of a Zemski Sobor was discarded as
insufficient for the necessities of the situation, and strong
speeches were made in support of a much more democratic
constitution.
It was thus becoming clearer every day that between the Liberals
and the Government there was an essential difference which could
not be removed by ordinary concessions. The Emperor proved that he
was in favour of reform by granting a very large measure of
religious toleration, by removing some of the disabilities imposed
on the Poles, and allowing the Polish language to be used in
schools, and by confirming the proposals of the Committee of
Ministers to place the Press censure on a legal basis. But these
concessions to public opinion did not gain for him the sympathy and
support of his Liberal subjects. What they insisted on was a
considerable limitation of the Autocratic Power; and on that point
the Emperor has hitherto shown himself inexorable. His firmness
proceeds not from any wayward desire to be able to do as he
pleases, but from a hereditary respect for a principle. From his
boyhood he has been taught that Russia owes her greatness and her
security to her autocratic form of government, and that it is the
sacred duty of the Tsar to hand down intact to his successors the
power which he holds in trust for them.
While the Liberals were thus striving to attain their object
without popular disorders, and without any very serious infraction
of the law, Revolutionaries were likewise busy, working on
different but parallel lines.
In the chapter on the present phase of the revolutionary movement I
have sketched briefly the origin and character of the two main
Socialist groups, and I have now merely to convey a general idea of
their attitude during recent events. And first, of the Social
Democrats.
At the end of 1894 the Social Democrats were in what may be called
their normal condition--that is to say, they were occupied in
organising and developing the Labour Movement. The removal of
Plehve, who had greatly hampered them by his energetic police
administration, enabled them to work more freely, and they looked
with a friendly eye on the efforts of the Liberal Zemstvo-ists; but
they took no part in the agitation, because the Zemstvo world lay
outside their sphere of action. In the labour world, to which they
confined their attention, they must have foreseen that a crisis
would sooner or later be produced by the war, and that they would
then have an excellent opportunity of preaching their doctrine that
for all the sufferings of the working classes the Government is
responsible. What they did not foresee was that serious labour
troubles were so near at hand, and that the conflict with the
authorities would be accelerated by Father Gapon. Accustomed to
regard him as a persistent opponent, they did not expect him to
become suddenly an energetic, self-willed ally. Hence they were
taken unawares, and at first the direction of the movement was by
no means entirely in their hands. Very soon, however, they grasped
the situation, and utilised it for their own ends. It was in great
measure due to their secret organisation and activity that the
strike in the Putilof Ironworks, which might easily have been
terminated amicably, spread rapidly not only to the other works and
factories in St. Petersburg, but also to those of Moscow, Riga,
Warsaw, Lodz, and other industrial centres. Though they did not
approve of Father Gapon's idea of presenting a petition to the
Tsar, the loss of life which his demonstration occasioned was very
useful to them in their efforts to propagate the belief that the
Autocratic Power is the ally of the capitalists and hostile to the
claims and aspirations of the working classes.
The other great Socialist group contributed much more largely
towards bringing about the present state of things. It was their
Militant Organisation that assassinated Plehve, and thereby roused
the Liberals to action. To them, likewise, is due the subsequent
assassination of the Grand Duke Serge, and it is an open secret
that they are preparing other acts of terrorism of a similar kind.
At the same time they have been very active in creating provincial
revolutionary committees, in printing and distributing
revolutionary literature, and, above all, in organising agrarian
disturbances, which they intend to make a very important factor in
the development of events. Indeed, it is chiefly by agrarian
disturbances that they hope to overthrow the Autocratic Power and
bring about the great economic and social revolution to which the
political revolution would be merely the prologue.
Therein lies a serious danger.
After the failure of the propaganda and the insurrectionary
agitation in the seventies, it became customary in revolutionary
circles to regard the muzhik as impervious to Socialist ideas and
insurrectionary excitement, but the hope of eventually employing
him in the cause never quite died out, and in recent times, when
his economic condition in many districts has become critical,
attempts have occasionally been made to embarrass the Government by
agrarian disturbances. The method usually employed is to
disseminate among the peasantry by oral propaganda, by printed or
hectographed leaflets, and by forged Imperial manifestoes, the
belief that the Tsar has ordered the land of the proprietors to be
given to the rural Communes, and that his benevolent wishes are
being frustrated by the land-owners and the officials. The forged
manifesto is sometimes written in letters of gold as a proof of its
being genuine, and in one case which I heard of in the province of
Poltava, the revolutionary agent, wearing the uniform of an aide-
de-camp of the Emperor, induced the village priest to read the
document in the parish church.
The danger lies in the fact that, quite independent of
revolutionary activity, there has always been, since the time of
the Emancipation, a widespread belief among the peasantry that they
would sooner or later receive the whole of the land. Successive
Tsars have tried personally to destroy this illusion, but their
efforts have not been successful. Alexander II., when passing
through a province where the idea was very prevalent, caused a
number of village elders to be brought before him, and told them in
a threatening tone that they must remain satisfied with their
allotments and pay their taxes regularly; but the wily peasants
could not be convinced that the "General" who had talked to them in
this sense was really the Tsar. Alexander III. made a similar
attempt at the time of his accession. To the Volost elders
collected together from all parts of the Empire, he said: "Do not
believe the foolish rumours and absurd reports about a
redistribution of the land, and addition to your allotments, and
such like things. These reports are disseminated by your enemies.
Every kind of property, your own included, must be inviolable."
Recalling these words, Nicholas II. confirmed them at his
accession, and warned the peasants not to be led astray by evil-
disposed persons.
Notwithstanding these repeated warnings, the peasants still cling
to the idea that all the land belongs to them; and the Socialist-
Revolutionaries now announce publicly that they intend to use this
belief for the purpose of carrying out their revolutionary designs.
In a pamphlet entitled "Concerning Liberty and the Means of
Obtaining it," they explain their plan of campaign. Under the
guidance of the revolutionary agents the peasants of each district
all over the Empire are to make it impossible for the proprietors
to work their estates, and then, after driving away the local
authorities and rural police, they are to take possession of the
estates for their own use. The Government, in its vain attempts to
dislodge them, will have to employ all the troops at its disposal,
and this will give the working classes of the towns, led by the
revolutionists, an opportunity of destroying the most essential
parts of the administrative mechanism. Thus a great social
revolution can be successfully accomplished, and any Zemski Sobor
or Parliament which may be convoked will merely have to give a
legislative sanction to accomplished facts.
These three groups--the Liberals, the Social Democrats, and the
Socialist Revolutionaries--constitute what may be called the purely
Russian Opposition. They found their claims and justify their
action on utilitarian and philosophic grounds, and demand liberty
(in various senses) for themselves and others, independently of
race and creed. This distinguishes them from the fourth group, who
claim to represent the subject-nationalities, and who mingle
nationalist feelings and aspirations with enthusiasm for liberty
and justice in the abstract.
The policy of Russifying these subject-nationalities, which was
inaugurated by Alexander III. and maintained by his successor, has
failed in its object. It has increased the use of the Russian
language in official procedure, modified the system of instruction
in the schools and universities, and brought, nominally, a few
schismatic and heretical sheep into the Eastern Orthodox fold, but
it has entirely failed to inspire the subject-populations with
Russian feeling and national patriotism; on the contrary, it has
aroused in them a bitter hostility to Russian nationality, and to
the Central Government. In such of them as have retained their old
aspirations of political independence--notably the Poles--the semi-
latent disaffection has been stimulated; and in those of them
which, like the Finlanders and the Armenians, desire merely to
preserve the limited autonomy they formerly enjoyed, a sentiment of
disaffection has been created. All of them know very well that in
an armed struggle with the dominant Russian nationality they would
speedily be crushed, as the Poles were in 1863. Their disaffection
shows itself, therefore, merely in resistance to the obligatory
military service, and in an undisguised or thinly veiled attitude
of systematic hostility, which causes the Government some anxiety
and prevents it from sending to the Far East a large number of
troops which would otherwise be available. They hail, however,
with delight the Liberal and revolutionary movements in the hope
that the Russians themselves may undermine, and possibly overthrow,
the tyrannical Autocratic Power. Towards this end they would
gladly co-operate, and they are endeavouring, therefore, to get
into touch with each other; but they have so little in common, and
so many mutually antagonistic interests, that they are not likely
to succeed in forming a solid coalition.
While sympathising with every form of opposition to the Government,
the men of the subject-nationalities reserve their special
affection for the Socialists, because these not only proclaim, like
the Liberals, the principles of extensive local self-government and
universal equality before the law, but they also speak of replacing
the existing system of coercive centralisation by a voluntary
confederation of heterogeneous units. This explains why so many
Poles, Armenians and Georgians are to be found in the ranks of the
Social Democrats and the Socialist-Revolutionaries.
Of the recruits from oppressed nationalities the great majority
come from the Jews, who, though they have never dreamed of
political independence, or even of local autonomy, have most reason
to complain of the existing order of things. At all times they
have furnished a goodly contingent to the revolutionary movement,
and many of them have belied their traditional reputation of
timidity and cowardice by taking part in very dangerous terrorist
enterprises--in some cases ending their career on the scaffold. In
1897 they created a Social-Democratic organisation of their own,
commonly known as the Bund, which joined, in 1898, the Russian
Social-Democratic Labour Party, on the understanding that it should
retain its independence on all matters affecting exclusively the
Jewish population.* It now possesses a very ably-conducted weekly
organ, and of all sections of the Social-Democratic group it is
unquestionably the best organised. This is not surprising, because
the Jews have more business capacity than the Russians, and
centuries of oppression have developed in the race a wonderful
talent for secret illegal activity, and for eluding the vigilance
of the police.
* The official title of this Bund is the "Universal Jewish Labour
Union in Russia and Poland." Its organ is called Sovremenniya
Izvestiya (Contemporary News).
It would be very interesting to know the numerical strength of
these groups, but we have no materials for forming even an
approximate estimate. The Liberals are certainly the most
numerous. They include the great majority of the educated classes,
but they are less persistently energetic than their rivals, and
their methods of action make less impression on the Government.
The two Socialist groups, though communicative enough with regard
to their doctrines and aims, are very reticent with regard to the
number of their adherents, and this naturally awakens a suspicion
that an authoritative statement on the subject would tend to
diminish rather than enhance their importance in the eyes of the
public. If statistics of the Social Democrats could be obtained,
it would be necessary to distinguish between the three categories
of which the group is composed: (1) The educated active members,
who form the directing, controlling element; (2) the fully
indoctrinated recruits from the working classes; and (3) workmen
who desire merely to better their material condition, but who take
part in political demonstrations in the hope of bringing pressure
to bear on their employers, and inducing the Government to
intervene on their behalf.
The two Socialist groups are not only increasing the number of
their adherents; they are also extending and improving their
organisation, as is proved by the recent strikes, which are the
work of the Social Democrats, and by the increasing rural
disturbances and acts of terrorism, which are the work of the
Socialist-Revolutionaries.
With regard to the unorganised Nationalist group, all I can do
towards conveying a vague, general idea of its numerical strength
is to give the numbers of the populations--men, women, and
children--of which the Nationalist agitators are the self-
constituted representatives, without attempting to estimate the
percentage of the actively disaffected. The populations in
question are:
Poles 7,900,000
Jews 5,190,000
Finlanders 2,592,000
Armenians 1,200,000
Georgians 408,000
----------
16,495,000
If a National Assembly were created, in which all the nationalities
were represented according to the numbers of the population, the
Poles, roughly speaking, would have 38 members, the Jews 24, the
Finlanders 12, the Armenians 6, and the Georgians 2: whereas the
Russians would have about 400. The other subject-nationalities in
which symptoms of revolutionary fermentation have appeared are too
insignificant to require special mention.
As the representatives of the various subject-nationalities are
endeavouring to combine, so likewise are the Liberals and the two
Socialist groups trying to form a coalition, and for this purpose
they have already held several conferences. How far they will
succeed it is impossible to say. On one point--the necessity of
limiting or abolishing the Autocratic Power--they are unanimous,
and there seems to be a tacit understanding that for the present
they shall work together amicably on parallel lines, each group
reserving its freedom of action for the future, and using meanwhile
its own customary means of putting pressure on the Government. We
may expect, therefore, that for a time the Liberals will go on
holding conferences and congresses in defiance of the police
authorities, delivering eloquent speeches, discussing thorny
political questions, drafting elaborate constitutions, and making
gentle efforts to clog the wheels of the Administration,* while the
Social Democrats will continue to organise strikes and semi-pacific
demonstrations,** and the Socialist-Revolutionaries will seek to
accelerate the march of events by agrarian disturbances and acts of
terrorism.
* As an illustration of this I may cite the fact that several
Zemstvos have declared themselves unable, under present conditions,
to support the indigent families of soldiers at the front.
** I call them semi-pacific, because on such occasions the
demonstrators are instructed to refrain from violence only so long
as the police do not attempt to stop the proceedings by force.
It is certain, however, that the parting of the ways will be
reached sooner or later, and already there are indications that it
is not very far off. Liberals and Social Democrats may perhaps
work together for a considerable time, because the latter, though
publicly committed to socialistic schemes which the Liberals must
regard with the strongest antipathy, are willing to accept a
Constitutional regime during the period of transition. It is
difficult, however, to imagine that the Liberals, of whom a large
proportion are landed proprietors, can long go hand in hand with
the Socialist-Revolutionaries, who propose to bring about the
revolution by inciting the peasants to seize unceremoniously the
estates, live stock, and agricultural implements of the landlords.
Already the Socialist-Revolutionaries have begun to speak publicly
of the inevitable rupture in terms by no means flattering to their
temporary allies. In a brochure recently issued by their central
committee the following passage occurs:
"If we consider the matter seriously and attentively, it becomes
evident that all the strength of the bourgeoisie lies in its
greater or less capacity for frightening and intimidating the
Government by the fear of a popular rising; but as the bourgeoisie
itself stands in mortal terror of the thing with which it frightens
the Government, its position at the moment of insurrection will be
rather ridiculous and pitiable."
To understand the significance of this passage, the reader must
know that, in the language of the Socialists, bourgeoisie and
Liberals are convertible terms.
The truth is that the Liberals find themselves in an awkward
strategical position. As quiet, respectable members of society
they dislike violence of every kind, and occasionally in moments of
excitement they believe that they may attain their ends by mere
moral pressure, but when they find that academic protests and
pacific demonstrations make no perceptible impression on the
Government, they become impatient and feel tempted to approve, at
least tacitly, of stronger measures. Many of them do not profess
to regard with horror and indignation the acts of the terrorists,
and some of them, if I am correctly informed, go so far as to
subscribe to the funds of the Socialist-Revolutionaries without
taking very stringent precautions against the danger of the money
being employed for the preparation of dynamite and hand grenades.
This extraordinary conduct on the part of moderate Liberals may
well surprise Englishmen, but it is easily explained. The Russians
have a strong vein of recklessness in their character, and many of
them are at present imbued with an unquestioning faith in the
miracle-working power of Constitutionalism. These seem to imagine
that as soon as the Autocratic Power is limited by parliamentary
institutions the discontented will cease from troubling and the
country will be at rest.
It is hardly necessary to say that such expectations are not likely
to be realised. All sections of the educated classes may be agreed
in desiring "liberty," but the word has many meanings, and nowhere
more than in Russia at the present day. For the Liberals it means
simply democratic parliamentary government; for the Social Democrat
it means the undisputed predominance of the Proletariat; for the
Socialist-Revolutionary it means the opportunity of realising
immediately the Socialist ideal; for the representative of a
subject-nationality it means the abolition of racial and religious
disabilities and the attainment of local autonomy or political
independence. There is no doubt, therefore, that in Russia, as in
other countries, a parliament would develop political parties
bitterly hostile to each other, and its early history might contain
some startling surprises for those who had helped to create it. If
the Constitution, for example, were made as democratic as the
Liberals and Socialists demand, the elections might possibly result
in an overwhelming Conservative majority ready to re-establish the
Autocratic Power! This is not at all so absurd as it sounds, for
the peasants, apart from the land question, are thoroughly
Conservative. The ordinary muzhik can hardly conceive that the
Emperor's power can be limited by a law or an Assembly, and if the
idea were suggested to him, he would certainly not approve. In his
opinion the Tsar should be omnipotent. If everything is not
satisfactory in Russia, it is because the Tsar does not know of the
evil, or is prevented from curing it by the tchinovniks and the
landed proprietors. "More power, therefore, to his elbow!" as an
Irishman might say. Such is the simple political creed of the
"undeveloped" muzhik, and all the efforts of the revolutionary
groups to develop him have not yet been attended with much success.
How, then, the reader may ask, is an issue to be found out of the
present imbroglio? I cannot pretend to speak with authority, but
it seems to me that there are only two methods of dealing with the
situation: prompt, energetic repression, or timely, judicious
concessions to popular feeling. Either of these methods might,
perhaps, have been successful, but the Government adopted neither,
and has halted between the two. By this policy of drift it has
encouraged the hopes of all, has satisfied nobody, and has
diminished its own prestige.
In defence or extenuation of this attitude it may be said that
there is considerable danger in the adoption of either course.
Vigorous repression means staking all on a single card, and if it
were successful it could not do more than postpone the evil day,
because the present antiquated form of government--suitable enough,
perhaps, for a simply organised peasant-empire vegetating in an
atmosphere of "eternal stillness"--cannot permanently resist the
rising tide of modern ideas and aspirations, and is incapable of
grappling successfully with the complicated problems of economic
and social progress which are already awaiting solution. Sooner or
later the bureaucratic machine, driven solely by the Autocratic
Power in the teeth of popular apathy or opposition, must inevitably
break down, and the longer the collapse is postponed the more
violent is it likely to be. On the other hand, it is impossible to
foresee the effects of concessions. Mere bureaucratic reforms will
satisfy no one; they are indeed not wanted except as a result of
more radical changes. What all sections of the Opposition demand
is that the people should at least take part in the government of
the country by means of freely elected representatives in
Parliament assembled. It is useless to argue with them that
Constitutionalism will certainly not work the miracles that are
expected of it, and that in the struggles of political parties
which it is sure to produce the unity and integrity of the Empire
may be endangered. Lessons of that kind can only be learned by
experience. Other countries, it is said, have existed and thriven
under free political institutions, and why not Russia? Why should
she be a pariah among the nations? She gave parliamentary
institutions to the young nationalities of the Balkan Peninsula as
soon as they were liberated from Turkish bondage, and she has not
yet been allowed such privileges herself!
Let us suppose now that the Autocratic Power has come to feel the
impossibility of remaining isolated as it is at present, and that
it has decided to seek solid support in some section of the
population, what section should it choose? Practically it has no
choice. The only way of relieving the pressure is to make
concessions to the Constitutionalists. That course would
conciliate, not merely the section of the Opposition which calls
itself by that name and represents the majority of the educated
classes, but also, in a lesser degree, all the other sections. No
doubt these latter would accept the concession only as part payment
of their demands and a means of attaining ulterior aims. Again and
again the Social Democrats have proclaimed publicly that they
desire parliamentary government, not as an end in itself, but as a
stepping stone towards the realisation of the Socialist ideal. It
is evident, however, that they would have to remain on this
stepping stone for a long series of years--until the
representatives of the Proletariat obtained an overwhelming
majority in the Chamber. In like manner the subject-nationalities
would regard a parliamentary regime as a mere temporary expedient--
a means of attaining greater local and national autonomy--and they
would probably show themselves more impatient than the Social
Democrats. Any inordinate claims, however, which they might put
forward would encounter resistance, as the Poles found in 1863, not
merely from the Autocratic Power, but from the great majority of
the Russian people, who have no sympathy with any efforts tending
to bring about the disruption of the Empire. In short, as soon as
the Assembly set to work, the delegates would be sobered by a
consciousness of responsibility, differences of opinion and aims
would inevitably appear, and the various groups transformed into
political parties, instead of all endeavouring as at present to
pull down the Autocratic Power, would expend a great part of their
energy in pulling against each other.
In order to reach this haven of safety it is necessary to pass
through a period of transition, in which there are some formidable
difficulties. One of these I may mention by way of illustration.
In creating parliamentary institutions of any kind the Government
could hardly leave intact the present system of allowing the police
to arrest without a proper warrant, and send into exile without
trial, any one suspected of revolutionary designs. On this point
all the Opposition groups are agreed, and all consequently put
forward prominently the demand for the inviolability of person and
domicile. To grant such a concession seems a very simple and easy
matter, but any responsible minister might hesitate to accept such
a restriction of his authority. We know, he would argue, that the
terrorist section of the Socialist-Revolutionary group, the so-
called Militant Organisation, are very busy preparing bombs, and
the police, even with the extensive, ill-defined powers which they
at present possess, have the greatest difficulty in preventing the
use of such objectionable instruments of political warfare. Would
not the dynamiters and throwers of hand-grenades utilise a
relaxation of police supervision, as they did in the time of Louis
Melikof,* for carrying out their nefarious designs?
* Vide supra, p. 569.
I have no desire to conceal or minimise such dangers, but I believe
they are temporary and by no means so great as the dangers of the
only other alternatives--energetic repression and listless
inactivity. Terrorism and similar objectionable methods of
political warfare are symptoms of an abnormal, unhealthy state of
society, and would doubtless disappear in Russia, as they have
disappeared in other countries, with the conditions which produced
them. If the terrorists continued to exist under a more liberal
regime, they would be much less formidable, because they would lose
the half-concealed sympathy which they at present enjoy.
Political assassinations may occasionally take place under the most
democratic governments, as the history of the United States proves,
but terrorism as a system is to be found only in countries where
the political power is concentrated in the hands of a few
individuals; and it sometimes happens that irresponsible persons
are exposed to terrorist attacks. We have an instance of this at
present in St. Petersburg. The reluctance of the Emperor to adopt
at once a Liberal programme is commonly attributed to the influence
of two members of the Imperial family, the Empress Dowager and the
Grand Duke Vladimir. This is a mistake. Neither of these
personages is so reactionary as is generally supposed, and their
political views, whatever they may be, have no appreciable
influence on the course of affairs. If the Empress Dowager had
possessed the influence so often ascribed to her, M. Plehve would
not have remained so long in power. As for the Grand Duke
Vladimir, he is not in favour, and for nearly two years he has
never been consulted on political matters. The so-called Grand
Ducal party of which he is supposed to be the leader, is a recently
invented fiction. When in difficulties the Emperor may consult
individually some of his near relatives, but there is no coherent
group to which the term party could properly be applied.
As soon as the Autocratic Power has decided on a definite line of
action, it is to be hoped that a strong man will be found to take
the direction of affairs. In Russia, as in other autocratically
governed countries, strong men in the political sense of the term
are extremely rare, and when they do appear as a lusus naturae they
generally take their colour from their surroundings, and are of the
authoritative, dictatorial type. During recent years only two
strong men have come to the front in the Russian official world.
The one was M. Plehve, who was nothing if not authoritative and
dictatorial, and who is no longer available for experiments in
repression or constitutionalism. The other is M. Witte. As an
administrator under an autocratic regime he has displayed immense
ability and energy, but it does not follow that he is a statesman
capable of piloting the ship into calm waters, and he is not likely
to have an opportunity of making the attempt, for he does not--to
state the case mildly--possess the full confidence of his august
master.
Even if a strong man, enjoying fully the Imperial confidence, could
be found, the problem would not be thereby completely and
satisfactorily solved, because an autocrat, who is the Lord's
Anointed, cannot delegate his authority to a simple mortal without
losing something of the semi-religious halo and the prestige on
which his authority rests. While a roi faineant may fulfil
effectively all the essential duties of sovereignty, an autocrate
faineant is an absurdity.
In these circumstances, it is idle to speculate as to the future.
All we can do is to await patiently the development of events, and
in all probability it is the unexpected that will happen.
The reader doubtless feels that I am offering a very lame and
impotent conclusion, and I must confess that I am conscious of this
feeling myself, but I think I may fairly plead extenuating
circumstances. Happily for my peace of mind I am a mere observer
who is not called upon to invent a means of extricating Russia from
her difficult position. For that arduous task there are already
brave volunteers enough in the field. All I have to do is to
explain as clearly as I can the complicated problem to be solved.
Nor do I feel it any part of my duty to make predictions. I
believe I am pretty well acquainted with the situation at the
present moment, but what it may be a few weeks hence, when the
words I am now writing issue from the press, I do not profess to
foresee.
End of The Project Gutenberg Etext of Russia by Donald Mackenzie Wallace
Livros Grátis
( http://www.livrosgratis.com.br )
Milhares de Livros para Download:
Baixar livros de Administração
Baixar livros de Agronomia
Baixar livros de Arquitetura
Baixar livros de Artes
Baixar livros de Astronomia
Baixar livros de Biologia Geral
Baixar livros de Ciência da Computação
Baixar livros de Ciência da Informação
Baixar livros de Ciência Política
Baixar livros de Ciências da Saúde
Baixar livros de Comunicação
Baixar livros do Conselho Nacional de Educação - CNE
Baixar livros de Defesa civil
Baixar livros de Direito
Baixar livros de Direitos humanos
Baixar livros de Economia
Baixar livros de Economia Doméstica
Baixar livros de Educação
Baixar livros de Educação - Trânsito
Baixar livros de Educação Física
Baixar livros de Engenharia Aeroespacial
Baixar livros de Farmácia
Baixar livros de Filosofia
Baixar livros de Física
Baixar livros de Geociências
Baixar livros de Geografia
Baixar livros de História
Baixar livros de Línguas
Baixar livros de Literatura
Baixar livros de Literatura de Cordel
Baixar livros de Literatura Infantil
Baixar livros de Matemática
Baixar livros de Medicina
Baixar livros de Medicina Veterinária
Baixar livros de Meio Ambiente
Baixar livros de Meteorologia
Baixar Monografias e TCC
Baixar livros Multidisciplinar
Baixar livros de Música
Baixar livros de Psicologia
Baixar livros de Química
Baixar livros de Saúde Coletiva
Baixar livros de Serviço Social
Baixar livros de Sociologia
Baixar livros de Teologia
Baixar livros de Trabalho
Baixar livros de Turismo